• Non ci sono risultati.

Crowdfunding tax incentives in Europe: a comparative analysis

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "Crowdfunding tax incentives in Europe: a comparative analysis"

Copied!
54
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

Crowdfunding tax incentives in Europe: A comparative

analysis

Cicchiello, A.F, Battaglia, F., & Monferrà, S. The European Journal of Finance

(Accepted on 1 April 2019)

Abstract

Some European countries offer tax incentive schemes to investors and companies in crowdfunding. On one hand, they could be seen as a tool to reduce the system’s dependence on banks and increase the availability of credit for start-ups and Small and Medium Enterprises (SMEs). On the other hand, there is the counterweight of disadvantages that investors may face by investing in crowdfunding (i.e., complex and incomplete laws, and weak protection). This paper is primarily intended as a primer on the use of tax incentives for crowdfunding in Europe. In this study, we first examine the implementation of tax incentive schemes in the United Kingdom, France, Italy, Spain, and Belgium. Then, we analyse and compare the characteristics of such schemes along three dimensions: the incentives structure; the business characteristics; and the type of investor. We find that tax incentive schemes for crowdfunding vary widely in their form and other features of their design. Moreover, the most used forms of tax incentives are those that provide for an up-front tax credit on the amount invested in early-stage ventures. These incentives have an immediate effect on the annual income tax of the investor. A central implication is that the more tax incentive schemes are properly designed and tailored for crowdfunders, the more investors, start-ups and other firms with low liquidity could use crowdfunding as a source of funding.

JEL classification: G30, H31, H32

Keywords: Government Policy and Regulation; Tax incentives; Crowdfunding investment; Entrepreneurial finance; European countries.

(2)

1. Introduction

Over the last few years, crowdfunding has emerged as a new player in entrepreneurial finance (Bruton et al., 2015; Block et al., 2018a). The 2008/2009 financial crisis and the resulting tightening of credit conditions have made the development of new forms of financing for young innovative firms necessary. Moreover, the recent wave of digital technologies has reshaped the financial sector by changing the way customers and businesses access financial services. In such a highly dynamic scenario, crowdfunding provides consumers with the opportunity to become investors and to finance projects, companies or ideas via the Internet by providing many small amounts of capital (Ahlers et al., 2015).

In less than a decade, this new financing model has become a multi-billion-dollar industry worldwide. According to the 3rd annual European Alternative Finance Industry Report (Ziegler et al., 2018), the European market grew by 41% in 2016, reaching € 7.7 billion and doubling its volumes from 2015. The United Kingdom still remains the largest online alternative finance market, with a market volume in Europe of € 5.6 billion, followed by France (€443.98 million), Germany (€321.84 million) the Netherlands (€194.19 million), Finland (€142.23 million), Spain (€130.90 million), Italy (€127.06 million) and Georgia (€102.58 million). Figure 1. shows the total amount of funding raised through the alternative finance platforms in selected European countries in 2016 (in euro million).

INSERT FIGURE 1.

In response to the growing importance of crowdfunding in entrepreneurial finance, European policymakers started using tax incentives. These schemes are intended to increase new ventures investment through crowdfunding and provide investors with a counterweight to the uncertainties such as complex and incomplete laws and weak protection.

According to research commissioned by the UK Government (HM Revenue and Customs Research Report, 2016), for more than 79% of investors the availability of the income tax relief is crucial in their decision to invest into small and high-risk businesses. Moreover, in 2016 among

(3)

the UK higher rate taxpayers (i.e. investors that have more than £40,000 of investments and, pay an income tax four times higher than the national average), IW Capital’s Taxpayer Sentiment Reportstated the majority (54%) claimed to be willing to invest through the Enterprise Investment Scheme (EIS), which is also used for crowdfunding investment.

In Europe, tax incentives are mainly used to stimulate equity-based crowdfunding (investors provide funds in early-stage unlisted companies in exchange for shares). However, a few tax incentives are also addressed at lending-based crowdfunding (investors provide funds through small loans to consumers or business and obtain repayment with interest in return), and donation-based crowdfunding (investors provide funds in social or charitable causes without expecting something in return) (see Mollick, 2014 for a detailed description of crowdfunding models).

Prior research has investigated the success drivers of crowdfunding campaigns and has shown that the presence of tax incentives has a positive impact on campaign success (Ralcheva and Roosenboom, 2016; Signori and Vismara, 2016 and 2018). However, probably due to the lack of data and the difficulties in assessing the incentives impact, the existing literature has examined tax incentives only marginally by focusing mainly on the UK's SEIS and EIS schemes. Until now, little is known about the existence of tax incentives for crowdfunding in other European countries, or on the role they could play in attracting crowdfunding investment across Europe. This paper extends the existing literature by analysing and comparing the tax incentive schemes for crowdfunding currently used in European countries. The aim is to give a primer on the use of tax incentives in fostering investment oriented towards the four main types of crowdfunding (i.e. donation-based, reward-based, lending, and equity), by answering the following research questions:

(1) What tax incentives are currently available for crowdfunding investment?

(2) What are the desirable design features of crowdfunding tax incentives?

To answer our research questions, we provide a detailed analysis of the tax incentives offered in the UK, France, Italy, Spain, and Belgium (the only countries adopting tax incentives to stimulate

(4)

crowdfunding investment). Following this analysis, we provide significant insight into how tax incentive differ from country to country by comparing these schemes along three dimensions (1) the incentives structure, (2) the business characteristics, and (3) the type of investor.

It is worth noticing that the majority of the tax incentives addressed in the paper are actually pre-existing incentives, which are equally used to promote both crowdfunding and other kinds of investment in startups. The United Kingdom’s Enterprise Investment Scheme (EIS), for example, was launched in 1994 to provide tax relief on investments in certain small unquoted companies. In recent years, the application of this scheme has also been extended to crowdfunding. Today EIS scheme is widely used by equity crowdfunding firms to encourage investment in small high-risk companies. The same applies to France’s “Madelin” tax reductions scheme introduced in 1994 (to provide incentives for individuals investing in SMEs), and currently used for crowdfunding investment. Tailored schemes for crowdfunding investment already exist in Europe, and many European countries are evaluating their implementation. Our analysis includes schemes specifically designed for equity and lending-based crowdfunding, such as:

(1) The United Kingdom’s Innovative Finance ISA Scheme IFISA (2016);

(2) France's losses allocation system (2015);

(3) Belgium's Tax treatment of crowdfunding loans (2015).

Our paper contributes to the growing research on crowdfunding and in particular on equity crowdfunding by investigating and comparing the existing tax incentives for crowdfunding in European countries. Furthermore, we add to the entrepreneurial finance literature. It has been shown that tax incentives can be used as a single part of a broader portfolio of policy interventions to stimulate forms of entrepreneurial finance such as business angel and venture capital (Da Rin et al., 2006; Cowling et al., 2008; Cumming and Li, 2013). It has also been found that targeted and properly-designed tax incentives may help to correct some market imperfections or distortions such as moral hazard and information asymmetry (Keuschnigg and Nielsen, 2004a).

(5)

Hence, our paper contributes to literature on tax incentives in entrepreneurial finance by looking at the specific context of crowdfunding.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 summarises the relevant literature on crowdfunding and the use of tax incentives in attracting investment. Section 3 analyses the typology of tax incentives which can be used and how they affect tax burdens. Section 4 describes tax incentive schemes in force in the analysed countries. Section 5 presents the comparative analysis and its results. Section 6 concludes.

2. Literature review

The existing literature on crowdfunding focuses mainly on four streams of studies (for detailed literature review see Bouncken et al., 2015; Moritz and Block, 2016; Kuppuswamy and Bayus, 2017; Short et al., 2017; Mochkabadi and Volkmann, 2018). The first one addresses the issue of crowdfunding regulation and identifies the regulatory challenges that policymakers and regulators are facing. Legal scholars in the United States (Hazen, 2012; Stemler, 2013) discuss the legislative changes caused by the growth of crowdfunding and the need to provide a suitable level of investor protection. Stemler (2013) suggests that crowdfunding needs to be approached cautiously through specific regulation to mitigate the risks associated therewith. According to the author, this is the only workable way of helping investors make informed decisions and limiting the amounts they can put at risk. A large group of studies discusses the application of the Securities Act of 1933 (Bradford, 2012; Sigar, 2012; Cumming and Johan, 2013), and the entry into force of the “Jumpstart Our Business Startups (JOBS) Act” on April 5, 2012 (Fink, 2012; Knight et al., 2012; Bradford, 2018), which legalised crowdfunding.

The literature on crowdfunding regulation in Europe focuses mainly on the legal provisions required to guarantee a beneficial functioning of the crowdfunding market (notably of the equity-based sector) and to improve investor protection (Pekmezovic and Walker, 2015; Klöhn et al., 2016). The majority of the papers within this perspective analyses the existing legal regulations in different countries. Klöhn and Hornuf (2012), for example, compare German and US equity

(6)

crowdfunding regulation to identify the main differences among these frameworks. Similarly, Wilson and Testoni (2014) outline the main differences and similarities between the US and European regulation. By analysing the legal reforms promoting crowdfunding in six European countries, Hornuf and Schwienbacher (2017) argue that when alternative sources of entrepreneurial finance (such as angel capital and venture capital) are scarce, too strong investor protection may harm equity crowdfunding investments.

The second stream of literature explores the motivations for using crowdfunding assuming that non-financial motivations also drive both investors and companies (Ordanini et al., 2011; Lin et al., 2014; Cholakova and Clarysse, 2015). By conducting one-on-one semi-structured interviews with crowdfunding funders, Gerber et al. (2012) find that investors participate in crowdfunding to get rewards, but also to support companies or projects in which they believe, or to contribute to the community. Similarly, Allison et al. (2015) find that social reputation plays a significant role in the decision to invest in lending-based crowdfunding. Other strong motivations that investors try to satisfy by investing in crowdfunding are self-affirmation and fun (Hemer et al., 2011). By exploring the motivations from the companies’ point of view, Gerber et al. (2012) show that companies consider crowdfunding to be not only a funding channel, but also a way to develop strong relationship and networks, to increase awareness of the product, and to replicate successful experiences of others. Similarly, Belleflamme et al. (2013) find that reasons, like getting public attention and receiving feedback for their products and services, are relevant for companies, in addition to financial motivation. Burtch et al. (2013) confirm the result of Belleflamme et al. (2013), showing that participation in crowdfunding allows companies to increase their visibility and products consumption. According to Mollick and Kuppuswamy (2014), companies can not only fill the equity gap (notably in the early stage), but they can also benefit from better access to customers and outside funders (i.e., business angels and venture capitalists), by using crowdfunding. Other authors (Hemer et al., 2011; Hienerth and Riar, 2013; Macht and Weatherston, 2014) state that companies can adopt crowdfunding also to exploit the speed and flexibility of the online funding process.

(7)

The third and most extensive stream of literature focuses on success factors influencing crowdfunding campaigns. Specifically, a few studies empirically examine the campaign characteristics, such as the offer properties and its funding dynamics. Ahlers et al. (2015) and Vismara (2016), for example, investigate whether the amount of retained equity is related to campaigns success, in equity crowdfunding markets. Both studies conclude that the amount of retained equity affects the campaign success. Indeed, a larger percentage of equity offered to investors is linked to a smaller number of investors and a smaller amount of raised capital. Additionally, Ahlers et al. (2015) find that other factors, such as the presence of financial roadmaps and external certifications, a higher number of board members and a higher level of board education, significantly increase campaigns success.

Other studies (Zhang and Liu, 2012; Colombo et al., 2015; Vulkan et al., 2016; Hornuf and Schwienbacher, 2018) analyse the investment dynamics finding that, as in the IPO market (see, e.g., Welch, 1992 and Aggarwal et al., 2002), also in the crowdfunding market potential investors are influenced by the behaviour of earlier investors. Zhang and Liu (2012) provide the first paper exploring the investors’ behavioural mechanism in the context of lending-based crowdfunding. Specifically, the authors show that lenders engage in rational herding by deducting the borrower’s creditworthiness from observing others’ lending decisions. By analysing 669 projects from the reward-based platform Kickstarter, Colombo et al. (2015) find similar results. The authors provide evidence that contributions received in the very first stage of a crowdfunding campaign reduce uncertainty and accelerate its success. Concerning the equity crowdfunding context, Hornuf and Schwienbacher (2018) confirm that a larger number of early-stage investors can be interpreted as a quality signal, encouraging additional participation by others and increasing the probability of funding success. A few studies within this stream of literature show that the geographic proximity between firms and investors increases the probability of campaigns’ success.

By analysing data from Kickstarter, Mollick (2014) finds that, in reward-based crowdfunding, investors are more responsive to the distance and prefer to invest in geographically close projects.

(8)

Similarly, Lin and Viswanathan (2015) show the presence of home bias for investors in lending transaction. The positive influence of geographic proximity on funding success was also found in the equity crowdfunding market (Hornuf and Schmitt, 2016; Günther et al., 2018). By analysing projects from the Australian platform ASSOB, Günther et al. (2018) provide the first empirical evidence of the existence of local biases affecting home-country investors. Hornuf and Schmitt (2016) find similar results when they analyse the geographical distribution of investors on the German’s equity-based platforms Companisto and Innovestment.

The recent literature on success factors driving crowdfunding campaigns explores the role of information disclosure and social networks on crowd participation. Specifically, it focuses on how specific types of information can be used to overcome informational asymmetries and drive investment decisions (Kromidha and Robson, 2016; Angerer et al., 2017; Piva and Rossi-Lamastra, 2017; Block et al., 2018). Several authors state that updates typically have a positive impact on equity-based crowdfunding participation due to their highly visible and observable for potential investors. Block et al. (2018), for example, investigate the effects of information disclosure in the form of updates on funding success showing that, when entrepreneurs use updates to inform investors about new funding sources, business development processes, and marketing campaigns, this updates significantly increase funding success. In contrast, the use of updates containing information about the team and product development have no significant effect.

By employing hand-collected data from four German equity crowdfunding platforms, Hornuf and Schwienbacher (2018) explore the determinants of individual investment decisions in crowdfunding, showing that investors base their decisions on information provided by the entrepreneur in the form of updates during the campaign and by the investment behavior and comments of other crowd investors.

Angerer et al. (2017) confirm that an active communication and advertisement strategy based on social media, videos, and other online marketing tools have a positive impact on German startups’

(9)

equity crowdfunding campaigns’ chances of success. Polzin et al. (2018) distinguish between investors having strong personal ties with the project creator (in-crowd investors) and investors with weak personal ties (out-crowd investors) to test for heterogeneity in their information use. They find that, while in-crowd investors rely more on information about the project creators, out- crowd investors seem to give more importance to information about the project and its objectives.

Assuming that online social networks are the main drivers of crowdfunding activities, several scholars investigate how the size of investors’ and founders’ social networks affects campaigns in both reward-based and equity crowdfunding (Mollick, 2014; Agrawal et al., 2015; Colombo et al., 2015; Vismara, 2016 and 2018). Mollick (2014), for example, shows that a large number of founders’ Facebook friends is positively associated with the amount of capital raised for a project and the subsequent success of the project on the reward-based platform Kickstarter. By using the number of proponents’ LinkedIn connections, Colombo et al. (2015) and Vismara (2016) find the same results. In a recent study on equity campaigns posted on Crowdcube, Vismara (2018) shows that information cascades among investors are crucial in crowdfunding.

A fourth strand of literature has emerged over the last years, focusing on the post-campaign outcomes. The first papers in this field focused on the follow-on and survival of successful reward crowdfunding projects (Mollick, 2014; Mollick and Kuppuswamy, 2014; Colombo and Shafi, 2016; Butticè et al., 2017). Butticè et al. (2017), for example, identify the “serial crowdfunders,” namely entrepreneurs who repeatedly use crowdfunding to finance their projects. They find that campaigns launched by serial crowdfunders are more likely to turn successful. Little is known about whether equity crowdfunded firms can ultimately build enduring businesses. Therefore, academics investigated the post-campaign performance and provided first insights into the returns on investment (Drover et al., 2017; Coakley et al., 2018; Di Pietro et al., 2018; Hornuf et al., 2018; Signori and Vismara, 2018; Walthoff-Borm et al., 2018). Signori and Vismara (2018) confirm the effectiveness of the equity crowdfunding in boosting the growth of new ventures. The authors also find that firms with more dispersed ownership are less likely to issue further equity, while those that reach the target capital more quickly are more likely to launch a follow-on

(10)

offering. Finally, the results show that tax incentives, such as the UK’s EIS and SEIS schemes, increase the firms’ probability of raising additional capital, especially from a qualified investor. Coakley et al. (2018) investigate the determinants of a successful first follow-on campaign. The results show that the probability of conducting a first follow-on campaign is positively impacted by the degree of overfunding on the initial campaign and by the related social capital that initial campaign success garners. Hornuf et al. (2018) extend the work of Coakley et al. (2018) by examining failure rates, and follow-on financing of equity crowdfunded firms in Germany and the UK. The empirical evidence shows that German crowdfunded firms have a higher chance of obtaining follow-up funding through venture capitalists or business angels but also have a higher chance of failing compared to British firms.

To date, scholars have examined and discussed the presence of tax incentives in crowdfunding investment only marginally by focusing mainly on the UK's SEIS and EIS schemes. In a very recent study, Estrin et al. (2018), following the ‘Gioia Methodology’ (Gioia et al., 2013), find that on the investors’ side, tax breaks represent one of the ‘first-order’ reasons for investing in equity crowdfunding. By analysing the determinants of funding success in a sample of projects listed on the UK equity platforms, some authors include in the control variable sets the United Kingdom Investment Schemes (i.e. SEIS and EIS), which are designed to encourage seed investment in early-stage companies (Ralcheva and Roosenboom, 2016; Signori and Vismara, 2016 and 2018; Vismara 2016 and 2018; Vulkan et al., 2016). However, these studies dealing with the impact of tax incentives on crowdfunding, bring mixed results. In particular, Vismara (2016 and 2018) finds that tax incentives are not significant in attracting early investors and do not impact the probability of the offerings being successful, even if they do attract professional investors.

On the contrary, Signori and Vismara (2016 and 2018) show that being eligible for tax incentives matter, confirming the success of tax policies designed to stimulate investments in early-stage companies. Indeed, as found by these two scholars, firms that benefit from the tax incentive face not only a higher likelihood of a successful outcome (Signori and Vismara, 2016), but are also more likely to succeed in raising additional capital in follow-on offerings and less likely to fail in

(11)

a post-campaign scenario (Signori and Vismara, 2018). Finally, Ralcheva and Roosenboom, 2016, observe that successful campaigns often have tax breaks, but companies that do not offer tax breaks to investors do not experience lower funding success.

These studies belong to the stream of literature dealing with the effects (i.e., benefits and risks) of tax incentives on investment in both developed and developing countries (Buss, 2001). In particular, the most recent studies on the topic focus on the role and importance of tax incentives as part of a broader set of policy tools used to encourage forms of entrepreneurial finance such as business angel (Aernoudt, 1999; Lipper and Sommer, 2002; Hendon et al., 2012; Carpentier and Suret, 2013) and venture capital (Christofidis and Debande, 2001; EVCA, 2003; Keuschnigg and Nielsen, 2003 and 2004; Carpentier and Suret, 2007; Cowling et al., 2008; Cumming and Li, 2013). A recent report of the European Commission (2017) states that tax incentives for venture capital and business angels' investment significantly influence investment decisions by reducing the effective marginal cost of investing in smaller companies. According to this, in taking the initial investment decision, an investor should be willing to provide more capital through business angels or venture capital funds which benefit from tax incentives, rather than through those not benefit for them. Then, the report concludes that targeted and properly-designed tax incentives may help to correct some market imperfections or distortions such as moral hazard and information asymmetry. A growing body of literature discusses the controversial use of tax incentives in developing countries (Brodzka, 2013; Munongo et al., 2017). In particular, while some authors emphasize the positive impact of tax incentives in attracting Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) and strengthening the competitive position of developing countries (Shah, 1995; OECD, 2001; Zee et al., 2002; Klemm and Van Parys, 2012), others authors stress the risks and costs related to them (Wells et al., 2001; Easson and Zolt, 2002; Zee et al., 2002; Zelekha and Sharabi, 2012; Kinda, 2018). For instance, Easson and Zolt (2002) argue that tax incentives are the source of two kinds of revenue losses. First, tax incentives discourage other investments in favor of the incentive-receiving projects. Second, tax incentives give businesses the opportunity to shift income from taxable activities to those that fall under tax incentives by improperly

(12)

claiming the incentives and thereby avoiding tax. Moreover, authors find that tax incentives encourage the governments' corruption by giving the authorities discretionary power to determine which projects qualify for incentives and which do not. Recent evidence on 30 African countries suggests that these countries should avoid using costly tax incentives and pay more attention to the infrastructure, finance, institutions, and human capital, which are the key aspects of their economy’s investment climate (Kinda, 2018).

Despite many theoretical and empirical studies, which analyse the impact of tax incentives on investment, none of them focus on crowdfunding investments. Our study aims to extend the existing literature by giving a primer on the use of tax incentives in fostering investment oriented towards crowdfunding in Europe. Consistent with the previous literature review and its findings, we analyse and compare the tax incentive schemes for crowdfunding currently used in European countries, by answering the following research questions:

(1) What tax incentives are currently available for crowdfunding investment?

(2) What are the desirable design features of crowdfunding tax incentives?

More specifically, our study analyses the different tax incentive schemes in force in the UK, France, Italy, Spain, and Belgium, to understand their role in stimulating crowdfunding development.

3. Typology of Tax Incentives

Tax incentives can be defined as special tax provisions drawn up by governments to provide a more favorable tax treatment to certain activities, investment projects, or taxpayers, compared to the provisions applicable in general (i.e., those that do not receive a special tax provision) (Klemm, 2010). These special provisions can take multiple forms. Typically, they offer investors some combination of tax deductions through investment allowances or tax credits, temporary exemptions on corporate taxes (tax holidays), reduction of capital gains taxes for investors in

(13)

startups, preferential rates, relief on income generated over the life of the investment, relief on gains realised upon disposal of the investment, provisions for carry forward of capital gains or losses, and so on. How these incentives work and the reasons for their use vary considerably from country to country. The most common tax incentives are the following:

1) tax holidays are directed to new firms or investments and allow for a temporary exemption from certain specified taxes, typically income tax, which may be total or partial (i.e., with a rate that is below the regular rate for qualified investment projects). They may be granted to particular activities or particular taxpayers. Of all the different forms of tax incentives available, tax holidays are most popular among developing and transitioning countries, but rarely found in developed countries;

2) investment allowances are a form of tax relief by which a specified percentage of the initial costs on qualifying investments can be deducted from taxable income, in addition to the normal allowable depreciation on the full costs of such investments. Investment allowances aim to encourage capital investment, and they differ from investment tax credits which allow taxpayers to deduct investment costs directly from their tax liability;

3) investment tax credits are a form of tax relief structured to encourage economic growth by allowing investors to reduce the amount of taxes to be paid. In particular, investors may deduct a certain fraction of investment costs directly from their tax liability, in the current fiscal year or a later year (tax carryforward). Being equivalent forms of tax incentives, investment tax credits and investment allowances share the same advantages;

4) reduced tax rates provide a reduction of the ordinary rates of tax charged under various tax laws for qualified investment projects, qualified investors, and certain types of firms such as startups and SMEs. Reduced tax rates may occur on income, profits, sales, or assets, and they can be a one-time rebate, a reduction in the overall rate, or a tax credit. Unlike tax holidays, the tax liability of firms is not entirely eliminated, but only reduced;

(14)

5)

the Special Economic Zones (SEZs) are limited areas that are subject to unique

economic regulations, designated by the trade and commerce administrations of

various countries to encourage economic activity and the FDI flows by leveraging

tax incentives. In particular, companies that conduct their business in a SEZ

typically receive a total or partial tax exemption and the opportunity to pay lower

tariffs. The taxation rules are determined by each country and represent a heavily

debated argument;

6) tax exemptions reduce the amount of the taxable income by relieving the taxpayer of any tax obligation to submit taxes on the tax-exempt transaction or income. Not to be confused with the tax deductions, which reduce (but don't remove) the tax obligation by decreasing the total taxable income. Tax deductions are most commonly a way that the government provides an incentive for people to participate in activities that have a greater societal benefit (e.g., charitable donation or more environmentally friendly purchases);

7) tax deferral offers taxpayer the possibility to delay paying taxes by allowing a temporary exemption. Tax-deferred investments help investors avoid cash outflows for taxes in the immediate future, and generate higher returns: the money that would normally be used for tax payments is instead allowed to remain in the account and earn a return;

8) financing incentives are benefits given to customers or companies, to encourage them to do actions (typically invest) they normally wouldn’t, by reducing the tax rates applicable to investors.

4. Tax incentives to promote crowdfunding investment

For the purposes of this paper, five countries have been selected to highlight how varied tax incentive schemes are designed and implemented. This sample provides significant insight into how tax incentive schemes differ from country to country. The analysis includes the UK, France, Italy, Spain, and Belgium.

(15)

The UK has the most developed crowdfunding market in terms of both the number and the size of offerings (Ziegler et al., 2018). The number of platforms has increased from a dozen in 2010 to 65 in 2017. The major crowdfunding platforms for the invested amount in 2017 was Crowdcube (with £ 87.3 m), Seedrs (£ 55.1 m), Syndicate Room (£ 39.5 m), and Venture Founders (£ 32.9 m)1. The UK Regulator has enacted specific rules for both equity- and lending-based crowdfunding in April 2014 (FCA’s Policy Statement PS14/4). The Financial Conduct Authority (FCA) grants to the platforms the license to operate and supervises their activity. In the UK, in contrast with most other jurisdictions, investors can self-certify their belonging to specific categories of investors (e.g., sophisticated or net worth investors) which are not subject to investment limits. UK policymakers support crowdfunding via four tax incentive schemes. Two of these schemes are directed to equity investments (EIS and SEIS), one has been designed to lending-based crowdfunding (IFISA), and the last one is addressed to donation-based crowdfunding (Gift Aide Scheme). This “light-touch” regulatory approach combined with tax incentives policies have probably helped the rapid growth of crowdfunding in the UK (Estrin et al. 2016; Vulkan et al. 2016).

According to the barometer of crowdfunding, published every year by the French Professional Association FPF (Financement Participatif France), the crowdfunding market in France experienced steady growth. Since its inception in 2007, the number of platforms has more than doubled each year to reach 74 active platforms in 2017. In the same year, crowdfunding has raised over € 336 million, and it was able to finance 24,126 projects. The Ordinance no. 2014-559 of 30 May 2014 provides the basis for a regulatory framework applicable to investment-based crowdfunding in France. French regulation, supervised by the Authority of Financial Markets (AMF-Autorité des Marchés Financiers) and the National Financial Services Regulator (ACPR-Autorité de Contrôle Prudentiel et de Résolution), has created two specific regulatory statutes for the Crowdfunding platforms: (i) IFP (Intermédiaire en Financement Participatif) for the straight loans offering; and (ii) CIP (Conseiller en Investissement Participatif) for securities offering (shares or debt instruments). Platforms must be registered in the “Registre Unique des

(16)

Intermédiaires en Assurance, Banque et Finance” managed by ORIAS (the French association in charge of a single register of insurance, banking, and financial intermediaries), and subscribe a professional liability insurance policy. Currently, six different tax incentive schemes are available in France to encourage crowdfunding investment.

Italy has been the first country to regulate equity crowdfunding in Europe by the Law 221 of 17 December 2012. Under the current Italian law, the management of equity crowdfunding portals can be carried out by two types of subjects: (i) entities authorised to provide investment services and subject to MiFID rules; (ii) other legal entities authorised ad hoc by the Italian financial markets’ regulator (CONSOB, Commissione Nazionale per le Società e per la Borsa). All portals’ managers, other than banks and financial intermediaries, have to register with the ordinary section of the Register of the portals’ managers, published on the CONSOB website. At least 5% of the financial instruments offered shall be subscribed (i) by professional investors; (ii) banking foundations; (iii) innovative startups incubators; (iv) investors in support of small and medium-sized enterprises that fulfil certain requirements. Probably due to the too prohibitive and strict regulation, the Italian crowdfunding market has been slower in taking off than some other European markets. The size of the market is rather small and quite concentrated in the northern regions. Over the last years, regulators have tried to improve the market by adopting ever more simplified rules.

The value of funds raised through crowdfunding platforms grew by 45% in 2017 compared to 2016, reaching approximately € 41million. The equity-based crowdfunding has raised € 11 million (more than 150% compared to 2016), financing 78 companies. At the end of 2017, the overall Italian crowdfunding market was composed of 67 active platforms (46 based on donation and reward model)2. Italian investors can benefit from fiscal incentives through equity and lending crowdfunding.

Spain regulated crowdfunding investment, both equity and lending, in April 2015 with the “Ley de Fomento de la Financiación Empresarial” (Law 5/2015). Participatory financing platforms

(17)

(Plataformas de Financiación Participativa, or PFP) are under the authorisation and registration of the CNMV, the Spanish securities market regulator, with the participation of the Bank of Spain in the case of lending-based crowdfunding. At the end of 2017, the CNMV has authorised 26 CFPs, of which eleven were through shares, ten through loans and five were combined share-loan projects. Crowdfunding market in Spain continues to grow. The total amount of money raised through crowdfunding increased from €73.172.388 in 2016 to €101.651.284 in 2017, which represents a growth of 38,92%. The highest growth comes from the donation platforms (86.93%) followed by lending (68.86%), equity (44.26%), and real estate (20.79%) (Ramos and Gonzalez, 2018). In Spain, national and regional tax incentives for investment in newly-formed companies are extended to crowdfunding investors.

Crowdfunding has been regulated only recently in Belgium by the Law of 18 December 2016 (“The Act”). The crowdfunding law creates a specific status for equity and debt crowdfunding platforms and lays down the operating requirements. To operate, equity crowdfunding platforms must be authorised by the FSMA (Financial Services and Markets Authority). Moreover, crowdfunding platforms may not receive or keep money in cash or on an account. Rewards and donation-based platforms are not within the scope of this law. The market size in Belgium is still small but is growing steadily. During the 2012-2017 period, 232 campaigns were successfully funded, raising €40,025,000 in total. Approximately €24,9 million has been raised in 2017 (of which 50% has been collected from lending platforms and the rest from donation and reward platforms). Some of the most active platforms are Ulule for reward and donation, Seedrs for equity, and Look&Fin for lending (FSMA, 2018). Since the entry into force of the Belgian Crowdfunding Law, on 1 February 2017, individual Belgian taxpayers investing in an equity crowdfunding platform recognised by the FSMA can benefit from the tax shelter for startups (launched in 2015 by Alexander De Croo). Crowdfunding law also introduced an exemption from the 30% withholding tax on interest payments on loans made to certain startup companies.

(18)

For each of the analysed countries, table 1 shows the number of offered incentives, the name of the scheme, the year of entry into force, if the incentive has been created especially for crowdfunding or not, and the crowdfunding model to which it applies.

INSERT TABLE 1

In total, 18 tax incentives are offered. France and the UK have the highest number of incentives, with six and four schemes respectively. Among the five countries in the sample, only three have implemented specific incentives for crowdfunding (the UK, France, and Belgium). It is interesting to note that all three schemes have been tailor-made for lending-based crowdfunding.

In the following subsections, we describe in detail the tax incentive schemes available for crowdfunding in the UK, France, Italy, Spain, and Belgium. Table 2. shows the tax benefits associated with each of these schemes.

INSERT TABLE 2

4.1 United Kingdom

There are some interesting tax relief schemes in the United Kingdom. These schemes help UK SMEs and social enterprises to improve their liquidity and offer investors the opportunity to obtain tax reliefs on buying and holding for a specific period, new shares, bonds, or assets. Her Majesty's Revenue and Customs (HMRC) provides and monitors on the application of four tax reliefs schemes. Crowdfunding through equity offers companies and investors the possibility to claim and keep the Enterprise Investment Scheme (EIS), and the Seed Enterprise Investment Scheme (SEIS), as long as the company in which they have invested respects the scheme rules for at least three years after the investment is made. Otherwise, tax reliefs will be withheld or withdrawn from investors. Peer-to-peer (P2P) lending crowdfunding also give lenders the opportunity to get tax reliefs through the Innovative Finance ISA Scheme (IFISA). Donations made through a crowdfunding platform are generally not tax deductible for donors unless the

(19)

project has been started by a qualified charity and not an individual, in which case, donors can use the Gift Aid scheme to deduct the invested amount. No tax reliefs are available for reward crowdfunding. Now we describe the aforementioned tax schemes.

4.1.1 Equity crowdfunding tax relief: EIS and SEIS schemes

The Enterprise Investment Scheme (EIS) was introduced in 1994 to encourage investment in unlisted companies. This scheme allows growth companies to raise up to £5 million each year, with a maximum of £12 million in a company’s lifetime (including the amounts received from other venture capital schemes and state aid approved under the risk finance guidelines)3.

To benefit from an EIS scheme, companies have to fulfill the following characteristics:

1) company can receive investment under the EIS scheme only within the first seven years from its first commercial sale. If a company has any subsidiaries, former subsidiaries, or it has acquired other companies, the date of the first commercial sale of the first company in the group is considered;

2) cannot be listed on a stock exchange;

3) has to be established in the UK;

4) cannot control another company other than qualifying subsidiaries4;

5) cannot be controlled by another company and more than 50% of its shares cannot be owned by another company;

6) company and any qualifying subsidiaries must have less than £15 million of gross assets before any shares are issued and not more than £16 million immediately afterward;

7) company and any qualifying subsidiaries must have fewer than 250 full-time equivalent employees at the time the shares are issued.

(20)

The money raised by the new share issue must be used for a qualifying business activity5 and must be spent within two years of the investment, or if later, the date the company began operations. In addition, the raised money can only be used to grow or develop the company business and cannot be used to buy all or part of another business, in any circumstances.

Knowledge-intensive companies that carry out a significant amount of research, development, and innovation can raise more than £12 million in the company’s lifetime as long as (i) the raised money is being used to enter a completely new product market or a new geographic market; (ii) the claimed money is at least 50% of the company’s average annual revenue for the last five years; (iii) company didn't receive investment (under EIS, SEIS, SITR, VCT or state aid approved under the risk finance guidelines), within seven years of its first commercial sale. The shares for EIS investments must be paid in full with cash, at the time of issue and must be full risk ordinary shares (i.e., not redeemable and without special rights to company assets). In addition, shares can have limited preferential rights to dividends.

The shares issuance cannot be accompanied by an arrangement which (i) guarantee the investment or protect the investor from risk; or (ii) allows investors to sell the shares at end or during the investment period; or (iii) leaves investor’s benefit from the EIS in a way that’s not been intended; or (iv) an arrangement authorising investors to raise money for the purpose of tax avoidance; or (v) a reciprocal agreement in which companies invest back in an investor’s company to also gain tax relief.

EIS allows sophisticated investors to deduct up to 30% of the invested amount from their income tax, as long as the acquired shares are held at least for three years. Investors can carry back part of the EIS tax relief to the tax year preceding the investment. However, the deduction is limited to a maximum investment of £1 million for a single person and £2 million for a couple in a tax year and investors will be bound into the scheme for a minimum of three years. EIS is exempt from inheritance tax if the investor holds the acquired shares for a minimum of two years, and from capital gains tax if the investor holds the acquired shares for a minimum of three years.

(21)

Investors can defer up to 50% of the capital gains tax on gains realised on the disposal of any asset, provided that these gains are reinvested in an EIS eligible company. Moreover, investors can obtain a tax relief from investment losses when the shares of the EIS company are disposed at a loss, and such losses can be used to offset the investors' capital gains or income tax in the year of disposal or the previous year. Currently, there is no minimum investment requirement for EIS investments (until 6 April 2012 a minimum investment of £500 was required).

The Seed Enterprise Investment Scheme (SEIS) was introduced in 2012 to encourage investments in seed-stage companies by offering tax reliefs at a higher rate than those offered by the existing EIS6. This scheme provides for:

1) a reduction of 50% of the invested amount on the income tax liability, but not more than the maximum figure of £100,000 of the investments per tax year. Investors can carry back part of the SEIS tax relief to the previous tax year;

2) a relief up to 50% on capital gains tax, with a maximum of £50,000, in respect of capital gains realised and reinvested through EIS eligible companies in the same tax year;

3) in case of company fail, investors can claim up to 80% of the investment as tax relief against their income tax liability;

4) an exemption from capital gains tax for any gain arising on the disposal of the shares, if these are held for a minimum of three years.

There is no minimum investment requirement for SEIS investments and investors cannot be employees of the company. SEIS relief can be claimed up to five years after the 31st of January in the year which the investment was made; the maximum amount that can be collected through SEIS investments is £150,000 per year, including any other state aid received in the three years up to the date of the investment. Moreover, SEIS tax relief applies only under the following conditions:

(22)

2) companies must have 25 or less employees and gross assets of up to £200,000 at the time of the share issue – including the group’s employees and assets if the company has subsidiaries;

3) companies cannot be listed on the stock exchange, and cannot have (with their subsidiaries) an arrangement to become listed at the time of the share issue;

4) company cannot control another company other than qualifying subsidiaries;

5) companies shall be incorporated for less than two years;

6) an individual’s stake in the company can be no more than 30%;

7) companies and their subsidiaries may not be members of a partnership;

8) companies cannot have previously raised funds from other EIS investors or a venture capital trust.

The raised money must be spent within three years from a share issue and can be only used on the qualifying business activity for which it was raised. The investment cannot be used to buy shares, other than in a qualifying 90% subsidiary which uses that money for qualifying business activity. Shares issued for SEIS investments have to fulfill the same requirements provided for shares issued under EIS.

4.1.2 Peer-to-peer lending crowdfunding tax relief: IFISA tax scheme

Since April 1999, the UK Government has offered the Individual Savings Accounts (ISAs) to promote a higher propensity to save by low- and medium-income families. The ISAs are tax-exempt savings accounts allowing individuals aged 18 or over who are resident and ordinarily resident in the UK to invest in cash, stocks or shares, and life insurance, with an investment limit of £20,000 for the 2017/18 tax year, per person8. ISAs are exempt from income tax, and capital gains tax on the investment returns and investors also do not pay tax on money withdrawn from their ISA. In April 2016, the UK Government introduced the Innovative Finance ISA (IFISA),

(23)

which allows residents of the United Kingdom to use some (or all) of their annual Individual Savings Accounts (ISAs) to lend money through Financial Conduct Authority (FCA)-regulated and approved P2P platforms. IFISAs also receive tax-free interest and capital gains on their investments up to the limit of £20,000 for 2017/18 financial year9. The UK Government sets the limit on an annual basis, and investors cannot roll over their investment allowance into the following tax year. Lending products eligible for the IFISA include bonds and revenue-based loans - i.e., personal loans, small business loans, and property loans. Lenders can offset the losses they suffer on the unpaid loans against the interest they receive on other P2P loans before the income is taxed. Tax relief allows a 12-month carry back and applies only if there is no reasonable possibility of the P2P loan being repaid, and doesn’t apply to late payment. If the borrower manages to pay the loan at a later date, or if there is a recovery of assets, and the lender has already received the tax relief for a bad debt, the amount is treated as new P2P income of the lender. To obtain the tax relief on bad debt, the lender must be subject to UK income tax on their P2P income and loan shall take place on P2P lending platforms that are authorised by the FCA. P2P loans through crowdfunding platforms are not currently protected by the Financial Services Compensation Scheme (FSCS).

4.1.3 Donation crowdfunding tax relief: Gift Aid scheme

Gift Aid is a government tax relief scheme that allows charities to claim back the basic rate of tax already paid on every eligible donation by the donor since donations are exempt from tax10. More in detail, charities can claim back from HM Revenue & Customs (HMRC) 25 p for every £1 donated by a UK taxpayer (VAT and Council Tax do not apply), increasing the donation value by 25%.

The following are not eligible for Gift Aid:

1) donations from non-UK taxpayers;

2) donations which are not 'free will' gifts but are made in return of something such as tickets (raffles, events, and auctions) or goods and services (including ‘experience’ days);

(24)

3) donations made on behalf of third parties – a person, group of people, or company. This is because the HMRC needs to know the details of the person actually contributing the funds and, as a consequence, a Gift Aid declaration can only be made on the taxpayer’s personal status;

4) donations to a family member who's taking part in an event when the charity is contributing to the cost.

4. 2 France

Recognising the importance of crowdfunding, France supports the financing of French companies providing tax benefits for investments in SMEs. Individuals and professionals whose income is taxable in France are eligible for the following tax reliefs11:

1) “Madelin” tax reductions: all those who are liable for income tax (IR-Impôt sur le revenu) are allowed to deduct 25% (18% previously) of the amounts invested directly or indirectly (through a holding company) in the capital of unlisted French and European SMEs. To benefit from the tax deduction, the shares must be held for a minimum of five years, and the subscription must take place by 31 December of the current fiscal year. The tax benefit is limited to € 50,000 (with a maximum tax reduction of € 12,500) for a single person and € 100,000 for a couple (with a maximum tax reduction of € 25,000). Investments in excess of the annual limit give the right to receive, under the same conditions, the tax reduction in the following four years (right to carry forward). This reduction cannot be combined with that of the solidarity wealth tax (ISF-Impôt de solidarité sur la fortune). Moreover, depending on the holding period of the securities, a tax reduction is possible on the capital gain resulting from the sale of these securities. For a detention period of one to four years, up to 50% of reduction is possible, 65% from four to eight years and 85% after eight years. The tax relief benefit is reserved for natural persons who have their tax domicile in France;

(25)

2) solidarity wealth tax reduction (ISF): before 31 December 2017 all those required to pay the ISF were allowed, under certain conditions, a reduction of 50% of the amounts invested directly or indirectly (through a holding company) in the capital of unlisted French and European SMEs. However, with the recent reform of the Financial Law in 2018, the ISF has been substituted by the real-estate wealth tax (IFI-Impôt sur la fortune immobilière), with effect from the 1 January 2018. The IFI tax is levied only on property values (excluding securities) and doesn't provide tax reduction for investments in small and medium-sized companies. Therefore, the IFI cannot be used as a tax incentive for crowdfunding investment;

3) stock saving plan (PEA/PEA-PME)12: natural persons who have their tax domicile in France can buy a portfolio of shares of French and European SMEs and mid-caps, with the possibility to benefit from a tax exemption on dividends and capital gains if securities are held for a minimum duration of five years. The maximum amount is €150,000 for a single taxpayer. The profits tax depends then on the year of securities divestment. Before five years, the tax will be 22.5%, 19% between five and eight years and, 0% after eight years. In this case, the capital gain must be however reinvested in the PEA. The classic PEA (Le Plan d’Epargne en Actions), allows investing in companies without capitalization constraint. The PEA-PME (Plan d'Épargne en Actions dédié aux Petites et Moyennes Entreprises-PME) allows investment only in SMEs companies with fewer than 5,000 employees and with an annual turnover of less than 1.5 billion euros or a balance sheet total of less than 2 billion euros. The maximum amount is €75,000 for a single taxpayer. These benefits cannot be combined with those on the IR or the ISF.

Companies can benefit from the system of taxation applicable in the case of parent companies and subsidiaries (régime des mères et filiales) for securities held at least eight years. If the parent company holds at least 5% of the subsidiary company, two years of detention is then sufficient to benefit from the tax exemption (the ‘Niche Copé’). The ‘Niche Copé’ is an exemption of 88% from corporate tax on capital gains received by natural or legal persons, especially holding

(26)

companies, in the case of sale of their subsidiaries or equity securities held for more than two years.

Donation-based crowdfunding also gives investors (individuals and enterprises) the opportunity to obtain tax benefits if and only if the project promoters are organizations that work in the common interest, foundations and associations recognized as being of public utility. Only in this case, the project promoter will send investors a tax receipt to be attached to their tax return. Investors will benefit from the deduction in force, currently 66% of the contribution, if the investor is an individual, up to 20% of taxable income (60% of contribution up to 0.5% of annual turnover if the investor is an enterprise). The rate of the tax reduction is increased to 75% (up to a limit of € 530) for investments made to non-profit organizations that provide free meals to people in need, who help to promote their housing or who are primarily responsible for the free provision of care. Investments in rewards-based crowdfunding provide tax reduction if the reward has a value less than 25% of the investment amount and have a value less than € 60. If these conditions are not met, the investment does not give rise to a tax benefit.

To promote the development of lending-based crowdfunding, French regulation has provided for losses allocation system (loss relief). In particular, Article 25 of the Law 2015-1786 of 29 December 2015 of the Amending Finance Act for 2015, allows lenders to offset the capital losses incurred in the event of non-repayment of loans granted since 1 January 2016, through crowdfunding platforms, against the interest generated by other loans granted during the same year or in the subsequent five years (CGI art. 125-00 A). Article 44 of the Law 2016-1918 of 29 December 2016 of the Amending Finance Act for 2016 extended the benefit of this losses allocation system to the Mini-bonds subscribed from 1 January 2017 up to € 8,000 during the same year.

4. 3 Italy

The Italian tax regulators provide tax benefits for investments in innovative startups and SMEs (Order of 30 January 2014 of The Ministry of Economy and Finance -MEF). These benefits have

(27)

been recently extended to equity crowdfunding by the Budget Law that went into effect on 1 January 2018. In detail13, natural persons can benefit from a tax deduction on income tax (IRPEF- Imposta sul reddito delle persone fisiche) of 30% (19% previously) of the invested amount. The deduction is limited to €1 million (€ 500,000 previously) per year. In the same way, legal entities can obtain a tax credit on corporate tax (IRES- Imposta sul reddito delle società) of 30% (20% previously) of the invested amount up to a maximum of €1.8 million per year. Tax reductions apply for direct investments made through startups, SMEs and social enterprises, and also for indirect investments made through mutual investment bodies or other joint stock companies that invest mainly in small and medium-sized businesses.

To benefit from the tax deduction, the participation instruments must be held for a minimum of three years (two years previously) and must submit as part of the tax filing a set of documents and certifications, which include:

1) the certification attesting the compliance with the maximum limits for contributions about the tax period in which the investment was made; and

2) the company investment plan, containing detailed information on the subject of its activity, on the products and the current or expected performance of sales and profits.

Law n.205 of the 27 December 2017 (2018 Budget Law) regulates the P2P lending by including income from loans granted through P2P lending platforms within the incomes from capital14. It states that such platforms must be managed by payment institutions or by companies authorized by the Bank of Italy, according to Article 106 of the Consolidated Law on Banking (TUB – Testo Unico Bancario). For non-professional lenders, the income from P2P lending is subject to a 26%

withholding tax to be levied by the authorised platforms' managers.

Following the Budget Law 2018 (Law no. 205 of 27 December 2017), peer to peer lending, originated through crowdfunding platforms, have been included within the eligible investments for the Individual Long-term Savings Plans (PIR). Like the UK's IFISAs, Italian PIRs receive tax-free interest and capital gains on their investments.

(28)

4.4 Spain

Spanish regulation makes available some tax breaks to investors15. Investors in Spanish companies that are less than three years old16 are entitled to a deduction of 20% of their investment on the income tax (IRPF-Impuesta sobre la renta de las personas fisicas). The deduction is limited to €10,000 a year for a single tax payer. Moreover, investors must not have working relations with the company, and they must not hold, together with the family group, more than 40% of its capital.

Many autonomous communities offer additional incentives to their residents and companies. These regional tax reliefs are complementary to the state tax reliefs and increase the total deductible limit. For example, in Andalucía investors receive a supplementary 20% break. This means that if they invest in a new company, they can write off 40% of that investment on their income tax returns at the end of the year. Supplemental tax breaks by autonomous communities are described below:

1) Madrid: deduction of 20% with a maximum amount of €4,000;

2) Cataluña: deduction of 30% with a maximum amount of €6,000;

3) Andalucía: deduction of 20% with a maximum amount of €4,000;

4) Galicia: deduction of 20% with a maximum amount of €4,000;

5) Aragón: deduction of 20% with a maximum amount of €4,000;

6) Baleares: deduction of 20% with a maximum amount of €600;

7) Murcia: deduction of 20% with a maximum amount of €4,000;

8) Cantabria: deduction of 15% with a maximum amount of €2,000.

The remaining regions do not have additional tax incentives. To be able to take advantage of these benefits, the company has to be fiscally resident in the same region as the investor.

(29)

To encourage investment in early-stage companies, Spain has also put into place others incentives. First, all profit made upon the disposal of the investment is not taxable under the following conditions:

1) the reinvestment must be made in early-stage companies during the year following the disinvestment date;

2) the participation in the invested company shall be of at least three year's duration;

3) the participation in the invested company together with the relatives of 1° and 2°s degree must not overcome the 40% of the social capital;

4) there is no tax exemption for participations sold to relatives of 2°degrees, or entities linked to the sender.

Second, if the invested company fails, the investment can be recovered by writing off your capital gains tax for up to four years.

Donation in non-profit entities give investors (natural and legal persons) the possibility to obtain tax benefits17. In particular, for natural persons, the first €150 donated has a deduction of 75% in the entire IRPF fee. What exceeds €150 has a deduction of 30% in the fee. A deduction of 35% (instead of the general 30%) may be applied, provided that donations have been made for the same or greater amount to the same entity in the two previous immediate tax periods. The deduction has a limit of 10% of the taxable base in the IRPF. For legal persons, the donated amount has a deduction in the corporate tax rate of 35%. A deduction of 40% (instead of the general 35%) may be applied provided that donations have been made for the same or greater amount to the same entity in the two previous immediate tax periods. The deduction has a limit of 10% of the tax base of the tax period.

4. 5 Belgium

Belgian legislation provides interesting tax incentives for individuals who invest in Belgian startups (SMEs or micro-enterprises) through crowdfunding platforms recognised by the

(30)

Authority for Financial Services and Markets (FSMA)18. In particular, since the inception of the Crowdfunding Platform Act in 201719, all natural persons subject to the Belgian natural person tax or the non-resident person tax can benefit from:

1) a personal income tax reduction of 30% of the sum invested in SMEs which have less than 250 employees, a turnover of maximum €50 million, and a total balance sheet value not exceeding €43 million; and

2) a personal income tax reduction of 45% of the sum invested in micro-enterprises with less than 10 employees and maximum revenue and total balance sheet value not exceeding € 2 million.

The total amount of the investment qualifying for a tax exemption may not exceed €250,000 per startup.

Each person can invest a maximum of €100,000 per year and can benefit from a maximum tax reduction of 45% each year (with a maximum of €45,000) for investments made in micro-enterprises, and a maximum tax reduction of 30% each year (with a maximum of €30,000) for investments made in SMEs. Tax relief can be gained for the year in which the investment occurred and cannot be refunded or transferred. Furthermore, to benefit from the tax incentives, investors must hold onto the investment (shares) at least four years.

No tax deductions are available to companies, and any director of the startup is not eligible for the tax advantage.

To ensure the tax reliefs to their investors, the startups have to adhere to certain conditions, including:

1) the startup shall be an unlisted Belgian or EU tax resident company or must have a permanent establishment in Belgium or the EU;

2) the funds raised cannot be used to distribute dividends, to issue loans or to buy shares during 48 months as from the investment date;

(31)

3) during at least 48 months as of the investment, the startup cannot change their business to become an investment firm, a finance company, a treasury company, a management company, a real estate company, or a patrimonial company;

4) the tax reduction may not exceed 30% of the startup’s share capital per investor;

5) the tax shelter investment must be fully paid up in cash;

6) the startup may not be the result of a merger or spin-off operation;

7) the startup may not have distributed any dividend or made any capital reduction previously.

The new crowdfunding law also allows for a tax exemption on interest produced by loans to startups through regulated crowdfunding platforms. The tax treatment of crowdfunding loans scheme was announced in 2015 and, together with the UK’s IFISA and France's losses allocation system, is specifically targeted to investors in SMEs through crowdfunding. To participate in the scheme, investors are required to be natural persons acting in their private capacity. Entrepreneurs, executive managers, and key personnel can also benefit from the exemption for loans granted to the company as long as they meet the criteria defined above. The maximum exempted amount on interest, per taxpayer per year, may not exceed € 15,000 of the loan (article 21,13° of the Belgian Income Tax Code). The loan needs to have a minimum duration of 4 years in SME’s of less than four years.

Belgian investors can obtain a tax advantage by supporting a charity and large relief operations through donation-based crowdfunding platforms. To obtain the tax relief donations must be made to a recognised entity20, must have at least an amount of € 40 per calendar year, per recognised entity, and should be made in cash. Moreover, the recognised entity must issue a tax certificate to the donor indicating the amount of donations made for the calendar year concerned. According to the Belgian Income Tax Code, natural persons can recover between 40% and 50% annually of their donation, which cannot exceed the greater of (i) or 10% of total net income or (ii) € 376.350

(32)

(for financial years 2017 and 2018). The amounts donated by a legal entity subject to corporate income tax can be fully deducted from its profit made in the taxable period concerned (with a maximum of (i) either 5% of the taxable income or (ii) a threshold of € 500.000).

5. Comparison of tax incentive schemes for crowdfunding

In this section, we compare and evaluate the 18 tax incentive schemes identified in section 4. For this purpose, we use three comparison dimensions:

1. the incentives structure, which includes the form and timing of the incentive and the tax base;

2. the business characteristics, which include the firm age, the status (listed on the stock exchange or not), and the headquarters (in the jurisdiction granting the tax relief or not);

3. the type of investor, which includes the distinction between natural persons and corporate investors, and tax resident or not.

5.1 Tax incentives structure

As described in section 3, tax incentives can take multiple forms. The most common forms are tax credit, tax exemption, tax deduction, tax deferral, and loss relief. The majority of the tax incentive schemes in our sample provides just one form of the tax incentive. Three of the 18 schemes offer a combination of different forms of tax incentives within one scheme. The UK's EIS and SEIS, utilise tax exemption, tax credit, tax deferral, and loss relief. The Italian incentive for investment in innovative startups and SMEs use both tax credit and tax exemption. Figure 2 shows that tax credit and tax exemption are the most used incentive forms in the sample, with 8 of the 18 schemes analysed provide this form of incentive. Four schemes use tax deduction and three loss relief. Only two schemes utilise tax deferral.

(33)

Tax incentives can be applied in different stages of the investment lifecycle. Considering the timing across the investment lifecycle, we can distinguish between three types of tax incentive:

1. up-front tax incentives for the investor on the amount invested;

2. tax incentives on the income received and return from the qualifying investment (dividends, capital gains) and treatment of losses;

3. tax incentives on the sale or disposal of the assets held (capital gains, inheritance or gift taxes).

Figure 3 shows that the most widely used stage of application in the investment lifecycle is the initial investment, followed by the relief on disposal and then finally on income received. The UK, France, and Spain provide tax incentives at multiple stages of the investment lifecycle. Italy and Belgium only in one stage.

INSERT FIGURE 3

Tax incentive can apply to different tax bases corresponding to the nature of the investor which claim the incentive (natural persons and/or corporate) and to the nature of the return generated by the investment. Figure 4 shows that among the 18 tax incentive schemes analysed, the personal income tax is the most used tax base. Five schemes operate a unified tax base for income and capital gains taxation. Only the Spanish incentive for investments in newly-formed companies provides the use of all three tax bases within one tax incentive.

INSERT FIGURE 4

5.2 Business characteristics

Tax incentives are often used to stimulate investment in businesses with certain characteristics. Tax incentives for crowdfunding, for example, are typically used to promote investment in young, unlisted companies. Figure 5 shows that nine of the 18 schemes in our sample use business age criteria, with France's "Niche cope" topping the table with 10-year maximum age criteria.

Figura

Figure 1. Alternative finance volume by country in 2016 (in million Euros).
Table 1. Overview of the tax incentive schemes in force in the analysed countries.
Table 2. Benefits of tax incentive schemes in the analysed countries.
Figure 2. Forms of tax incentives.
+4

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

This  research  work  analyzes  the  existing  instruments  to  deflate  tax  legal  disputes  between  tax  payers  and  Revenue  Agency,  in  order  to  identify 

In gioco c’è qualcosa di assai […] radicale e problematico, perché la vita non è solo coestensiva ma consustanziale rispetto alla formazione, il

Tabella 3 - Mercanti e fattori genovesi a Southampton, 1459-1468 Mercanti Fattori 1459-60 (E179/173/137, E179/137/142) Edwardus Catane Lucianus Spynelle Dimitrius Spynelle Angelo

Il Panvinio nel suo particolar trattato de Peregrinatione, dice: Che |15| la Pellegrinatione cominciò a pratticarsi da Christiani, prima alle Chiese erette (giusta

(a) Average and standard deviation of the optimal trading strategies with parameters given by Table 1 when the drift process is negative and short selling is allowed and

Hence the lost tax revenue due to non-compliance is either strictly increasing or has an inverted U -shaped time path, when the firm is regulated with an increasing emission tax

4 Reti con attivit` a spontanea 62 4.1 Il modello di Izhikevich per neuroni dotati di attivit` a spontanea 62 4.2 Simulazione di una rete

(38) Con alcune decisive anticipazioni già nel Passaggio di Enea e poi nel Seme del piangere (nel «nominalismo pressoché blanchotiano» (30) dei Lamenti, e più «nella pratica