• Non ci sono risultati.

The evolution of job stability and wages after the implementation of the Hartz reforms

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "The evolution of job stability and wages after the implementation of the Hartz reforms"

Copied!
28
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

1 23

Journal for Labour Market Research Zeitschrift für ArbeitsmarktForschung ISSN 1614-3485

Volume 49 Number 3

J Labour Market Res (2016) 49:269-294 DOI 10.1007/s12651-016-0209-x

The evolution of job stability and wages

after the implementation of the Hartz

reforms

Gianna C. Giannelli, Ursula Jaenichen &

Thomas Rothe

(2)

1 23

Commons Attribution license which allows

users to read, copy, distribute and make

derivative works, as long as the author of

the original work is cited. You may

self-archive this article on your own website, an

institutional repository or funder’s repository

and make it publicly available immediately.

(3)

A R T I C L E

DOI 10.1007/s12651-016-0209-x

The evolution of job stability and wages after the implementation of

the Hartz reforms

Gianna C. Giannelli1,2· Ursula Jaenichen3· Thomas Rothe3

Accepted: 1 August 2016 / Published online: 29 September 2016

© The Author(s) 2016. This article is available at SpringerLink with Open Access.

Abstract We address the concerns about rising inequality

in the German labour market after the implementation of the Hartz reforms between 2003 and 2005. We focus on the quality of new jobs started between 1998 and 2010 in West Germany in terms of job stability and level of earn-ings. Using social security data drawn from the Integrated Employment Biographies, we analyse the distributions of job durations and wages and model their determinants at the worker level. Our results show a high degree of job stability during and after the reform years, decreasing wage levels and increasing wage dispersion.

Keywords Hartz reforms · Job duration · Wage inequality JEL classification C34 · C41 · J31 · J62 · J68

Die Entwicklung von Beschäftigungsstabilität und Löhnen seit Einführung der Hartz-Reformen Zusammenfassung Seit den Hartz-Reformen in den

Jah-ren 2003 bis 2005 gibt es Hinweise auf eine gestiegene Ungleichheit im deutschen Arbeitsmarkt. Anhand der Indi-katoren Stabilität und Entlohnung untersuchen wir die Qua-lität von Beschäftigungsverhältnissen, die im Zeitraum von 1998 bis 2010 begonnen haben. Mit administrativen Daten aus den Integrierten Erwerbsbiographien analysieren wir

 Ursula Jaenichen ursula.jaenichen@iab.de

1 University of Florence, Florence, Italy 2 IZA, Bonn, Germany

3 IAB, Nuremberg, Germany

die Verteilungen und modellieren individuelle Determinan-ten von Beschäftigungsdauern und Löhnen. Die Ergebnisse weisen auf ein hohes Maß an Stabilität in den Beschäfti-gungsdauern, einen Rückgang des Lohnniveaus und einen Anstieg der Lohnungleichheit während und nach der Peri-ode der Hartz-Reformen hin.

1 Introduction

The Hartz reforms were implemented from 2003 to 2005 after the so-called “placement scandal” of the Federal Em-ployment Agency (Fleckenstein 2008). The aims of the Hartz reforms were to improve public employment services, enhance the efficiency of active labour market policies and decrease the number of unemployed persons in Germany. Among the reforms were the restructuring of the Federal Employment Agency, a reorganisation of the local employ-ment agencies, and several minor legislative changes related to dismissal protection, fixed-term contracts and temporary agency work (see, e. g., Jacobi and Kluve2007). The most important reform, Hartz IV, abolished the then-existing un-employment assistance for long-term unemployed workers and consolidated this program with social assistance for households in need, thereby worsening the conditions for a vast majority of longer-term unemployment benefit recip-ients.1

In the years following the reforms, the labour market in Germany performed surprisingly well: from 2005 to 2008, unemployment decreased by one-third, while employment liable to social insurance increased by approximately the same amount (1.5 million persons, see Fig. 1). During

1 See Goebel and Richter (2007) for an early analysis of changes in the available income of unemployment benefit recipients.

(4)

Fig. 1 Number of Employed and Unemployed persons in Germany (Source: German Federal Employment Agency, quarterly average of monthly data, seasonally adjusted, own calculations) 0 1.000 2.000 3.000 4.000 5.000 6.000 24.000 25.000 26.000 27.000 28.000 29.000 30.000 U n empl oy ment i n 1. 000 E m ploym e nt in 1.000

Employment (le scale) Unemployment (right scale) pre-reform reform post-reform

period

the recession years of 2008/2009, both the decrease in em-ployment and the increase in unemem-ployment were modest, although GDP decreased dramatically (see Fig. 2). This phenomenon was noticed worldwide, and Krugman even called it “Germany’s job miracle”. Nevertheless, there are concerns about rising wage inequality (Card et al. 2013) and the increasing prevalence of atypical and low-wage jobs (Eichhorst and Tobsch2015), tendencies that may have laid the groundwork for the introduction of a general minimum wage in Germany in 2015.

This paper takes the positive overall performance of the German labour market following the Hartz reforms and dur-ing the great recession as a startdur-ing point for our analysis of whether there is an unsavoury side to this positive trend in the form of lower job quality. We use job duration and wages as indicators of job quality and look at new jobs started between 1998 and 2010 (the terms “job duration” and “job stability” are used as synonyms throughout the paper). We are interested in whether changes in job quality occurred in the “middle” of the labour market and therefore analyse the stability and wages of regular jobs covered by social security.

The quality of a specific job has various dimensions and many of them are difficult to measure. In addition to wages and stability, aspects such as mental and physical stress, autonomy and self-responsibility, temporary versus perma-nent contracts, working time, and the reconciliation of fam-ily and working life have been the subjects of research.2The 2 For an overview of several aspects of job quality, see Osterman (2013) and the literature cited therein.

main reasons for our choice of indicators of job quality are that job stability and earnings are extremely important economically and that our data allow us to observe these indicators very precisely (limitations are discussed later in the paper).

The expectation that the Hartz reforms have increased in-equality and created a generation of jobs that are lower paid and less stable than jobs in the past is supported by search-theoretical arguments. Intensive monitoring and stricter use of sanctions will increase the job search intensity of ployed workers. The worsening of conditions for unem-ployment benefit recipients will lead to lower reservation wages and increase the willingness of unemployed work-ers to accept jobs of a given quality. Rebien and Kettner (2011) report that after the reforms, job applicants more often accepted jobs with worse working conditions, e. g., longer commutes and even lower wages. In Sweden, Van den Berg and Vikström (2014) demonstrate that the use of sanctions induced unemployed job-seekers to take jobs with lower wages, fewer working hours and fewer qualification requirements.

The Hartz reforms also contained certain deregulative elements, such as a reduction of dismissal protection in small firms and a relaxation of the legislation on temporary agency work. The growing use of working contracts that offer less employment protection could be another source of the rising inequality in the labour market.

There are also good reasons to expect positive effects of labour market reforms on job quality. The matching of unemployed workers to jobs may have been positively influ-enced by the reorganisation of local employment agencies

(5)

Fig. 2 Hiring and Separation Rates over the Business Cycle (Source: Quarterly hiring rate [hirings(t)/employment(t-1)] and separation rate [separations(t)/ employment(t-1)] are calculated using official data of the German Federal Employment Agency. GDP is provided by the Federal Statistical Office) -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09 GD P g rowth rate (chang e ov er prev io us y e ar) hi ri ng rate and se para o n rate

GDP growth rate hiring rate separaon rate reform

period

pre-reform post-reform

combined with the tightening of active labour market poli-cies. Even if increased pressure on unemployed job-seekers will induce them to accept worse jobs in the first round, ac-cepting these jobs might result in shorter unemployment durations, less depreciation of human capital, less stigma-tisation and better signals to firms in the second round.3

Similarly, atypical jobs may become stepping stones into permanent and better-paid jobs in the medium run.4All in

all, it is an empirical question whether the Hartz reforms have had a positive or a negative influence on job quality.

It should be noted that the extent to which the Hartz re-forms have influenced the German labour market is contro-versial. In a recent and prominent paper, Dustmann et al. (2014) argue that the scale of the Hartz reforms was not sufficiently large to substantially contribute to the positive changes in competitiveness and unemployment observed af-ter the reform period. These authors stress the importance of factors such as flexibility in the German wage-setting institutions and the growing importance of firm-level nego-tiation of wages since the restructuring of the German econ-omy after reunification. However, another view is that the Hartz reforms and “especially the merger between unem-ployment assistance and welfare, deeply changed the

fun-3 Nekoei and Weber (2015) and Schmieder et al. (2016) discuss the effect of extending benefit entitlement periods and highlight the impact of non-employment duration on wages.

4 Research on previous (pre-Hartz) changes in the employment protec-tion law yields mixed results on dismissal probabilities and job stability (Bauer et al.2007; Boockmann et al.2008).

damental labor market institutions” (Möller2015, p. 164). Similarly, the reduced generosity of the unemployment ben-efit system as a result of the Hartz reforms is considered a key determinant of the wage moderation during the years preceding the great recession (Gartner and Merkl2011).

Although we share the view that the Hartz reforms had an important influence on the German labour market, we do not aim to estimate the size of this impact or to dis-entangle it from other factors that have contributed to the positive labour market outcomes observed in recent years. Our results on job durations and wages are descriptive in character; nevertheless, we will also perform econometric model analyses that account for worker and job heterogene-ity.

We contribute new evidence to previous research in sev-eral ways. First, whereas existing studies have focussed primarily on wages, we analyse both wages and job dura-tion because both aspects are fundamental dimensions of job quality. Second, a distinctive feature of our analysis is that we select cohorts of newly started jobs. We ex-pect the employment contracts of workers taking new jobs to respond immediately to changes in both legislation and market conditions. Third, we update the evidence through 2010, giving us a period of analysis that allows us to con-sider a sufficiently long time span (five years) after the Hartz reforms.

The paper is organized as follows. In Sect. 2, we review the literature on job stability and wages in Germany. In Sect. 3, we describe our empirical strategy, and in Sect. 4,

(6)

we present the results. The paper ends with concluding remarks.

2 The Hartz reforms and recent trends in job stability and wages in Germany: a review of the literature

There are several macro-level studies analysing the influ-ence of the Hartz reforms on aggregate matching efficiency. Fahr and Sunde (2009) estimate positive effects of the first two reform packages (which addressed the organisation of the Federal Employment Agency and local employment agencies) on both the duration of unemployment and the matching probability. Subsequent aggregate studies con-firm the improved matching efficiency following the imple-mentation of the Hartz reforms (Hertweck and Sigrist2013) and the increase in job-finding rates, not only for the short-term unemployed but also for the long-short-term unemployed (Klinger and Rothe2012). Launov and Wälde (2016) ana-lyse the impact of different elements of the Hartz reforms using structural equilibrium models. Comparing pre- and post-reform steady states, the estimated effect of the reform of the public employment agencies in Germany accounts for approximately 20 % of the reduction in equilibrium unem-ployment, whereas the Hartz IV reform accounts for an-other 5 %. Taken together, these studies confirm that that the functioning of the German labour market improved af-ter the reforms. The reform of the benefit system through the Hartz IV reform seems to be of minor importance in the macroeconomic context.

The cyclical behaviour of aggregate labour turnover in Germany gives a first impression of whether jobs have be-come more or less stable since the mid-nineties (Rothe 2009). Fig.2shows the overall trends in hiring and separa-tion rates over the business cycle between 1996 and 2012. Beginning with the year 2001, both rates clearly drop and continue to decrease during the period of the Hartz reforms. Remarkably, both hiring and separation rates remain fairly low during the cyclical upturn following the Hartz reforms (instead of returning to higher levels) and in the recession years 2008 and 2009. Thus, there has been a reduction in worker turnover in Germany that started before the Hartz reforms and continued thereafter. If job stability had de-creased significantly after the reform period, we would have expected to see a corresponding increase in the turnover rates. This first piece of evidence will be confirmed and complemented by analyses that account for job heterogene-ity in our micro-level analysis.

Regarding existing micro-evidence for Germany, there are studies that should be mentioned even if most of them do not refer to the Hartz reforms. These studies look at long-term trends in job stability or wages, and several of

them focus explicitly on inequality and the processes of sorting or polarization in the labour market.5

Most analyses of long-term trends in individual job du-ration indicate a constant or declining level of job stability. Bergemann and Mertens (2011) find a tendency towards shorter job durations for the period 1984 to 1998, but other studies present evidence of a rather constant level of job stability until the middle of the last decade (Giannelli et al. 2012; Rhein 2010). Giesecke and Heisig (2011) look at the long period from 1984 to 2008 and thus cover the first years after the Hartz reforms. They find that overall mo-bility between firms has remained fairly constant, whereas less qualified workers have experienced a decline in job stability over time.

Boockmann and Steffes (2010) focus on the determi-nants of job duration in Germany and demonstrate that in addition to the socio-economic characteristics of workers, the internal structure of firms, as captured by the existence of working councils or further training opportunities, con-tributes to longer job duration. Furthermore, the results suggest a sorting process of workers with higher expected duration to firms offering more stable employment.

The recent literature on wages contains influential contri-butions that demonstrate a rise in wage dispersion in West Germany over the last several decades. Dustmann et al. (2009) focus on wages between 1975 and 2004 and docu-ment that inequality has continued to rise since the 1980s. In the 1980s, it was mainly the upper half of the wage distribution that was affected, but in the early 1990s, in-equality also started to increase at the bottom half of the wage distribution. Antonczyk et al. (2010) find particularly pronounced growth of wage inequality at the bottom of the wage distribution from 2001 to 2006. Card et al. (2013) look at full-time workers in the years from 1985 to 2009 in West Germany and demonstrate that increased hetero-geneity in the establishment component of wages strongly contributes to the rise in wage inequality. They also find evidence that (positive) assortative matching has increased, with workers’ wage potential being more closely correlated with firms’ wage premia over time. Cornelißen and Hübler (2011) estimate the influence of unobserved individual and firm heterogeneity on wage and job-duration functions us-ing German linked employer-employee data for the years 1996 to 2002. Somewhat at odds with the results of Card et al. (2013), the estimated individual and firm effects

5 In the international literature, Gottschalk and Moffitt (1999) provide an overview of early research on job instability in the US during the 1980s and 1990s. Booth et al. (1999) examine job mobility and job duration over the period 1915 to 1990 in the UK. Autor et al. (2006,

2008) and Goos and Manning (2007) are examples of recent efforts to study wage inequality and job polarization in the US and the UK. Goos et al. (2009) provide evidence of disproportionate increases in both high-paid and low-paid employment in 16 European countries.

(7)

show that high-wage workers tend to be stable workers and are more likely to be employed in low-wage firms, whereas low-wage workers are more likely to accept jobs with shorter durations in high-wage firms.6

The study of Riphahn and Schnitzlein (2016) analyses individual wage mobility, i. e., the probability of shifting to a different quantile of the wage distribution or changes in the rank positions, and shows a substantial decline in wage mobility over time. The results are provided for East Germany, where the decline in wage mobility begins in the early 1990s, and for West Germany, where decreasing wage mobility has been observed since the late 1990s.

The paper by Arent and Nagl (2013) is relevant because it claims to estimate the effect of the Hartz reforms on wages. Their central result, a structural break in the wage equation in the year of the benefit reforms, differs from the findings mentioned above and from ours (we find that wages started to decrease before 2005; see also Ludsteck and Seth (2014) for a comment).

Our empirical analysis borrows from the literature dis-cussed in this section, especially when we present evidence on empirical distributions and in the specification of our models of job durations and wages. Although the sorting of workers to firms seems to be a promising road for further research, the results of these studies are not unambiguous. Our own analyses are performed at the individual or job level, which seems to be adequate for our research ques-tion. Our aim is to assess the changes in job quality after the implementation of labour market reforms that appar-ently improved the functioning of the labour market and led to the creation of new jobs. We use stability and wages as indicators of job quality and analyse them for a large share of the labour market.

3 Empirical strategy

We start our analysis with an assessment of overall trends in the distributions of job durations and wages. We then es-timate job duration and wage models to determine the size and direction of changes in job quality across the reform period while controlling for the heterogeneity of jobs and workers. Finally, we look at the job quality over time of three groups of disadvantaged workers, namely, unskilled workers, previously unemployed workers and temporary agency workers.

Following a relevant strand of the economic literature, we measure job quality by the level of wages and by job

6 A possible explanation for this puzzle, at least for large firms, might be that stable firms tend to be low-wage firms and high-wage workers can afford to buy job security by choosing permanent and long-lasting jobs in those stable firms (Cornelißen and Hüber2011).

duration: the higher the wage is, the better the job is; the longer a job lasts, the better the job is (Jahn and Rosholm 2014or Caliendo et al.2013).

We use a flow sampling approach and select cohorts of jobs starting in the same year or period. This approach avoids oversampling of longer durations, known as length-bias (Cameron and Trivedi2005). A drawback of this ap-proach is that our sampling yields a large share of incom-plete job spells because of the limited observation period. Because we also censor jobs after 24 months, our analysis of changes in survival probabilities and job-leaving hazards over time is confined to changes in the initial two years in a job and is based on samples with large numbers of censored job spells.

We examine entry wages (wages at the time of the first notification of a worker with a specific employer), which ensures that we do not mix wages for new jobs with the wages of incumbent workers who have already gained some experience on the job. Because new jobs will strongly re-flect current labour market conditions, changes in the mar-ket wage or an increase in temporary, unstable jobs will be revealed rather quickly in our samples. With respect to wages, we see our analyses as complementing other studies based on stock samples.

3.1 The job duration model

To analyse job durations, we estimate the following piece-wise exponential mixed proportional hazard model (Bloss-feld et al. 2007; Cameron and Trivedi 2005; Gutierrez 2002):

ij.tjx0iˇ; i/ D 0.t/exp.x0iˇ/i;

i D 1; :::; N I j D 1; :::; J and

0.t/ D j; j –1< t < j (1)

whereij is the hazard rate representing the risk of leaving the current employer during the jthtime interval of the job

spell belonging to individual i. Job durations are split into at most J time intervals (pieces) to model changes in the risk of job termination conditional on the time already spent in the current job. The jth interval starts at durationj 1and ends at durationj. The baseline hazard0.t/ is a step function

that is constant within intervals. Unobserved heterogeneity is modelled by a gamma-distributed frailty term i that is assumed to be specific to the job spell. Only the variance  of the frailty term is estimated.

The vectorxi is a set of individual, job, firm, industry, and macroeconomic time invariant explanatory variables

(8)

that are specific for an individual at the beginning of the job.

3.2 The wage model

To analyse wages, we estimate censored regression mod-els that allow us to take the threshold for social security contributions into account (Cameron and Trivedi2005).

We model the observed censored wageWijof individual i in year j as the realization of a latent variableWij: W

ij D xij0 ˇ C "i (2)

wherexij are the covariates of individual i if her employ-ment spell starts in year j, and"i is a normally distributed error term with variance2.

The observed wage is: Wij D  W ij cj if Wij < cj Wij  cj (3)

where cjis the threshold for social insurance contributions,

which varies over time.

The coefficientsˇ measure the influence of the covari-ates on the latent variable Wij:The maximum likelihood estimation yields results for the vector of coefficients as well as for the variance2.

3.3 Data and variables

We draw our data from a two % sample of the German Integrated Employment Biographies (IEB), a large admin-istrative data set regularly produced at the Institute for Em-ployment Research (IAB) in Nuremberg.7The IEB contains

employment liable to social insurance but does not include self-employment or civil servants. We focus on workers’ employment spells and wages from 1998 to 2010.

The analysis will concentrate on West Germany which accounts for more than 80 % of the German labour market. A common analysis for East and West is hindered by the large differences that continue to exist between the two labour markets.8 Selected results on overall trends in East

Germany are contained in the appendix.

We select workers aged 25 to 54 when starting their jobs. Workers under 25 or over 54 are excluded because the job exits of younger workers often coincide with re-entry into the educational system and the transitions of older workers might be influenced by the alternative option of retirement.

7 See Jacobebbinghaus and Seth (2007) for a detailed description of an earlier version of the IEB Sample (IEBS).

8 See Riphahn and Schnitzlein (2016) and Möller (2015) for a discus-sion of East-West differences in wage distribution.

Because our focus is on employment spells, we also exclude apprentices of any age.

The duration of a job is defined as a period of em-ployment in the same establishment.9Successive sub-spells

within the same establishment are concatenated to generate the job spells, allowing for a maximum of 90 days of inter-ruption. The start and end of the job spells are measured exactly in days. To keep the observation window as long as possible, we look at durations up to 24 months, therefore censoring longer job spells. In the case of overlapping job spells, we only keep the spell with the highest amount of earnings.

Entry wages are measured as those of the first sub-spell (lasting at most one year) contained in a possibly longer employment episode. We deflate the nominal amount with the German consumer price index to obtain the real daily wage. Right-censoring occurs at the threshold for social se-curity contributions, which is adjusted almost every year.10

The exact amount of wages above the threshold is unob-served.

Even if the data allow us to distinguish between full-time and part-full-time work, they do not contain information on hours worked. Consequently, although we include part-timers (those liable to social insurance) in the analysis of job durations, we are forced to exclude them from the analysis of wages, which implies the neglect of a considerable part of the female workforce.11In addition, we exclude “mini-jobs”

and other part-time jobs with short hours or low earnings from our analyses. Mini-jobs are legally required to fall below a certain threshold (e. g., 400 C in 2012) and are largely exempted from social security contributions. The growth of such jobs in recent years is certainly relevant to our research question (Jahn et al. 2012; Möller 2014). However, due to the lack of information on hours worked and because earnings from mini-jobs often constitute a type of extra income, these jobs are difficult to analyse without any information on the household context.

With respect to individual characteristics, the adminis-trative data contain information on workers’ age, gender and nationality. Information regarding workers’ skill levels combines different types of school and university training

9 The employment information is based on firms’ notifications to the social insurance agencies, which are obligatory at least once annually. Therefore, the employment period covered by a notification can last from a few days up to a maximum of one year.

10 In 2010, the West German threshold was equal to 180.82 (5500) C per day (month).

11 Moreover, there might still be part-time workers in our sample, be-cause some of them might have been erroneously declared full-time workers. In fact, since 2011, the collection of information on working times in the employment statistics has changed. The break in the data caused by this change has revealed a considerable overestimation of the share of full-time workers before 2011 (Bundesagentur für Arbeit

(9)

with a binary indicator of whether the worker has com-pleted vocational training. We include indicators of labour market status preceding the new job, distinguishing “jobs taken after unemployment” (where unemployment is de-fined by benefit receipt or being registered with the local employment agency), “job-to-job changes” (allowing for 31 days of non-employment between jobs), “gaps” (peri-ods without entries in our data) and “first spells”, which are workers’ first appearance in the IEB. Jobs with fixed-term contracts contribute to our results on durations and wages but cannot be distinguished from permanent jobs in our data. Regarding temporary agency work, the Hartz re-forms implied a considerable liberalization and the increase in the number of temporary agency workers has been one of the main topics in the debate on recent labour market changes in Germany. In contrast to fixed-term contracts, temporary agency workers can be identified relatively well using the industry code (see Antoni and Jahn2009).

We include industry and firm size class in our models as information on establishments.12 To take account of

busi-ness cycle effects, we include indicators for the state of the local labour market: GDP growth obtained from the Ger-man Federal States’ Accounts and the regional unemploy-ment rate made available by the Federal Statistical Office, with both variables measured at the level of the West Ger-man districts (Kreise). Seasonal effects are modelled by the inclusion of dummy variables for the quarters of job entry. In the analysis of overall trends in job quality, we focus on yearly cohorts of new jobs. In our regression models of job duration and wages, we group the observations into three sub-periods: jobs beginning in the period before the reforms (1998 to 2002), jobs beginning during the period of the Hartz reforms (2003 to 2005) and jobs beginning in the post-reform period (2006 to 2009/2010).

4 Results

We first discuss the results of the overall analysis of job duration and wages in new jobs (Sect. 4.1). We then turn to the model analysis (Sect. 4.2) and, finally, to the re-sults concerning the three selected groups of disadvantaged workers: unskilled workers, temporary agency workers, and previously unemployed workers (Sect. 4.3).

12 Because of several changes in the classification system of industries, a combined 3-digit industry variable generated at IAB’s Research Data Centre (see Eberle et al. 2011) is used and regrouped into broader categories for the regression analyses.

4.1 Trends in the distributions of job durations and wages

The duration of a new job is defined as an uninterrupted period of work with the same employer (see Sect. 3.3). We adopt Kaplan-Meier survival function estimators to plot time trends of the distributions of job durations. For wages, we compare the quartiles (25th, median and 75th percentile) of the distribution of log wages. To visualize broad group differences, we first distinguish by gender and then by skill level.

4.1.1 Durations of newly started jobs

Fig.3shows the estimated probabilities of staying in a job at specific durations after the job begins for job spells started between January 1998 and December 2009 (Decem-ber 2008 for survival probabilities of 18 and 24 months).

Job stability is fairly high. The estimated 12-month sur-vival probabilities for male workers are between 50 and 60 %, and they are even higher for female workers (see also Table 4 in the appendix). Over time, the survival prob-abilities for male workers seem to be fairly stable, whereas for female workers they show a tendency towards longer job durations. There is a temporary decrease in survival prob-abilities for jobs beginning in the year 2000; this decrease is more pronounced for women and for longer durations. We do not have a ready explanation for this result;13in any

case, the size of this reduction is rather limited (up to 4 per-centage points for women’s 24-month survival probability, see Table 4 in the appendix).14 Overall, the vertical

dis-tances between the survival probabilities at different dura-tions remain fairly constant, meaning that within the groups of male and female workers, job durations do not become much more unevenly distributed over time (see also Fig.7 in Sect. 4.3). As an intermediate result, there are no signs of a general downward trend in job durations during or after the reform period, which confirms the aggregated turnover rates presented in Fig.2.15.

Fig.4distinguishes between three skill levels (see also Table 5 in the appendix). The category of “unskilled” workers comprises those with lower than medium education

13 If anything, the labour market reforms adopted in the period 1999–2001 went in the direction of re-regulation (see Giannelli et al.

2012).

14 The decrease in the 2009 survival probabilities for longer durations is due to the censoring of these spells at the end of 2010.

15 In East Germany, the 6-month survival probabilities decrease some-what over time, whereas longer-term survival probabilities remain con-stant or even increase. As a result, survival probabilities for jobs started in 2008/2009 in East Germany are more similar to those observed in West Germany than they were previously. See Fig. 8 and Table 4 in the appendix.

(10)

Fig. 3 Job Survival Prob-abilities after 6, 12, 18 and 24 Months. Survival probabil-ities at 18 and 24 months are not observed for jobs starting in 2009 (Source: IEB, own calculations, N = 816,774) .4 .6 .8 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 Men W omen

6 months 12 months 18 months 24 months

S u rv iv a l P ro b a b ili ty Years

and without vocational training. The category of “skilled” workers includes workers with up to a medium level of education, workers with vocational training, and workers with a degree that qualifies them for professional college or university attendance. Workers in the “highly skilled” category have college or university degrees.

For a given duration, highly skilled workers have the highest survival probabilities, whereas unskilled workers have the lowest. Over time, the survival probabilities de-crease somewhat for unskilled workers, especially at job durations of 18 and 24 months. The opposite is true for highly skilled workers; their survival probabilities show a slight upward trend, which is stronger for longer job du-rations. Because the observed changes are rather small, this evidence indicates that heterogeneity in job durations within skill groups has also not increased significantly over time.

4.1.2 Wages in newly started jobs

This analysis is confined to full-time workers, because in-formation on hours worked is not available for part-time workers (see Sect. 3.3).

By now, the growth in earnings inequality over the last several decades and a steady decline in real wages since the early 2000 s is fairly well established for Germany, as well as for other industrialized countries (Dustmann et al.2009, Card et al.2013). With its focus on new jobs, our analysis presents further evidence on this issue.

The wage variable is measured as the log of daily real wages in 2005 prices. In Fig.5, the 25th percentile, median, and 75th percentile of the wage distributions for men and women are plotted over the years (exact figures for the years 1998 and 2010 can be found in Table 6 in the appendix).

In line with the results of Card et al. (2013), the decrease in real wages after 2001 is clearly visible. For both men and women in new jobs, the decline in wages is strongest in the 25th and 50th percentiles of the wage distribution, whereas the decline in the 75th percentiles is comparatively modest. Furthermore, wage inequality has been increasing among both men and women. The lower interquartile difference (50th percentile minus 25th percentile) has increased by 8 % for men and by 4 % for women, and the upper interquar-tile difference (75th perceninterquar-tile minus 50th perceninterquar-tile) has increased by 6 % for both men and women (Table 6).16

As previously noted, “wage moderation” is one poten-tial explanation of Germany’s relatively good employment performance during the great recession in 2008/2009. In accordance with most of the studies summarized in Sect. 2, our results show that the decrease in real wages begins well before the Hartz reforms. Thus, one impact of the reforms might have been to strengthen a pre-existing tendency to-wards lower wages. The size of wage losses in our sample

16 For values up to 0.05, the differences in log points are good approx-imations of percentage wage changes.

(11)

Fig. 4 Job Survival Prob-abilities after 6, 12, 18 and 24 Months, by Skill Level. Sur-vival probabilities of 18 and 24 months are not observed for jobs starting in 2009. (Source: IEB, own calculations; N = 816,774)

.4

.6

.8

199 8 2 000 20 02 200 4 2 006 20 08 199 8 2 000 2 002 20 04 2 00 6 2 008 199 8 200 0 2 002 20 04 200 6 2 008

U nskilled Skilled Highly Skilled

6 months 12 months 18 months 24 months

S u rv iv a l P rob ab il it y Years

of new jobs is clearly larger than the wage decreases re-ported in Card et al. (2013).17

The differences in entry wages between skill levels are substantial (Fig.6, Table 7 in the appendix). Furthermore, the disadvantage of unskilled workers is increasing. The median log wage of highly skilled workers, for example, decreased from 4.79 in 1998 to 4.63 in 2010, implying a daily wage loss of 15 % (approximately 18 C). The cor-responding median wage loss for skilled workers from 1998 to 2010 was also 15 % (10 C). However, the median wage loss for unskilled workers was 21 % (11 C; see Table 7). In addition, within-group inequality has been rising, which also accords with the results of Card et al. (2013). For the skilled and highly skilled worker groups, the decline in

17 The 1995–2009 wage decreases shown in Table1 in Card et al. (2013) amount to –4 to –6 %. Considering workers moving between different quartiles of the establishment wage distribution, the study also finds large wage decreases in certain cases, especially for the period 2002–2009 (see Card et al.2013; Online Appendix Table 6). 18 For highly skilled workers, the 75th percentile is unfortunately not informative because for this group, between 17 %(in 2010) and 29 %(in 1998) of workers have entry wages above the social security threshold. 19 Overall wage trends for East Germany are contained in the ap-pendix, Fig. 9 and Table 6. In 2010, there remains a substantial gap between the levels of East German and West German wages. Wage dispersion in East Germany has increased over time and is larger for women than for men. The wage decrease in East Germany was largest in the lowest quartile and larger for men than for women in all three quartiles. In 2010, East German daily full-time wages at the 25th percentile were approximately 38 C for men and approximately 33 C for women.

wages is strongest in the 25th percentile (that is, for workers with the lowest earnings in these groups).18 19

4.2 Model analysis

4.2.1 Job duration

Although no general tendency towards shorter job durations over time was revealed by the analysis in Sect. 4.1.1, we now consider the possibility that changes in the composition of jobs have influenced this result. We estimate a duration model that controls for a broad range of explanatory vari-ables. The objective is to determine whether the period in which the Hartz reforms were implemented or the subse-quent period are associated with changes in job durations when we take into account changes in the structure of jobs, as captured by our covariates. Because we do not use an experimental or quasi-experimental design, the estimated covariate effects reflect empirical associations rather than causal influences.

The model is a single spell model, estimated separately for men and women, for employment spells beginning be-tween January 1998 and December 2008. For persons with

20 The selection of only one spell per person and the exclusion of spells starting in 2009 account for the different numbers of observations used for the graphical survival analysis in Section 4.1.1 and the model anal-ysis in this section. The means of the model variables are contained in Table 8 in the appendix.

(12)

Fig. 5 Distribution of Wages (Source: IEB, own calculations,

N = 747,214) 3. 5 4 4. 5 5 199 8 200 0 200 2 2 00 4 2 006 200 8 201 0 1 998 2 000 2 002 2 004 2 006 20 08 2 010 Men W omen

25th percentile 50th percent ile 75th percentile

Lo g W a g e Years

Fig. 6 Distribution of Wages by Skill Level (Source: IEB, own calculations, N = 747,214) 3. 5 4 4. 5 5 199 8 20 00 20 02 2 004 200 6 200 8 20 10 199 8 20 00 2 002 2 004 200 6 200 8 20 10 199 8 20 00 2 002 200 4 20 06 20 08 2 010

U nskilled Skilled Highly Skilled

25th percentile 50th percent ile 75th percentile

Lo g W a g e Years

more than one new job in the observation window, we ran-domly select only one spell.20

The results are presented in the form of hazard ratios, which – in the case of binary or categorical variables – indicate the influence of a variable on the risk of leaving the job relative to the reference group (see Table1). The relationship between the risk of terminating a job and job

duration is inverse, meaning that a value of the hazard ra-tio greater (smaller) than one implies a positive (negative) effect on the hazard and a negative (positive) effect on du-ration for that variable. The z-values in Table1are based on the cluster-robust estimation of the variance-covariance matrix, because the district-level variables of unemploy-ment rate and GDP growth give rise to a within-district

(13)

correlation of regression model errors (Cameron and Miller 2015).21

Starting with our variables of interest, the time period indicators of the year of entry are smaller than one for both men and women during the reform period (2003–2005). For the post-reform period (2006–2008), the hazard ratio continues to be smaller than one for women but is insignifi-cant for men. These results imply that job durations ceteris paribus are somewhat longer for new jobs started in the re-form period (2003–2005) compared to the reference period (1998–2002). For men, in the years following the Hartz reforms, durations do not differ from those in the reference period, whereas for women, job durations continue to be slightly longer than those in the period preceding the Hartz reforms.

For the rest of the models, the pattern of the baseline hazard, the associations of the covariates with the hazard rate and the relevance of the frailty term are of interest as well. The pattern of the estimated risk of leaving a job is non-monotonic: the hazard ratios for the time periods at the top of the table initially slightly increase (for women, there is also a temporary decline in the third month) and then start to decrease after the first three months of employment. This non-monotonic pattern can be explained by the high initial risk of contract dissolution if a mismatch is found in combination with the stabilizing effect of job-specific human capital (Blossfeld et al. 2007, p. 121). In addition to this baseline pattern – and despite the large number of covariates – the importance of unobserved heterogeneity is confirmed in all of our models by likelihood ratio tests that are highly significant.

The results also point to a clear seasonal pattern in job durations. The estimated hazard ratios from the men’s model are large and increase during the year, implying the longest durations for jobs beginning in the first three cal-endar months. For women, this pattern is less regular and less pronounced.

The state of the local labour market might influence job durations through fluctuations in labour demand. The re-spective control variables are insignificant, however. Per-sistent differences in economic conditions between regions might also influence job durations. The estimated hazard ratios for the federal states seem to reflect to some extent the north-south divide in Germany. The reference is North Rhine-Westphalia, which is the state with the largest pop-ulation and is situated in the western centre. Significantly shorter job durations are estimated in the northern states

21 As suggested by an anonymous referee, we tested an alternative model specification that includes district-level dummy variables in-stead of the continuous variables used in the model in Table1. The differences between the results of these two specifications with respect to other covariates were very small. The results of the district dummy variable models are available upon request.

of Schleswig Holstein and Hamburg, and longer job dura-tions are estimated in the southern states. For the state of Hesse, situated in the southern centre, and the economi-cally strong states Baden Württemberg and Bavaria, which are both situated in the south of Germany, we find lower risks of leaving jobs and thus longer durations (in Bavaria, this is only found for women).

The effect of firm size is clear and rather large. As pre-dicted by theories of internal labour markets, job duration monotonically increases with the size of the firm for both men and women.

For some industries, we can also note fairly strong and significant effects. Compared to business services (the ref-erence group), jobs tend to be very stable for men in man-ufacturing and for women in social and public services. Very large and significant hazard ratios for both men and women are estimated for temporary agency jobs, indicating far shorter durations. Although this confirms the general no-tion that temporary agency jobs are of low quality, a more careful analysis would need to look at subsequent jobs to see how many temporary agency jobs lead to regular jobs (e. g., Jahn and Rosholm2014).

Part-time jobs with a minimum of 18 h per week are much shorter for men but only slightly more stable for women. One interpretation of this finding is that for many men, part-time jobs are only temporary solutions until they find a full-time job. Women might have longer durations in part-time jobs, although these jobs are relatively hard to find.

Age and nationality have the expected effects: job dura-tion is much shorter for younger age groups and foreigners. The skill effect is pronounced for both men and women. Workers for whom information on skill was missing and unskilled workers have far higher risks of leaving their jobs compared to the reference group (vocational training with at least an intermediate degree), which indicates the importance of completed vocational training in Germany. Among workers with higher educational levels, only men with a university or comparable degree have more stable jobs than the reference group. Among the categories de-scribing previous labour market status, the reference group (job-to-job changers)22is the largest group. Persons

begin-ning new jobs out of unemployment form another sizeable group. Although the group of persons starting a new job after a gap is also fairly large, the group of persons in their first jobs and the group of persons who are first unemployed and then have a gap before starting their current jobs are both rather small. The results show clearly that compared to job-to-job changers, all other groups experience shorter job durations. The negative association with duration is

22 Job-to-job changers are defined as workers with at most one month of non-employment between their last job and their current job.

(14)

Table 1 Job Duration Models for West Germany

Job duration

Men Women

Hazard ratio za Hazard ratio za

Durationb 0–31 days 0.802 –171.5 0.936 –197.6 32–61 days 0.923 –190.9 0.988 –195.5 62–91 days 0.905 –198.2 0.893 –194.9 92–122 days 1.039 –192.8 1.036 –205.7 123–183 days 0.906 –186.5 0.878 –223.8 184–365 days 0.877 –190.9 0.793 –232.9 366–548 days 0.733 –173.2 0.676 –229.0 549–730 days 0.728 –162.5 0.652 –203.9

Year of entry (ref: 1998–2002)

2003–2005 0.897 –9.2 0.916 –7.2

2006–2008 0.984 –1.2 0.959 –3.6

Quarter of entry (ref: 1st quarter)

2nd quarter 1.320 21.0 1.212 14.4

3rd quarter 1.333 21.2 1.184 12.3

4th quarter 1.364 21.3 1.238 15.8

Local labour demand (district level)

Unemployment rate 1.002 0.8 1.000 –0.1

GDP growth 0.999 –0.7 0.998 –1.7

Federal state (ref: North Rhine-Westphalia)

Schleswig Holstein, Hamburg 1.060 2.5 1.032 1.2

Lower Saxony, Bremen 1.033 1.4 0.989 –0.6

Hesse 0.963 –2.0 0.945 –3.1

Rhineland Palatinate, Saarland 1.050 2.1 0.961 –1.3

Baden-Württemberg 0.930 –3.2 0.904 –4.8

Bavaria 1.000 0.0 0.932 –3.4

Firm size (ref: <20 employees)

20–49 0.813 –14.5 0.966 –2.3

50–249 0.680 –28.8 0.914 –6.6

250–999 0.538 –31.9 0.779 –13.3

1000 and more 0.460 –19.4 0.659 –13.8

Industry (ref: business services)

Agriculture, mining 2.089 14.6 2.337 9.3

Energy, traffic and information 1.098 3.0 1.017 0.7

Manufacturing 0.751 –11.7 0.918 –4.5

Construction 1.175 6.0 0.849 –4.2

Trade and retail 0.895 –4.4 1.011 0.6

Personal and domestic services 1.389 9.4 1.374 14.9

Social and public services 0.980 –0.9 0.828 –10.5

Temporary work agency 4.302 38.9 4.251 40.5

Foreigner 1.682 32.8 1.438 18.5

Age (ref: 30–34)

Age 25–29 1.121 8.2 1.208 12.4

Age 35–39 0.955 –3.4 0.856 –11.1

(15)

Table 1 Job Duration Models for West Germany (Continued) Job duration

Men Women

Hazard ratio za Hazard ratio za

Age 45–49 0.895 –6.1 0.824 –10.6

Age 50–54 0.908 –5.8 0.828 –10.2

Skill Level (ref: vocational training with at most an intermediate degree)

Missing information on educational level 1.875 18.6 1.696 17.1

No vocational training with at most an interme-diate degree

1.254 12.7 1.294 14.9

High school/equivalent; with or without voca-tional training

1.076 4.3 1.002 0.1

University/technical/professional college de-gree

0.823 –11.2 1.036 2.5

Preceding state (ref: job-to-job)

First spell 1.035 1.9 1.085 4.9

Unemployed 1.995 45.1 1.748 33.6

Job followed by gap 1.708 31.6 1.503 28.7

Unemployment followed by gap 1.205 10.9 1.217 12.6

Part-time (min. 18 h/week) 1.407 11.9 0.954 –3.2

Variance of frailty term (logθ) –0.394 –8.5 –0.852 –8.8

LR – test for significance ofθ 1100.9 – 223.6 –

Wald chi2 1,558,412 1,255,807

Log likelihood –218,031 – –173,214 –

Number of obs. 180,546 – 142,335 – aThe standard errors are adjusted for 325 regional clusters using a separate model with a non-individual-specific frailty term bThe hazard ratios of the duration time pieces are multiplied by 1000 in order to obtain legible values

Source: IEB, Federal Statistical Office, own calculations

strongest for persons who are unemployed immediately be-fore starting a job.

4.2.2 Wages

As in the duration model, we use one randomly selected employment spell per person beginning in the period 1998 to 2009. We estimate the models separately for men and women in West Germany (see Table2).23

Once again, the coefficients24of the time period

indica-tors are of central interest. They are negative for the reform period (2003–2005) and for the period following the Hartz reforms (2006–2009), indicating that real wages have been falling since the reference period. Although we control for cyclical effects by including GDP growth rates, an

ad-23 Once again, the difference between the number of observations used to produce Fig.5and6and the number of observations used in the wage model follows from the selection of only one spell per person and from the exclusion of spells starting in the final year, 2010. Descriptive information on the variables of the wage model is contained in Table 9 in the appendix.

24 As a rule of thumb, small coefficients (<0.05) indicate percentage wage changes associated with a unit change in the respective covariate. For larger coefficients, this rule becomes inaccurate.

ditional wage effect of the great recession in 2008/2009 cannot be excluded. The negative wage effect during the reform period is slightly stronger for women than for men; in the post-reform period, we observe much lower entry wages for both sexes. The skill level has the expected positive effect on wages.

Potential work experience has a significant effect only for men. The wages of foreigners are approximately 8 % lower for women and more than 10 % lower for men.

The preceding labour market status is highly relevant for wages in newly started jobs. There is a large negative wage differential for workers in their first job following un-employment. The estimated coefficients are –0.268 (men) and –0.228 (women), which correspond to percentage wage losses of 20 % or more compared to the reference wages of job-to-job changers.

Given the size of these coefficients, it should be stressed once again that these results are descriptive and do not reflect causal relationships.25

25 Schmieder et al. (2016) estimate a causal effect of unemployment on wages. The effect is found to be significantly negative and large, with an additional month of unemployment corresponding to a reduc-tion in the reemployment wage of 0.8 %.

(16)

Table 2 Wage Models for West Germany

Censored Regression Model Log Real Wages

Men Women

Coefficient za Coefficient za

Year of entry (ref: 1998–2002)

2003–2005 –0.023 –5.7 –0.030 –5.5

2006–2009 –0.089 –29.8 –0.088 –20.1

Skill level (ref: vocational training with at most an intermediate degree)

Missing information on educational level –0.205 –11.1 –0.174 –11.3 No vocational training with at most an intermediate

degree

–0.220 –38.4 –0.217 –23.3

High school/equivalent; with or without vocational training

0.096 17.7 0.148 22.0

University/technical/professional college degree 0.495 52.6 0.413 44.2

Potential experienceb 3.582 27.1 0.044 0.3

Potential experience squaredb –0.063 –23.2 0.006 1.8

Preceding state (ref: job-to-job)

First spell 0.024 5.7 –0.014 –2.4

Unemployed –0.268 –48.4 –0.228 –37.6

Job followed by gap –0.179 –34.4 –0.190 –31.9

Unemployment followed by gap –0.179 –29.9 –0.198 –28.3

Local labour demand (district level)

Unemployment rate –0.002 –2.1 0.003 2.2

GDP growth 0.035 0.8 0.067 0.8

Federal state (ref: North Rhine-Westphalia)

Schleswig Holstein, Hamburg –0.023 –1.4 0.021 0.7

Lower Saxony, Bremen –0.048 –6.7 –0.063 –3.2

Hesse 0.011 0.6 0.045 1.6

Rhineland Palatinate, Saarland –0.049 –4.4 –0.048 –2.8

Baden-Württemberg 0.017 1.6 0.017 1.0

Bavaria 0.008 0.5 0.038 1.1

Firm size (ref: < 20 employees)

20–49 0.128 34.1 0.176 31.3

50–249 0.181 37.1 0.268 49.2

250–999 0.270 45.8 0.395 50.1

1000 and more 0.363 37.2 0.511 31.4

Industry (ref: business services)

Agriculture, mining –0.221 –13.1 –0.174 –7.8

Energy, traffic and information –0.123 –8.8 –0.010 –0.4

Manufacturing 0.007 0.8 –0.035 –2.8

Construction 0.005 0.5 –0.173 –8.0

Trade and retail –0.035 –4.3 –0.051 –3.7

Personal and domestic services –0.359 –32.0 –0.247 –21.3

Social and public services –0.164 –13.3 –0.006 –0.3

(17)

Table 2 Wage Models for West Germany (Continued)

Censored Regression Model Log Real Wages

Men Women Coefficient za Coefficient za Foreigner –0.153 –29.4 –0.080 –9.4 Constant 4.017 270.0 3.941 209.9 Log (sigma) –0.863 –65.6 –0.699 0.7 Wald chi2(33) 39.685 38.019 Log pseudolikelihood –105.077 – –72.515 – Number of obs. 178,065 – 99,012 – Censored obs. 17,278 – 2827 – aThe standard errors of the coefficients are adjusted for 325 regional clusters

bThe coefficients of the experience variables and of GDP growth are multiplied by 100 in order to obtain legible values Source: IEB, Federal Statistical Office, own calculations

The coefficient of the local unemployment rate is nega-tive in the model for men’s wages and posinega-tive in the model for women’s wages.26The effects of the federal states

vari-ables are often insignificant, with persons from Lower Sax-ony/Bremen and Rhineland Palatinate/Saarland having sig-nificantly lower wages than those from the reference state of North Rhine-Westphalia.

Firm size is positively correlated with wages; larger firms pay higher wages. This effect seems to be stronger for women. In most industries, wages are lower than in busi-ness services, which is the reference group. In particular, workers in personal and domestic services and temporary agency workers are worse off.

4.2.3 Summary of results for job duration and wages

In summary, the results of the multivariate analysis pre-sented in this section show that ceteris paribus, the dura-tions of new jobs did not significantly decrease either during or after the Hartz reform period compared to the previous period (1998–2002) and that there were real wage losses during the reform period and even greater wage losses in the period following the Hartz reforms.

4.3 Job durations and wages for selected groups of workers over time

Because our analysis is concerned with increasing inequal-ity, it might be worthwhile to check whether the situations of certain groups of workers known to be disadvantaged have improved or worsened over time. We select three

26 The positive sign in the model for women is somewhat surprising, but because we do not estimate a causal model, this result may simply be a spurious relationship resulting from changes in the supply of fe-male labour and associated positive wage changes during our observa-tion period. An anonymous referee brought this issue to our attenobserva-tion.

groups – temporary agency workers, workers who were unemployed before starting a new job, and unskilled work-ers – to determine whether trends for them differ from the overall trends assessed previously.

In Fig. 7, similar to Sect. 4.1, Kaplan-Meier survivor functions are plotted across periods for the entire sample (first panel) and for the groups of temporary agency work-ers, unskilled workwork-ers, and previously unemployed workers. It is obvious that there is virtually no effect on job du-rations for these groups over time. Comparing the survivor functions of these three groups with that of the entire sam-ple confirms the lower level of job stability for the selected groups, especially for temporary agency workers.27

Table3presents median log wages together with changes across time periods for the entire sample and for the three selected groups of workers. The model analysis in Sect. 4.2.2 clearly proved that these groups have lower wages ceteris paribus, and the median wages complement this finding. For all men, the median wage dropped by 3 % from the first to the second period and further declined by approximately 9 % from the second to the third period. For women, the decline between the first two periods is also approximately 3 % and the decline between the second and the third periods is approximately 4 %.

Temporary agency workers, the group with the lowest median wage, experienced sizable wage losses between the first two periods: the median wage dropped by approx-imately 6 % for men and more than 10 % for females. Unskilled workers as a group clearly suffered the largest wage losses: for men, the median wage falls by approxi-mately 8 % between the first two periods and falls again by more than 10 % between the second and third periods. The median wage of female unskilled workers falls by

ap-27 We also tried to assess the question of different group trends by estimating models in which all covariates were interacted with the time period indicators. These results are available upon request.

(18)

Table 3 Median Wages for Different Groups (Source: IEB, own calculations)

Log Median Wage Differences

1998–2002 2003–2005 2006–2010 03/05–98/02 06/10–03/05 Men All 4.36 4.33 4.24 –0.03 –0.09 Temporary 3.81 3.75 3.71 –0.06 –0.04 Unskilled 4.03 3.95 3.84 –0.08 –0.12 Unempl. before 4.19 4.16 4.05 –0.03 –0.12 Women All 4.14 4.11 4.06 –0.03 –0.04 Temporary 3.75 3.64 3.63 –0.11 –0.01 Unskilled 3.83 3.77 3.69 –0.06 –0.08 Unempl. before 3.99 3.93 3.87 –0.06 –0.06 N = 761,246

proximately 6 % between the first and second periods and by approximately 8 % between the second and the third periods. For men who were unemployed before starting the current job, there is also a very sharp decline in the median wage between the last two periods. For the group of women starting a job after unemployment, the drop in the median wage is approximately 6 % both between the first two periods and between the last two periods.

It is reasonable to consider overlaps between these groups of disadvantaged workers (e. g., workers who are both unskilled and employed in a temporary work agency) and to examine the median wages of these overlap groups across periods. However, jobs with workers belonging to two or more of our disadvantaged groups account for less than 10 % of the sample, and there are only a few subgroups for which the wage trends were even worse than those reported in Table3.28

In summary, median wage losses were often larger in the three selected groups compared to overall wage trends.29

The sizable wage losses observed for jobs held by disadvan-taged groups of workers might partly reflect demand-side changes, such as changes in relative skill demand. On the supply side, the decrease in reservation wages of workers in these groups is likely linked to the changes in the benefit system, because the risk of (recurrent) unemployment for these workers is comparatively high.

28 In contrast, the jobs of previously unemployed workers account for 29 % of the job sample used for the descriptive analysis in Table3and jobs in temporary agencies – which strongly increased in number after the reform period – account for 10 % of that job sample.

29 When we tried to detect these combined group-period-effects by in-cluding interaction terms in our wage model, the coefficients were of-ten rather small and insignificant. The results are available from the authors upon request.

5 Concluding remarks

In this paper, we have assessed whether a reduction in the quality of new jobs has occurred in the German labour market during and/or after the implementation of the Hartz reform.

Our results on overall trends in job durations indicate stable job durations for men and somewhat longer dura-tions for women. Interestingly, the graphical analysis does not show a stronger tendency towards a more unequal dis-tribution of job durations. Consistent with the finding of decreased labour turnover, the results of the duration analy-sis even imply somewhat longer job durations in the reform period. When looking at selected groups of workers, we also do not find evidence of decreased job stability over time. Although job stability seems to hold steady, we con-firm both a decrease in real wages over time and an in-crease in overall wage dispersion. For our sample of newly started jobs, several of the observed wage decreases are quite large. The estimated models reveal stronger wage losses in the period 2006–2009 compared to the reform pe-riod 2003–2005, which is due at least in part to the great recession in 2008/2009. The selected groups experienced severe wage losses in both periods, which in most cases were larger than the sizeable decrease in the overall median wage.

The predominantly high level of job stability is rather surprising. One explanation could be that the matching process has become more efficient, not only with respect to the duration of job searches but also with respect to the quality of job matches. In light of the results regard-ing wages, however, we attribute this stability to the higher cost of job mobility. Workers are more reluctant to quit both because the benefit system is less generous than it was pre-viously and because entry wages are decreasing over time. Nevertheless, firms can count on very flexible labour, as demonstrated by the far shorter job durations of temporary agency workers compared to other workers.

(19)

Fig. 7 Survivor Functions for Different Groups. a Men,

b Women (Source: IEB, own

calculations, N = 832,158) .2 .4 .6 .8 1 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 200 400 600 800 200 400 600 800

All Temporary Agency W ork

Unskilled Unemployed before job

1998-2002 2003-2005 2006-2009 S u rv iv a l P ro b a b ili ty Days .2 .4 .6 .8 1 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 200 400 600 800 200 400 600 800

All Temporary Agency W ork

Unskilled Unemployed before job

1998-2002 2003-2005 2006-2009 S u rv iv a l P rob ab il it y Days a b

(20)

With respect to wages, it is difficult to attribute our re-sults solely to the Hartz reforms. The decrease in real wages for our sample of new jobs begins in the years 2001/2002, well before the Hartz reforms. However, the marked wage losses for disadvantaged groups of workers indicate a strong decline in reservation wages, which is likely linked to changes in the benefit system because these workers suffer a comparatively high risk of unemployment, especially long-term unemployment.

Acknowledgements We would like to thank Johannes Ludsteck and

Joseph Sakshaug and the anonymous reviewers for helpful comments and suggestions.

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the

Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://

creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted

use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

(21)

Appendix

Fig. 8 East Germany: Job

Survival Probabilities after 6, 12, 18 and 24 Months (Source: IEB, own calculations; N = 248,240) .4 .6 .8 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 Men W omen

6 months 12 months 18 months 24 months

S u rv iv a l P rob ab il it y Years

Fig. 9 East Germany: Distri-bution of Wages (Source: IEB, own calculations; N = 217,921) 3. 5 4 4. 5 5 199 8 200 0 200 2 2 00 4 2 006 200 8 201 0 1 998 2 000 2 002 2 004 2 006 20 08 2 010 Men W omen

25th percentile 50th percent ile 75th percentile

Lo g W a g e Years

(22)

Table 4 Survival Probabilities after 6, 12, 18 and 24 Months of Duration, by Gender West GermanyMen Women Year 6 Mths 12 Mths 18 Mths 24 Mths 6 Mths 12 Mths 18 Mths 24 Mths 1998 0.72 0.56 0.49 0.42 0.75 0.60 0.51 0.44 1999 0.71 0.56 0.47 0.41 0.76 0.62 0.52 0.46 2000 0.70 0.55 0.46 0.39 0.73 0.59 0.49 0.42 2001 0.71 0.55 0.47 0.39 0.75 0.59 0.51 0.44 2002 0.70 0.54 0.46 0.40 0.74 0.59 0.51 0.45 2003 0.71 0.56 0.47 0.41 0.76 0.62 0.53 0.46 2004 0.71 0.55 0.47 0.41 0.75 0.62 0.53 0.46 2005 0.71 0.55 0.48 0.42 0.76 0.62 0.54 0.47 2006 0.70 0.55 0.47 0.40 0.75 0.62 0.53 0.46 2007 0.70 0.57 0.47 0.41 0.75 0.62 0.53 0.46 2008 0.70 0.55 0.47 0.41 0.76 0.62 0.53 0.46 2009 0.70 0.54 – – 0.76 0.61 – – East GermanyMen Women Year 6 Mths 12 Mths 18 Mths 24 Mths 6 Mths 12 Mths 18 Mths 24 Mths 1998 0.71 0.48 0.39 0.33 0.80 0.53 0.44 0.38 1999 0.68 0.50 0.36 0.29 0.78 0.62 0.45 0.39 2000 0.68 0.47 0.37 0.31 0.77 0.53 0.43 0.37 2001 0.69 0.46 0.38 0.30 0.78 0.56 0.49 0.41 2002 0.68 0.47 0.39 0.33 0.77 0.56 0.49 0.43 2003 0.66 0.48 0.38 0.32 0.75 0.59 0.49 0.44 2004 0.64 0.44 0.37 0.31 0.73 0.56 0.48 0.42 2005 0.66 0.47 0.40 0.34 0.75 0.59 0.52 0.45 2006 0.68 0.51 0.43 0.37 0.75 0.59 0.52 0.46 2007 0.69 0.53 0.43 0.37 0.76 0.61 0.51 0.45 2008 0.68 0.51 0.43 0.36 0.75 0.60 0.51 0.44 2009 0.67 0.50 – – 0.76 0.58 – –

Source: IEB, own calculations

Table 5 Job Survival Probabilities after 6, 12, 18 and 24 Months of Duration, by Skill Level West Germany

Unskilled Skilled Highly Skilled

Year 6 Mths 12 Mths 18 Mths 24 Mths 6 Mths 12 Mths 18 Mths 24 Mths 6 Mths 12 Mths 18 Mths 24 Mths 1998 0.65 0.47 0.40 0.33 0.72 0.56 0.48 0.41 0.84 0.71 0.62 0.53 1999 0.67 0.50 0.40 0.34 0.72 0.57 0.48 0.42 0.82 0.68 0.57 0.50 2000 0.63 0.45 0.36 0.30 0.71 0.56 0.46 0.40 0.81 0.67 0.56 0.48 2001 0.63 0.45 0.37 0.30 0.72 0.56 0.48 0.41 0.82 0.67 0.58 0.50 2002 0.63 0.43 0.36 0.30 0.71 0.55 0.48 0.41 0.80 0.66 0.58 0.51 2003 0.63 0.48 0.37 0.32 0.72 0.57 0.48 0.42 0.81 0.69 0.59 0.52 2004 0.63 0.46 0.38 0.33 0.72 0.57 0.48 0.42 0.80 0.68 0.59 0.52 2005 0.62 0.44 0.38 0.32 0.72 0.57 0.50 0.43 0.81 0.67 0.59 0.51 2006 0.63 0.47 0.38 0.33 0.71 0.56 0.48 0.41 0.81 0.68 0.59 0.51 2007 0.61 0.47 0.37 0.32 0.71 0.57 0.48 0.42 0.81 0.69 0.59 0.52 2008 0.59 0.43 0.35 0.30 0.71 0.56 0.48 0.41 0.82 0.70 0.61 0.53 2009 0.64 0.46 – – 0.71 0.56 – – 0.82 0.67 – –

(23)

Table 6 Percentiles of the Wage Distribution and Changes, 1998 and 2010, by Gender

West Germany

Percentiles 1998 2010

25th percentile 50th percentile 75th percentile 25th percentile 50th percentile 75th percentile

Men 4.09 4.36 4.66 3.84 4.19 4.55 Women 3.78 4.13 4.45 3.66 4.05 4.44 Differences (log points) 1998 2010 2010–1998 2010–1998 50th–25th per-centile 75th–50th per-centile 50th–25th per-centile 75th–50th per-centile 50th–25th per-centile 75th–50th per-centile Men 0.27 0.30 0.35 0.36 0.08 0.06 Women 0.35 0.32 0.39 0.39 0.04 0.06 East Germany Percentiles 1998 2010

25th percentile 50th percentile 75th percentile 25th percentile 50th percentile 75th percentile

Men 3.78 4.00 4.29 3.64 3.90 4.20 Women 3.61 3.86 4.28 3.48 3.81 4.25 Differences (log points) 1998 2010 2010–1998 2010–1998 50th–25th per-centile 75th–50th per-centile 50th–25th per-centile 75th–50th per-centile 50th–25th per-centile 75th–50th per-centile Men 0.21 0.29 0.27 0.30 0.05 0.01 Women 0.25 0.42 0.33 0.44 0.08 0.02

Source: IEB, own calculations

Table 7 Percentiles of the Wage Distribution and Changes, 1998 and 2010, by Skill Level

West Germany Percentiles 1998 2010 25th per-centile 50th per-centile 75th per-centile 25th percentile 50th per-centile 75th per-centile Unskilled 3.69 3.98 4.26 3.51 3.75 4.08 Skilled 3.98 4.26 4.50 3.76 4.10 4.40 Highly Skilled 4.49 4.79 1 4.23 4.63 4.99

Differences (log points) 1998 2010 2010–1998 2010–1998

50th–25th per-centile 75th–50th per-centile 50th–25th per-centile 75th–50th per-centile 50th–25th percentile 75th–50th per-centile Unskilled 0.29 0.28 0.24 0.33 –0.06 0.05 Skilled 0.28 0.24 0.34 0.29 0.06 0.05 Highly Skilled 0.30 1 0.40 0.36 0.10 a

aNo entry because of high proportion of censored wages. The proportion of highly skilled workers in new jobs with earnings above the social security threshold is 29 % in 1998 and 17 % in 2010

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

in the Italy through the Stereoscope set, there are three types of media that com- plement each other: stereoviews, texts (the written guide, plus the captions on the front and

The aim of this European study is to gain a better understanding of the impact of current core trends regarding employment and work arrangements in the retail and wholesale

Siamo quindi arrivati a inserire la tecnologia digitale dentro il prodotto indossabile, studiando come l’interaction design possa entrare in tutti i processi del sistema

Il territorio di Lunigiana (Val di Vara compresa) sotto gli imperatori franchi venne inserito nella Marca della Liguria orientale, affidata alla famiglia degli Obertenghi, dalla

State Research Center of Russian Federation, Institute for High Energy Physics, Protvino, Russia 107 University of Belgrade, Faculty of Physics and Vinca Institute of Nuclear

This result strongly suggests that we are observing discrete shifts from part-time to full-time work, as conjectured by Zabalza et al 1980 and Baker and Benjamin 1999, rather

und Forschung, Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft, and Helmholtz-Gemeinschaft Deutscher Forschungszentren, Germany; the General Secretariat for Research and Technology, Greece;

La comparsa intorno alla metà del XIV secolo nel cuore della Toscana di una classe di produzione ceramica altamente specializzata e standardizzata, foggiata a stampo pone