• Non ci sono risultati.

experiment information Referrals and flow in networks increase discrimination: Alaboratory Social Networks

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "experiment information Referrals and flow in networks increase discrimination: Alaboratory Social Networks"

Copied!
12
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

Contents lists available atScienceDirect

Social

Networks

j o u r n a l h o m e p a g e :w w w . e l s e v i e r . c o m / l o c a t e / s o c n e t

Referrals

and

information

flow

in

networks

increase

discrimination:

A

laboratory

experiment

Károly

Takács

a,∗

,

Giangiacomo

Bravo

b

,

Flaminio

Squazzoni

c

aMTATK“Lendület”ResearchCenterforEducationalandNetworkStudies(RECENS),CentreforSocialSciences,HungarianAcademyofSciences,Tóth

Kálmánu.4.,1097Budapest,Hungary

bDepartmentofSocialStudiesandCentreforDataIntensiveSciencesandApplications,LinnaeusUniversity,Universitetsplatsen1,35195Växjö,Sweden

cDepartmentofEconomicsandManagement,UniversityofBrescia,ViaSanFaustino74B,25122Brescia,Italy

a

r

t

i

c

l

e

i

n

f

o

Articlehistory:

Received8August2017

Receivedinrevisedform19March2018

Accepted22March2018 Keywords: Hiringdiscrimination Referrals Recommendations Informationnetworks Labormarket Laboratoryexperiment Qualitystandards

a

b

s

t

r

a

c

t

Referralsandinformationflowdistortmarketmechanismsofhiringinthelabormarket,buttheymight assistemployersunderasymmetricinformationinfindingbetteralternatives.Thispaperinvestigates whetheranimpartialinformationflowbetweenemployersinacyclicnetworkstructurecouldgenerate morediscriminationthanwhennoinformationisexchangedbetweenemployers.Wesetupanartificial labormarketinwhichtherewasnoaveragequalitydifferencebetweentwocategoriesofworkers.We askedparticipantstoplaytheroleofemployersandexaminedthepartialityoftheirhiringchoices.Results showedthatdiscriminationwasprevalentinallconditions.Higherstandardsbytheemployersforthe qualityofworkersincreaseddiscriminationasdidthepresenceofreferralsfromworkers.Unexpectedly, impartialinformationflowinacyclicnetworkofemployersdidnothelptodecreasediscrimination.We alsoshowedthatthesemechanismsinteractwithandsubdueeachotherincomplexways.

©2018TheAuthors.PublishedbyElsevierB.V.ThisisanopenaccessarticleundertheCCBY-NC-ND license(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).

Introduction

Hiringdiscriminationmeansdifferentialtreatmentofacertain socialcategory,basedoncategorymembershipratherthan indi-vidualmerit.Differentialtreatmentisrecurrentinhiringchoices characterizedbyasymmetryofinformationbetweenthe organiza-tionandtheapplicant(PetersenandSaporta,2004;Rooth,2010). Giventhatthetrueworker’squalitycannotbeaccuratelypredicted duringhiringdecisions,organizationsmightuserecognizabletraits (e.g.,raceandgender)‘asinexpensivescreeningdeviceswhen hir-ingforjobs,particularlyskilledjobs,inthebelief(correctornot) thatraceandsexstatusare,onaverage,relatedtoproductivity’ (Kaufman2002,p.550).Whenthereisnoorlittlestatisticalbasis todistinguishthequalityofmembersofdifferentcategories, fol-lowingrecognizabletraitscannothelptoestimatetheapplicant’s quality.Inthesecases,understandingwhydiscriminationcould persistisofparamountimportance(Bertrandetal.,2005).

∗ Correspondingauthorat:MTATK“Lendület”ResearchCenterforEducational

andNetworkStudies(RECENS),CentreforSocialSciences,HungarianAcademyof

Sciences,TóthKálmánu.4.,1097,Budapest,Hungary.

E-mailaddresses:takacs.karoly@tk.mta.hu(K.Takács),

giangiacomo.bravo@lnu.se(G.Bravo),flaminio.squazzoni@unibs.it(F.Squazzoni).

Hiringdecisionsmightreflectsignalsandinformationthat chan-nelthrough social networks. The important role of referrals in particulariswelldocumentedforgettingajob(Granovetter,1973, 1974;Linetal.,1981;Wegener,1991;Elliott,2001;Mouw,2002; FernandezandFernandez-Mateo,2006;PonzoandScoppa,2010; FountainandStovel,2014).Manystudiesarguedthatgettingajob viareferralsmightdistorttheperfectmarketlogicandreplace mer-itocraticprocessesinhiring(IoannidesandLoury,2004;Petersen etal.,2000;TassierandMenczer,2008).Forinstance,theextended useofinformaljobsearchmethodsmayhaveanegativeeffecton therateofmobilityfromlowstatustohighstatusjobs(McBrier 2003;1212).Ifoneofthegroupshasabetteraccesstoinformal jobsearch,thisisdetrimentalfortheothergroup,asinthecaseof referralsfromthe“oldboys”networkinawiderangeofcontexts (Rogers,2000;McBrier,2003;McDonald,2011;Bianetal.,2015).

Research concerning referrals highlighted how the hiring mechanismcouldenhanceinequalityofemploymentandwages (Montgomery,1991;Krauth,2004;Fontaine,2008).Giventhat con-tactsmightbehomophilouswithregardtointernal quality,the extensiveuseofreferralsleadnecessarilytogrowinginequality (Montgomery,1991;Beamanand Magruder,2012).Considering that contactsare homophilous alsowithregard to social char-acteristics that are uncorrelated with ability, research showed that initial differences in the employment rate could result in greaterwage inequalitiesovertime (Montgomery,1991;Arrow https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socnet.2018.03.005

0378-8733/©2018TheAuthors.PublishedbyElsevierB.V.ThisisanopenaccessarticleundertheCCBY-NC-NDlicense(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.

(2)

and Borzekowski,2004).Exogenously provided job information thatispassedonvianetworktiesalsoenlargessmallinitial dif-ferences(Calvó-ArmengolandJackson,2004,2007).

Afewstudieslookedatreferrals(Engströmetal.,2012;Beaman andMagruder,2012;Beamanetal.,2013;CariaandHassen,2013; FernandezandGreenberg,2013)andotherstructuralmechanisms thataffectdiscrimination(seeOlianetal.,1988foranearlier meta-analysis).Ourpaperaimstostudystructuralmechanismsthatcan influencedifferentialhiringpracticesexperimentally.

Themainadvantagesoftheexperimentalmethodologyarethat: (a)thehypothesizedcorrelationscanbetestedunambiguouslyin afullycontrolledenvironmentthatexcludesconfoundingeffects (e.g.,Smith,1991;Roth,1993;WebsterandSell,2007);(b) genera-tiverelationscanbeidentified;(c)replicationoffindingsispossible (e.g.,Chapin,1932;FalkandFehr,2003;WillerandWalker,2007; Fehr and Gintis,2007;Bohnet,2009; Falk and Heckman,2009; Smith,2010).Itisworthnotingthatexperimentalstudiesmight helpustoidentifymechanismsthatcanbeempiricallyexamined indifferentcontexts(Camerer,2003;Ostrom,2010;Ariely,2008; FalkandHeckman,2009).

Classicaland recent small group experiments in social psy-chologytestifiedtothehumantendencytodiscriminateunknown partnersbasedoncategorymembership(e.g.,Brewer,1979,1996; Dovidioetal.,2002;Fiske,2009).Similarly,recentlaboratoryand fieldstudiesineconomicsandsociologyconfirmedtheexistenceof discriminativepractices(e.g.,SolnickandSchweitzer,1999;Pager etal.,2009;Jackson,2009;Midtbøen,2014;Agerström,2014;Lee etal.,2015).Somelaboratorystudieswereabletoisolateimportant behavioral effectsand interactionalinfluencesin discrimination (e.g.,Keuschniggand Wolbring,2015; Takácsetal.,2015; Lane, 2016).

Veryfewstudieshavetriedtoanalyzefactorsrelatedtosocial capital in hiring experimentally (Godechot, 2016). This can be explainedasitisverydifficulttodepictthecomplex characteris-ticsofsocialcapitalinthelaboratory,causingconcernsofexternal validity. But exactlydue to thecomplex nature of social capi-talrelatedprocesses,fieldresearchcannotfullydisentanglethe informationalaspectsofsocialcapitalfromothermechanismson discrimination.Bycontrast,carefullydesignedexperimentsusing simplenetworkstructurescanprovideusatrulycausalaccountby focusingonspecificmechanismsinherentintherelational struc-ture(Kosfeld,2004;WillerandWalker,2007;Gërxhanietal.,2013; BrashearsandQuintane,2015;BrashearsandGladstone,2016).In ourcase,theexperimentaldesigncanconcentrateandrelyonsome elementaryandempiricallyrelevantmechanismsthatpotentially determinediscriminationinhiring.Oneofthesemechanisms cov-ersreferralscomingfromworkers.Anotheronesummarizesthe informationflowcomingfromotheremployerswhoareverymuch inthesamesituationandhavesimilargoals.Acquiring,passingon, andexchanginginformation betweenemployersabout employ-eesisverydifficulttotraceinfieldstudies.Tagsandsignalsthat characterizeworkersarealsomulti-dimensional,somecorrelate withinternalqualitiesandskills,whileothersdonot.Asourstudy demonstrates,thesemechanismscanbeabstractedandusedin thelab.Inordertoallowforcausalinference,ourlaboratory exper-imentsexcludeconcernsaboutstrategicchoicesandendogeneity inrecommendationsandreferralsbydesign.

Itanalyzeshiringdecisionsinacontrolledsettingandisable toreducethehighdimensionalityofrealityintoastraightforward model.

Given thecomplexity of hiring choices in the labormarket, empiricalfieldresearchisunabletotestunivocallywhether refer-ralsincreasediscriminationcomparedtoabaselinecasewithout referrals or not. Furthermore, it cannot be explored whether referralsmakeadifferencealsowithoutanyinitialbiasesor alter-natively,observedinequalitiesaretherebecauseofhistoricalpath

dependence.Besides,inexistingfieldstudies,workerreferralsand informationflowamongemployersareconsideredjointlyandtheir impactsarehardlyseparated.

In order to overcome these empirical difficulties, following Takácsetal.(2015),wehavedesignedalabormarketexperiment whereparticipants(universitystudents)wereaskedtoplay the roleofemployersandselectfictiveworkersbelongingtotwo cate-gories.Inourexperiment,byexcludingcontextualeffectsandother importantaspectsofthehiringprocess,wetestedthenetandthe jointeffectsofreferrals,informationflowfromotheremployers,and qualitystandardsondiscrimination.

Referralshavebeendefinedasrecommendationsforhiringby workersin-house(Montgomery,1991;FountainandStovel,2014). Referralsarenaturallybiasedtowardsmembersofthein-group. Thischaracteristicfeaturehasbeendepictedinourexperimental design.Informationflowhasbeenconceptualizedasanautomated process in a simple directed network of employers. This con-ceptualizationcovers multiple mechanisms accordingto which employers gettoknow thetruequalitiesof workersemployed atconnectedfirms;suchasrecommendationletters,information exchange,andobservations thattakeplaceasa resultof estab-lishedcontactbetweentheorganizations.Qualitystandardswere evaluationthresholdssetupexogenouslytodeterminewhetherit iseconomicaltokeepworkersinhouseornot.

Inourexperiment,representinganidealisticworld,therewas nodifferenceinthemeananddistributionofqualityofworkersin thetwocategories;hencetheimpactofhistoricalpathdependence andinitialbiasescouldbeexcluded.Notethatsignificantelements ofeverydayinteractionswereneglectedinourlabormarket lab-oratory.Forinstance,therewasnorecruitmentprocedureinthe experimentaswewereinterestedindiscriminationwhenhiring decisionsaremade.Recruitmentitselfcanaddanextralayerof dis-criminationbyselectivelytargetingcertaingroupsorusingbiased information channels.Moreover, in reality,workers themselves couldapplyselectively byexpectingdiscrimination.These com-plicationsarepresentinthefieldandwoulddistorttheevaluation ofimpartialityofhiringdecisionsinthelab.

Ourresearchquestionswereasfollows.

1.Doesdiscriminationoccurinanartificiallabormarketwith bal-ancedandfairconditions?

2.Dohigherqualitystandardscreatemorediscrimination?Orin otherwords,ifemployersarerewarded onlyforhighquality workers,willdiscriminationincrease?

3.Doworkerreferralsincreasediscrimination?

4.Doesflowofaccurateinformation inanetworkofemployers decreasediscrimination?

Thesequestionsconcernprimarilythebehavior ofindividual employers.Inaddition,wewerealsoabletoanalyzewhether occa-sionalindividualbiasesbalanceeachotheroutortheyaddupto inequalityofemploymentbetweengroupsinourartificiallabor marketwithbalancedandfairconditions.

Hypotheses

Aninclinationtowardsdiscrimination

AssuggestedbyTakácsandSquazzoni(2015),whobuiltasimple modelofanidealizedlabormarketinwhichtherewasnoobjective differenceinaveragequalitybetweengroupsandhiringdecisions werenotbiased,acertainlevelofdiscriminationcouldbeexpected alsoinanidealworldwithimpartialemployers.Judgmenterrorsof thiskindcouldbetheconsequenceof“rational”adaptivesampling ofavailableinformation(cf.Simon,1955;Denrell,2005;Fiedler

(3)

andJuslin,2006;LeMensandDenrell,2011;DenrellandLeMens, 2011).Thatis,peoplemakesystematic judgmenterrors asthey naïvelyextrapolate fromlimited information availabletothem. Moreover,psychologicalstudiesindicatedthatindividualsareto largeextentalsoprocessinformationinaccuratelyortheyrelyon biasedheuristics.Theyareconstrainedbyselectiveattentionand tendtoretaininformationconfirmingtheirbeliefs, while ignor-inginformationthatcontradictstheirexpectations(e.g.,Hamilton, 1981).Aninitialbiaswithsequential,path-dependenthiring deci-sionsmayresultinpersistentandself-reinforcingdiscriminative choices(e.g.,Hoefferetal.,2006).Theseexpectancyconfirmation sequenceshavebeenfoundinexperimentalresearch(Bergeretal., 1980;DarleyandFazio,1980)andareexpectedtoinfluencealso employerdecisionsinhiringprocesses.Theseconsiderationsledus toformulatethefollowinghypothesis:

Hypothesis1. Anon-zerolevelofdiscriminationisexpectedalso inthebaselineconditionofnoreferralsintheidealistic experimen-tallabormarket.

Higherstandardsanddiscrimination

Higherqualitystandardsforapplicant qualitiescanoriginate inhigherneedforthebestqualitylaborforce,inmore demand-ingtasks,inintensemarketcompetition,andinsimplegreediness. Employerswhohavehighstandardsforapplicantssortout can-didateswhowould otherwisebe abletoconductthejob.After employment,employerswithhigherstandardsarenoteasily satis-fiedandexperimentmorewithnewhires.Thatis,higherstandards areusedforselectionand alsofor keepingthelaborforce(e.g., TakácsandSquazzoni,2015).Higherstandardsaretypicalforhigh statusjobsandforjobswherespecializedknowledgeoradvanced skillsarerequired.Advancedskillscouldbelearntafter employ-mentwithinhouse,butthatrequiresexpensiveinvestmentsfrom theemployer.Theseinvestmentsareeasilylostiftheemployee quitsthejob.Turnovercoststhereforearemuchhigherinjobsthat requireadvancedskillsthaninjobsthatdonot.

Greedysearch(“over-searching”)thattriestoseekbetter alter-nativesthananemployeewiththequalitystandardoftheoptimal reservationlevelconveysaloss(e.g.,McCall,1970;Stigler,1961, 1962;Mortensen,1986).Asearchthatisextendedbeyondthe alter-nativethatisatleastasgoodasthereservationlevelresultsin anexpectedrelativelossnotjustbecauseofsearchcosts,butalso becausetheaverageexpectedqualityofnewworkersissmaller thanthatofthecurrentalternative.Extendedsearchandrepeated failuresimplythatthehigherqualitystandardsalsoresultinlower employerprofits.

Forthesakeofsimplicity,inourexperiment,weassumedthat employershavenoopportunitytotraintheirworkersandtheydo notfacedifferentialturnovercosts.Wewereprimarilyinterestedin theconsequencesofsettingahigherqualitystandardexogenously forworkerselectionforlabormarketinequality.

Ahigherqualitystandardimpliesmoreexperimentationwith new workers.Information cues therefore could have a greater importanceforemployerdecisions.Inourexperiment,theonly availableinformationcue wascategorymembership.Its impor-tance,therefore,is expectedtoincreasefor employerswho are motivatedtohirenewworkerswithhighquality.Hence,weexpect thatemployerslookingforhighqualityworkersconsidergroup markersmore closely and, dependingonavailable information, areinclinedtodevelopbiasedgroupreputations.Thefewhighly skilledworkerswhomtheyaresatisfiedwitharekeptinhouseand continuetobiastheemployer’sjudgmentaboutavailableskillsin thegroups.Becauseofthelargerperceivedroleofsupplementary informationandtheover-representationofskilledworkerskeptin houseforgroupreputationformation,higherdiscriminationrates

couldoccurforemployerswithhigherqualitystandards.Thisled ustooursecondhypothesis.

Hypothesis2. Higherqualitystandardsleadtohigher discrimi-nationrates.

Referralsanddiscrimination

Socialnetworkscanbeusedinjobhiringfortworeasons.First, duetoitsaffectivecontent,asocialtiecreatesanobligationforthe workerin-houseononeendandanopportunityforthejob-seeker attheotherendoftheconnection.Second,networktiesare chan-nelsofgathering,conveying,andsignalinginformationonhidden individualqualities.Dependingonwhichaspectismoreprevalent, referralsmighthavedifferentconsequencesfordiscrimination(cf. RubineauandFernandez,2015).

Workerreferralsbetweencurrentand prospectiveemployees buildontheaffectivecontentofrelationshipsandaremore con-cerned with the welfare of the applicant, less with employer benefits.Thismeansthatworkerreferralsdonotnecessarilyreflect informationonqualityanddonotallowtheemployertofind opti-malmatchesinhiring.Consequently,ifconsideredatall,worker referralsarenottakenintoaccountbecauseofdirectprofit-seeking motives.

Workerreferralsarebasedonsocialtiesthatarehomophilous toalargeextentintheethnicand otherimportantdimensions (McPhersonetal.,2001; RubineauandFernandez,2013).When referralnetworksare usedin whichties are typicallybased on homophily, theycause labormarket segregation(Model, 1993; Tilly,1998;Elliott1999,2001;Kugler,2003;StovelandFountain, 2009). With homophilous referrals, labor market segregation develops endogenouslyeven withnon-prejudicedagents (Barr, 2009).

Empiricalworkshowedthat membersof a particularethnic grouptendtorecommendotherswiththesameethnicbackground forajob(Elliott,2001;FernandezandFernandez-Mateo,2006).This canreinforcetheirdisadvantagedpositionandexcludethemfrom betterjobs(Wilson,1987).Therefore,thedeficitofdisadvantaged groupsdoesnotdependonthefactthattheywouldrelylessor moreonnetworksinfindingajob.Rather,itdependsonthefact thattheyextensivelyrelyon“wrongnetworks”thatcannotoffer themgoodjobs(FernandezandFernandez-Mateo,2006;Petersen etal.,2000).

Thecharacteristicfeatureofworkerreferralsthatweenteredin thelaboratoryistheirhomophilouscharacterwithregardto cat-egorymembership.Weassumethattheirpresencereinforcesthe initialrandomdelusionsofemployersaboutgroupdifferences(cf. FernandezandGreenberg,2013).Consequently,wecan hypoth-esizethatdiscriminationisstrongerwithworkerreferralsthanin caseofisolated,unconnectedemployers.Asweareinterestedinthe discriminationtendenciesofemployers,referralsbyfictiveworkers inourexperimentconsideredtobearandomwithin-groupprocess. Hypothesis3. Homophilousworkerreferralsincrease discrimi-nationrates.

Anetworkofinformationflowanddiscrimination

In contrasttoaffectivecontent ofworker referrals, theflow ofaccurateand relevant information betweenemployersabout workers coulddecrease information asymmetry in hiring deci-sions(Fernandezetal.,2000;Elliott,2001).Witha correctview onindividualqualitiesinalargerpoolofworkers,employerscould arriveatbetterinformeddecisions.Thisisinlinewiththeempirical factthatrecommendationsfrombusinesspartnersandrespected employersareconsideredseriouslyatjobinterviews.Surveysof personnelofficersfoundthatrecommendationsfromamanager

(4)

weremoreimportantforhiringthanobjectivesignals,suchashigh schoolgrades(Rosenbaumetal.,1990;Spoonley2008:27).

Whenemployersareisolatedandbasedecisionsonlyontheir ownexperience,decisionscouldbebiasedinfavorofonegroupor another.Ifadditionalinformationisreceivedaboutthequalitiesof individualworkersandgroups,thentheincreasedamountof infor-mationisexpectedtodecreasethestatisticalbiasfromindividual sampling.Inordertoprovidestandardizedconditionsforhiring decisions,informationflowisconsideredasanautomatedprocess inourexperiment.Pleasenotethatwedesignedourexperimentto guaranteethattheinformationexchangedisaccurate.Hence,we avoidedthestrategiccomplexityofrecommendationsinbusiness lifeforthesakeofsimplicity.

Employerswerearrangedinasimplecircularnetwork.Related experimentalresearchoncoordination incircular networkshas foundmixedevidenceaboutconvergencetowardsasingle con-sensus(Keseretal.,1998;Berninghausetal.,2002).

Biasesofindividualemployersfavoringonegrouporanotherare expectedtobalanceeachotheroutattheaggregatedlevelofthe fairlabormarket.Informationflowbetweenemployers,however, createsnetworkexternalitiesasemployersmightbepronetosocial influence.Inaperfectlybalancedidealisticworldasrepresentedin ourexperiment,socialinfluence(Takácsetal.,2016;Flacheetal., 2017)andthe“wisdomofthecrowd”(Galton,1907;Surowiecki, 2005;Lorenzetal.,2011)areexpectedtodrivethegrouptowards consensus.Flowoftrustedinformationbetweenemployerscould beviewedasaninsurancedevice(cf.GemkowandNeugart,2011) thatbringmarketsclosertoperfection,therebydecreasing inequal-ityinemployment.Experimentsshow,however,thatanaverage initialbiasandevenmildsocialinfluencecouldunderminethe wis-domofthecrowd(Lorenzetal.,2011),implyingthatinourcase socialinfluencecouldenlargeratherthandiminishinequalityin employment.

Thisledustoformulatethefollowinghypothesisatthelevelof individualemployersthatcould,butnotnecessarilytranslatedto morebalancedemploymentchancesattheaggregatedlevel. Hypothesis4. Accesstoreliableinformationinthenetworkof employersaboutindividualworkerqualitiesdecreases discrimi-nationrates.

Interactioneffects

Higherqualitystandardsareexpectedtoincrease discrimina-tionwhenthereisasymmetryofinformation,becauseemployers aremoredisappointedwithnewlaborforceandrelyextensively onfewhighqualityworkerskeptinhouse(TakácsandSquazzoni, 2015).Atthesametime,additionalandtrustedinformationfrom otheremployerscouldreducethisbiasandevenimprovethe situ-ation.Thisisbecauseemployersaremoremotivatedtohirequality workersandcouldovercometheirintrinsicpartialityforoneofthe groupsassoonasadequateinformationbecomesavailable.

Fortheemployers,workerreferralsenlargethepoolofworkers fromthecategorythatisalreadyoverrepresented.Ashigh stan-dardsincreasetheturnoverrateandemployerscontinuetofollow theirworkers’advices,thiscouldpotentiallyresultina positive interactioneffect(e.g.,Takácsetal.,2015).Wehaveexaminedthese potentialinteractioneffectsinourexperimentbytheinclusionof treatmentsinwhichamixtureofourmanipulationswaspresent. Method

Experimentaldesign

We designed an experiment where participants played the roleofemployersandaskedtohireworkersfortheirfirm.

Par-ticipantsplayed anonymouslyingroupsofsix,withtwogroups playingsimultaneouslyinthesamelaboratorytoavoid identifica-tionofothergroupmembers.Theyinteractedthroughacomputer networkrunningtheexperimentalsoftwarez-Tree(Fischbacher, 2007).Participantswereaskedtoimaginethattheywere employ-ers and were invited to hire 10 workers per period, which representedonecontractyear.

WorkerswerevirtualagentsandhadIDnumbersfrom1to200. Eachworkerhadafixedqualitydrawnfromauniforminteger dis-tributioninthe[0,19]intervalatthebeginningofthegame.Halfof theworkerswerelabeledas‘blues’,halfas‘greens’.Colorswerenot relatedtothequalityofworkers:thedistributionofqualitywas, onaverage,thesameforbluesandgreens.Subjectswerenotaware oftheexactdistributionofqualities.Theirinstructions,however, containedthat“ThereareplentyofBLUEandGREENworkersinthe marketwithamaximumqualityvalue”(Supp.Mat.).Inshort, sub-jectswerenotawareofanyinitialdifferencebetweentheworkers’ groupsthatcouldberesponsibleforindividualdiscriminationand suchdifferenceinfactdidnotexist.

Inallexperimentalconditions,participantscouldselecteach worker using one of thefollowing options: (i) hiring a worker randomly;(ii)hiringablueworkerrandomly;(iii)hiringagreen workerrandomly;(iv)hiringoneoftheworkerstheyhiredinthe previousperiod.Toallowparticipantstouse(iv),thelistofworkers hiredinthepreviousperiod,includingtheirqualityandcolor,was displayedontheirscreen(Supp.Mat.).Theseoptionswere supple-mentedintherespectiveexperimentalconditionswith(v)hiring workersthatwerehiredbytheconnectedemployerinthe previ-ousperiod(informationflow)and(vi)hiringworkersreferredby workersin-house.

Afterthehiringstage(i.e.,attheendofeachperiod),participants wereaskedtoprovideanestimationoftheaveragequalityofboth bluesandgreensintheentirepool,whichservedtomeasuretheir actualbeliefsandprejudice.Wesimulatedturnover(random fluc-tuation)byexcluding10percentofworkersfromthelistdisplayed tosubjectsineachround.Excludedworkerswereunavailablefor hiringwithprocedure(iv).

Eachexperimentincluded25periods.Theprofitofemployers dependedonthequalityofhiredworkers,whichwasunknown beforehiringexceptthatofworkershiredinthepreviousperiod. Lowandhighqualitystandardswereimplementedwiththe fol-lowingexogenousthresholdrule.Thethresholdwas=12inthe caseoflowqualitystandards(−S)and=17inthecaseofhigh qualitystandards(+S).Thresholdswereimperativeforindividual payoffs.Specifically,profitwascalculatedbysummingthequality ofworkerswithqi≥,anddividingtheresultbyten(thenumberof

jobsatthefirm).Therefore,qualitystandardsweresetupbydesign intheexperiment.

Attheendofeachperiod,theaveragequalityofblueandgreen workershiredbytheparticipantwascalculatedanddisplayedwith thenumberofpointsearned.Attheendoftheexperiment, partic-ipantswereaskedtocompletea shortquestionnaire.Individual profitswereaveragedacrossall25periods,witheachpointbeing exchangedwithoneEuro.Earningswerecashedimmediatelyafter theendoftheexperiment.

Wefollowedabetween-subjects2×2×2fullfactorialdesign. We manipulated:a)highorlow qualityemployerstandards,b) thepresenceofinformationflowbetweenemployers,andc)the presenceofworkerreferrals(Table1).Therefore,weincludedeight treatments,i.e.,fourtestingforeffectsofthesemanipulationsalone andfourexaminingtheirinteractions.

Incaseofinformationflowbetweenemployers(+E),each par-ticipantwaslinkedtoanotheremployerinadirectedcirclenetwork withsixnodes(Fig.1).Instructionsreferredtoemployernetwork tiesas“friends”(Supp.Mat.).Thisreferencehasbeenmadeinorder toincreasethecredibilityofinformationconveyedandtomakethe

(5)

Table1 Treatmentoverview. Treatment High standards Information flow Worker referrals Pureeffects −S−E−W

+S−E−W 䊏 −S+E−W 䊏 −S−E+W 䊏 Interaction effects +S+E−W 䊏 䊏 −S+E+W 䊏 䊏 +S−E+W 䊏 䊏 +S+E+W 䊏 䊏 䊏

experimentalsituationmorerealistic.Intheinformationflow

con-dition(+E),ownworkershiredinthepreviousperiod,andthose

hiredinthepreviousperiodbythefriendweredisplayed

automat-ically,includingcolorandqualityofworkerswithoutanyerror.

Theaveragequalityofblueandgreenworkershiredbythefriend

wasalsodisplayed.Toenhanceinformationflowfurther,subjects

receivedtheirfriends’estimatesabouttheaveragequalityofblues

andgreens.Intheinformationflowcondition(+E),subjectscould

alsoselectaworkerwhowashiredbythebusinessfriendinthe

previousperiod(selectionprocedurev).Notethatthismeantthat

thesameworkercouldbehiredbytwoormoreparticipantsinthe

sameperiodandbestworkerswerenotsubjecttocompetitionby

businessfriends.Thisexcludedthepossibilitythatdecisionspeed

woulddeterminewhichemployerhiresaworkerwithsuperb

qual-ity.Participantsdidnotknowtheentirenetworkstructure;hence

strategicconsiderationswereunimportantforwhocouldhirethe

bestworkers. In case of noinformation flow (−E),no network

existedandnoneofthesubjectsknewtheworkershiredbyother

subjectsorothers’estimationsofworkers’quality.

Intheworker referralscondition(+W),eachworker hiredin

thepreviousperiod ‘recommended’a friend of the samecolor,

randomlyselected,withoutrevealing itsquality.The suggested

workerswereshowninaspecificlistontheparticipants’screen.

Incaseof workerreferrals(+W),subjectscouldselecta worker

fromthislist(selectionprocedurevi).Incaseofnoworker

refer-rals(−W),participantsdidnothavealistofrecommendedworkers.

Participantswerefullyawarethatworkerswillgiveahomophilous

referral(seefullinstructionsinSupp.Mat.).

Subjects

Atotalof144subjects(56percentfemales)forming24groups

participatedintheexperiment,whichwasheldintheGECS

com-puterlaboftheDepartmentofEconomicsandManagementofthe

UniversityofBrescia,Italy.Subjectswereuniversitystudent

vol-unteersrecruitedacrossalluniversityfacultiesusingtheonline

platformORSEE(Greiner,2004).Theygaveinformedconsent.

Par-ticipantearningsaveragedtoD12.49(std.dev.D3.65),plusafixed show-upfee ofD5.Theexperiment, includinginstruction read-inganda finalquestionnaire,tookapproximatelyonehour.The fullinstructionsforparticipantsareincludedintheSupplementary Material.

Discriminationindexes

Wedefinedmicroleveldiscriminationastheaverageextentto whichindividualparticipantshiredworkersfromasinglegroupas ourmaindependentvariable.Themicroleveldiscriminationindex ıittakesanindividualvalueforeachparticipanti{1,...,144}in eachperiodt∈{1,...,25}.Itwasdefinedasoneminustheratioof thenumberofworkersofthemorediscriminatedgrouphiredbyi

Fig.1. Theinformationflownetworkintheexperiment.

Note:Nonetworkinformationwasgiventothesubjects.Subjectshavereceived

thefollowinginstructionintreatment(+E):“Duringtheexperiment,someofthe

otheremployerswillbeconsideredas‘yourfriends’.Asfriendscommunicatewith

eachother,yourfriendemployerswillshareinformationabouttheworkersthey

employ.Hence,inthesesituations,youwillgettoknowthequalityoftheworkers

employedbyyourfriendsandyoucanalsoselectaworkerfromthislist,whichwill

bedisplayedinthemiddleofyourscreen.Inthiscase,youwillbeabletoselect

workerswhomyourfriendsemployedinthepreviousyear...”

inperiodttothenumberofhiredworkersofthelessdiscriminated group.Formally: ıit={ 1−H g it Hb it if Hitg≤Hb it 1−H b it Hitg if H g it>Hitb (1)

whereHitbwasthenumberofhiredbluesandHitgwasthenumber

ofhiredgreensbyparticipantiinperiodt.Eq.(1)showsthatıitwas

0incaseofnodiscriminationand1ifallworkerswereofthesame color,withintermediatecasesofdiscriminationfallinginbetween. Toanalyzewhetheronegroupisfavoredoveranotheroneand discriminationtendenciesspreadorbalanceeachother,wealso definedmacroleveldiscriminationastheobjectiveextenttowhich groupsweredisproportionally hiredinthegivenperiod.Thisis importantbecause,althoughindividualemployersmightbe per-fectdiscriminators,thismaynotgenerateemploymentinequality ifmutualdiscriminationtendenciesacrossdifferentfirmsare bal-anced.

Themacro-leveldiscriminationindextissimilartothe

micro-levelindexbutisdefinedatthegrouplevel.Morespecifically,itwas calculatedasoneminustheratioofthenumberofworkersofthe morediscriminatedgrouphiredbyallthesixemployerstothe work-ersofthelessdiscriminatedgrouphired.Thismeansthatttook

asinglevalueineachperiodtanditsmathematicalformulation wasequivalenttoEq.(1)butHtbandHtg werecomputedasthe

sumofallbluesandgreenhiredinperiodt.Asforthemicro-level index,t was0fornoinequalityinemploymentandincreased

withincreasingdiscriminationupto1. Results

Testingforpureeffects

Wewillpresentourresultsinthreesteps.First,wewill dis-cussresultsfromtheno-interactiontreatments,inwhichonlyone manipulationwasintroducedatonce.Thiswillhelptohighlight thepureeffectof highquality standards,informationflow, and workerreferralsondiscrimination.Second,wewilldiscussresults ondiscriminationfromalltreatmentsthatincludedalso interac-tions.Third,wewillanalyzeemployerearnings.Althoughpayoffs werenotessentialtoourmainresearchquestions,theiranalysis hasimportanteconomicimplications.

(6)

Table2

Thenumberofworkershiredthroughdifferentoptions.

Treatment Newworkersrandomly(i-iii) Re-hiringworkers(iv) Hiringfromemployercontact(v) Hiringviaworkerreferrals(vi) Total(i-vi) no-interactiontreatments −S−E−W 1827 2651 4478 +S−E−W 3093 1405 4498 −S+E−W 782 2542 1155 4479 −S−E+W 1212 2493 792 4497 interactiontreatments +S+E−W 820 2708 951 4479 −S+E+W 719 2136 1280 351 4486 +S−E+W 1439 2043 985 4467 +S+E+W 745 2005 1209 510 4469 Total 10,637 17,983 4595 2638 35,853

Note:N=3600hiringdecisionswithamaximumof10workersperdecision.

Table3

Meansandstandarddeviationsofdiscriminationindexesinno-interactiontreatments.

Treatment micro–leveldiscriminationindex discriminationindexinrehiring macro-leveldiscriminationindex

N Mean SD SE N Mean SD SE N Mean SD SE

−S−E−W 450 0.283 0.275 0.013 400 0.367 0.275 0.014 75 0.173 0.060 0.034

+S−E−W 450 0.426 0.301 0.014 361 0.514 0.500 0.017 75 0.238 0.015 0.009

−S+E−W 450 0.366 0.227 0.011 402 0.466 0.293 0.015 75 0.322 0.116 0.067

−S−E+W 450 0.438 0.313 0.015 402 0.516 0.325 0.016 75 0.204 0.031 0.018

Note:Themacro-leveldiscriminationindexcouldonlybeaffectedlogicallyinthe−S+E-Wtreatment.

Table4

Mixed-effectsregressiononthemicro-leveldiscriminationindexinno-interactiontreatments(N=1800),withrandomeffectsforindividualsandgroups.Thedegreesof freedomwerecomputedusingSatterthwaite’sapproximation.

(Intercept) Estimate SE t p Estimate SE t p

0.283 0.042 6.736 0.000 0.239 0.083 2.892 0.006 treatmenteffects +S 0.143 0.060 2.406 0.043 0.150 0.063 2.392 0.045 +E 0.082 0.060 1.384 0.204 0.090 0.064 1.406 0.196 +W 0.154 0.060 2.595 0.032 0.161 0.063 2.552 0.035 subjectcharacteristics male 0.018 0.036 0.499 0.619 religious 0.006 0.038 0.166 0.868 economics 0.006 0.043 0.140 0.889 studyyear 0.011 0.013 0.859 0.394 part2 −0.016 0.012 −1.385 0.166 F 35.507 0.000 8.479 0.001

Note:Thedummyvariable“economics”hadavalueofoneiftheparticipantwasstudyingeconomicsormanagement.

Theupper four rows in Table2 show thatall available

hir-ingmethods(i–vi)wereselectedfrequentlybyparticipantsinthe no-interactiontreatments.Re-hiringofworkers(iv)wasfavored tohiring workersfromemployercontacts(v) andto hiringvia workerreferrals(vi).Re-hiringwasmorecommoninthelow qual-itystandardscondition.Higherqualitystandardsresultedinmore churnandexperimentationwithnewworkers.Table3 displays anoverviewofmeanıit valuesinno-interactiontreatments.All

factormanipulationsproducedsignificantlyhigherdiscrimination thanthebaseline(Wilcoxonranksumtestsonindividualaverages: W=83,p=0.006for+S;W=110,p=0.052for+E;W=89,p=0.010 for+W;allpvaluesareonetailed).

Notethatdiscriminationindexvaluescannotbefullyattributed toonemethodofhiringoranotherasparticipantscouldre-hire workers or select other hiring methods in every round. They typicallyused combinedstrategies and mighthave individually compensatedfortheirownbiasin onetype ofhiringby favor-inganothergroupwhenchoosinganotherhiringmethod.Still,in ordertoseetheextentofdiscriminationthatcouldpotentiallybe linkedtokeepingworkersinhouseselectively,wecalculatedıit

valuesforre-hiresonly.Table3showsthesemeanvalues(see mid-dlecolumns).Itisremarkablethatparticipantsweremorebiased

infavorofonegroupwhenre-hiringworkers.Thediscrimination indexforre-hireswashigherineveryexperimentalconditionthan themeandiscriminationvalueforotherhiringmethods.Although thesefactorsareintertwined,itisprobablethatdiscriminationby groupmembershipwasmoreinfluentialinkeepingworkersthan hiringnewones.

Asourdataincludedrepeatedobservationsofthesame indi-vidual,weestimatedamixed-effectsmodelwithrandomeffectsat theindividualandgrouplevel(hereafterMEmodel).Therecould befurtherdependenciesinourdataascurrentchoicesmighthave beeninfluencedbyearlierexperiencesindifferentways(cf.e.g., Ule,2008; Corten,2009).Asweare notinterestedin theexact nature of these dependencies,they are covered by individual-leveleffects,theexperimentalpartdummyandtheothercontrols includedinthemodel.Table4showstheresultsofthemodel.The positiveinterceptindicatesthatasignificantlevelofdiscrimination occurredinalltreatments.Resultssupportedourfirsthypothesis.

Results confirmedalsoHypothesis 2,as higher quality stan-dards resultedin higherdiscrimination rates. Asformulated in Hypothesis3,workerreferrals(+W)increaseddiscriminationrates. Meanwhile,Hypothesis4wasnotsupportedastheinformation flow(+E)coefficientwasnotsignificantand,ifanything,thisfactor

(7)

Fig.2.Socialinfluenceondiscriminationintheinformationflow(+E)treatment.

Notes:N=1800decisions.Positivevaluesindicatebiastowardsgreensandnegativevaluesindicatebiastowardsblues.Casesatthezeropointareimpartialjudgments.Fitted

smoothregressionlineisindicated.

Fig.3.Confirmationbiasintheinformationflow(+E)treatment.

Notes:N=1800decisions.Positivevaluesindicatebiastowardsgreensandnegativevaluesindicatebiastowardsblues.Casesatthezeropointareimpartialjudgments.

tendedtoincreaseratherthandecreasediscrimination.Itis impor-tanttonotethatcontrolvariablesincludedinthemodel,i.e.,gender, religion,facultystudyyearhadnosignificanteffect.Wealso con-trolledforapossibleexperimentallearning(orfatigue)effectby includingadummyandfoundnosignificantdifferencesbetween thefirstandsecondhalfoftheexperiment.

Regardingmacro-leveldiscrimination,indexvaluesshowthat individualtendenciestodiscriminatehavebeenbalancedouttoa largeextentatthemacrolevel(Table3).Thetvalueof0.173inthe

−S−E−Wbaselineconditioncorrespondstoanimbalanceofhiring atotalof32.84workersfromonegroupand27.16workersfrom theothergrouponaverage(outof60).Theinformationflow treat-ment(+E),however,ledtohigherdiscriminationthanthebaseline (Table 3).This was themanipulation under which participants couldhavebeenaffectedbytheselectionofanotheremployer.The highertvalueimpliesthatindividualdiscriminationtendencies

ruledeachotherouttoalesserextent.Thesomewhathigher macro-leveldiscriminationindexintheinformationflow(+E)condition

impliesthatsomeemployershaveadoptedthebiasesoforhave beeninfluencedbytheircontacts.Fig.2displaysthatwhilethe mostdecisionswerefreeofbias,participantsslightlyincreasedthe partialityoftheirdecisionfavoringthegroupofworkersthathad ahigheraveragequalityattheconnectedemployer.Hence, par-ticipantspartlyadaptedtheirsamplingrationallygiventhenew availableinformation(cf.LeMensandDenrell,2011).Fig.3 high-lightsmoreevidentlythatdiscriminationwascontagiousinthe informationflowtreatment(+E).Alargerbiasbytheconnected employerresultedinlargerdiscriminationinfavor ofthesame groupofworkers,andthereforediscriminationwassubjecttosocial influenceintheexperiment.

Interactioneffects

The lowerfour rows in Table 2 showthat all available hir-ingmethods(i-vi)wereselectedfrequentlybyparticipantsinthe interactiontreatments.Re-hiringofworkers(iv)wasalwaysthe

(8)

Table5

Meansandstandarddeviationsofdiscriminationindexesininteractiontreatments.

Treatment micro–leveldiscriminationindex discriminationindexinrehiring macro-leveldiscriminationindex

N Mean SD SE N Mean SD SE N Mean SD SE

+S+E−W 450 0.224 0.206 0.010 421 0.356 0.300 0.015 75 0.146 0.110 0.013

−S+E+W 450 0.413 0.284 0.013 403 0.553 0.336 0.017 75 0.264 0.202 0.023

+S−E+W 450 0.477 0.334 0.016 403 0.633 0.336 0.017 75 0.198 0.132 0.015

+S+E+W 450 0.483 0.292 0.014 370 0.592 0.328 0.017 75 0.385 0.178 0.021

Note:Themacro-leveldiscriminationindexcouldonlybeaffectedlogicallyinthe+Etreatments.

Table6

Mixed-effectsregressiononthemicro-leveldiscriminationindexincludinginteractioneffects(N=3600),withrandomeffectsforindividualsandgroups.Thedegreesof freedomwerecomputedusingSatterthwaite’sapproximation.

(Intercept) Estimate SE t p Estimate SE t p

0.283 0.040 7.064 0.000 0.229 0.062 3.662 0.001 treatmenteffects +S 0.143 0.057 2.523 0.023 0.150 0.060 2.484 0.025 +E 0.082 0.057 1.451 0.166 0.084 0.061 1.379 0.186 +W 0.154 0.057 2.721 0.015 0.163 0.061 2.699 0.016 +S*+E −0.284 0.080 −3.546 0.003 −0.292 0.086 −3.396 0.004 +S*+W −0.104 0.080 −1.292 0.215 −0.117 0.086 −1.354 0.195 +E*+W −0.107 0.080 −1.329 0.203 −0.118 0.086 −1.376 0.188 +S*+E*+W 0.314 0.113 2.769 0.014 0.335 0.123 2.732 0.015 subjectcharacteristics male 0.008 0.024 0.349 0.728 religious 0.019 0.026 0.716 0.475 economics 0.027 0.028 0.950 0.344 studyyear 0.006 0.009 0.599 0.550 part2 −0.000 0.008 −0.056 0.956 F 144.831 0.000 105.864 0.000

mostfavoredoption.Table5showsthatdiscriminationinre-hiring

washigherineveryinteractiontreatmentthan micro-level dis-crimination in general.Hiring workersfrom employercontacts (v) and new hires altogether (i-iii) weremore frequentlyused thanworkerreferrals(vi)whentheywereavailable.Treatments includinginteractionbetweenthemanipulatedfactorsgenerally ledtohighermicro-leveldiscriminationthanthebaseline,except when employers with high standards benefited from informa-tionfromotheremployersandworkerreferralswerenotpresent (Table5).Alldifferenceswiththebaseline(−S−E−W)were signif-icant:−S+E+W,+S−E+Wand+S+E+Wledtohigherdiscrimination (W=82, p=0.005,W=70,p=0.002and W=43,p<0.001 respec-tively,allpvalueswereonetailed),while+S+E−Wledtolower discrimination(W=226,p=0.022,onetailed).

We examinedinteraction effectsby estimatinga furtherME model.Notethat,unlikethepreviousmodels,alltreatmentswere includedintheanalysistocontrolforpureeffects.Severalpure andinteractioneffectsweresignificantinthenewmodel(Table6). Thesignsofallpurefactorcoefficientswerepositive,whichisin linewiththeresultspresentedintheprevioussection.Allbinary interactionsledtonegativecoefficientsbutonlytheinteractionof highqualitystandardsandinformationflow(+S*+E)was signifi-cant.ConsistentlywithHypotheses2and3,highqualitystandards (+S)and workerreferrals (+W)increaseddiscrimination.In line withHypothesis4,informationflow(+E)decreaseddiscrimination, althoughthathappenedonlyinconjunctionwithhighstandards.

Thecoefficientfortheinteractionofhighqualitystandardsand informationflow (+S*+E)wassufficientlylargetoovercomethe pureeffectsofthefactorsinvolved.Thismeansthatinthespecific caseofhighqualitystandards,informationflowactuallydecreased discrimination,despitetheoppositepureeffectsofthetwofactors. Thiscouldbeexplainedasfollows.Ontheonehand,incaseof lowqualitystandards,informationflowincreaseddiscrimination viaselectiveattentionorconfirmationbias.Ontheotherhand,in caseofhighqualitystandards,whenavailableinformationreally

mattered, information flow decreased employer partiality. This impliesthatwhentherewasashortageofworkerswith accept-ablequality,participantshaverealizedthebenefitsofadditional informationandacteduponaccordinglytoavoidprofitloss.

Theinteractionofhighqualitystandardsandworkerreferrals had a similareffect,although weaker.Given that there wasno informationbenefitinthecaseofworkerreferrals,anincreased alertness of employers withhigh quality standards couldhave reduced thepartiality of their judgment. Our results also sug-gestthateventhemutualpresenceofinformationflowbetween employersandworkerreferralscouldhavemadeemployersmore alertaboutpartiality.

Analternativeexplanationofpairwiseinteractioneffectsisthat informationflowandworkerreferralsoffseteachother.Thiscould haveoccurredwhenindividualdiscriminationdidnothavea coun-terpartintermsofmacroinequalityandneighboringemployers favoreddifferentgroups.Asthethree-wayinteractiontermshows, this balancingtendencyoccurredlesslikely foremployers with highstandards,whowerepickierintheirchoicesandtrappedmore likelybyconfirmationbias.

Exceptofthe+S+E−Wtreatmentthatshowedlower macro-leveldiscriminationthanthebaseline,informationflow(+E)ledtoa highervalueoft(Table5).Thisimpliesthatalsointheinteraction

treatments,individualbiasesdidnotruleeachotheroutcompletely inthepresenceofinformationflowbetweenemployers.This con-firmssomespread,butnotaninevitabledisseminationofbiased evaluationsinthenetworkofemployers.

Effectsonparticipants’earnings

Participants’payoffscouldbeseenasaproxyforthegeneral efficiencyintheallocationofworkerquality.Table7showsanME modelwherethedependentvariablewasthepayoffearnedineach periodofthegame.Followingtheobservationthathigher qual-itystandardsresultedinmoreexperimentationwithnewworkers

(9)

Table7

Mixed-effectsregressiononparticipant’speriodearnings(N=600),with randomeffectsforgroups.ThedegreesoffreedomwerecomputedusingSatterthwaite’s

approximation.

(Intercept) Estimate SE t p Estimate SE t p

12.388 0.639 19.375 0.000 10.415 0.941 11.074 0.000 treatmenteffects +S −5.659 0.904 −6.259 0.000 −5.609 0.915 −6.129 0.000 +E 3.497 0.904 3.868 0.001 3.671 0.926 3.964 0.001 +W −0.337 0.904 −0.373 0.714 −0.321 0.916 −0.351 0.730 +S*+E 4.603 1.279 3.600 0.002 4.361 1.303 3.346 0.004 +S*+W 2.654 1.279 2.075 0.054 2.549 1.303 1.956 0.068 +E*+W −0.447 1.279 −0.349 0.731 −0.603 1.302 −0.463 0.649 +S*+E*+W −2.820 1.808 −1.559 0.138 −2.461 1.854 −1.327 0.202 subjectcharacteristics male 0.123 0.360 0.341 0.734 religious −0.042 0.393 −0.108 0.914 economics −0.278 0.422 −0.660 0.511 studyyear 0.150 0.140 1.074 0.285 part2 3.218 0.105 30.521 0.000 F 472.233 0.000 440.719 0.000

1Itisworthoutliningthatmixedeffectsmodelswithindividualand/orgroup-levelrandomeffects,althoughtheyarenotalwaysstandardforexperimentaldataanalysis, representanefficientmethodthatcanbeprofitablyusedtoanalyzetheoutcomeofrepeatedgamespresentinginteractionsamongparticipants(e.g.,BarreraandBuskens, 2009;Boeroetal.2009a,b;Bravoetal.,2015).

(Table2),qualitystandardshadadirectimpactonpayoffs. Coher-entlywiththerulesofthegame,higherqualitystandardsledto lowerprofits.Incontrast,theinformationflow(+E)treatmentled tohigherearningsthatdemonstratesthedirectpayoffbenefitsof additionalavailableinformation.

Amongtheinteractioneffects,onlytheonebetween+Sand+E onewaspositiveandhighlysignificant,whiletheonebetween+S and+W,alsopositive,wasonlysignificantatthe10%level.None oftheindividualvariableswassignificant,whileearningsclearly increasedduringthegame.Thiswasexpectedasparticipantscould relyonalargersampleofworkerswhosequalityhasalreadybeen discoveredovertime.

Discussionandconclusions

Duetothecomplexityofmechanismsandproblemsoftheir identificationinthefield,wehavedesignedalaboratory experi-mentthatismeanttotesttheexistenceofabaselinetendencyfor impartiality,theimpactofahighernecessityofhighquality work-ers,theinfluenceofinformationflowinemployernetworks,and theroleofreferralsnetworksondiscriminationinhiringchoices. Intheexperiment,subjectsplayedtheroleofemployers. Repre-sentingasymmetricinformationintherealworld,subjectswere notawareofworkerqualitiesinadvanceandhadnoprior knowl-edgeaboutthedistributionofqualityforthetwocategories. In fact,workerqualitiesforthetwocategoriesweredrawnfromthe samedistributionandhencetherewasnoreasonforany impartial-ityinemployerdecisions.Thisneutralsituationprovidedthebest contrasttodemonstratetheinevitabilityofdiscrimination.

Wefoundthata substantiallevelof discriminationoccurred acrossalltreatments,confirmingthepresenceofabaseline incli-nationfordiscriminationalsoinanimpartialidealworld(Takács andSquazzoni,2015;Takácsetal.,2015).Thisisagainsttypical predictionsbymainstreameconomists,accordingtowhich belief-relateddiscriminationisnotviableasemployersnotsharingfalse beliefswouldgainacompetitiveadvantage(Arrow,1973;Aigner andCain, 1977).Accordingly,discriminationis costly:themost beneficialemployment strategyinourexperiment wasto com-pletelyneglectcolormarkers.Thereislittleevidence,however,that employerpracticesreflectefficientandrationalresponsesto dif-ferencesinskillsandturnovercostsinreality(BielbyandBaron, 1986;Kaufmannetal.,2015).Thisisconfirmedbythepersistence ofdiscriminationinallconditionsofourexperiment.

Wehypothesizedthatmorediscriminationcouldbeinduced byhigherstandardstowardsworkers(Hypothesis2).When stan-dardsare sethighexogenously,lower qualityworkers arealso employedbymereexperimentation,and hencepayoffsarealso lower.Ourfindingssuggestthathigherstandardsgeneratealarger biasandinequalityinhiring,confirmingprevioussimulation find-ings(TakácsandSquazzoni,2015).Subjectsactingasemployers withhighstandards reliedmoreonsupplementaryinformation ofgroupmembershipofworkersalreadyinhouseratherthanon theabundanceofinformationonthequalitiesofworkersscreened before.Inourexperiment,employerswithhighstandardskepta fewhighlyskilledworkersinhouseandthisbiasedtheirjudgment aboutthemeanqualityofsocialcategories.

Wedo notwant toconveythemessagethat thereis a gen-eralcognitivebiasofhumandecisionmakers,whichiscorrelated withhigherdesires andmore selectivepreferences.Our results rathersuggestthatanunintentionaladaptivesamplingbiasexists thatoriginatesfromtheover-generalizationofthequalityofthe smallsampleofemployeesinhouse(Denrell,2005;LeMensand Denrell,2011).Thisadaptive samplingbias wasmore probable whenemployerswithhighstandardswereinterestedinthemost qualifiedworkersonly(cf.Polman,2010;TakácsandSquazzoni, 2015).

Consideringcomplexcognitivemechanismsisnotrequiredto accountfor theemergence ofdiscrimination,althoughcomplex cognitivemechanismscouldin fact make thingsworse(Takács etal.,2015).Theeffectofhighstandardsondiscriminationcouldbe enlargedbyjudgmentbias,inparticularbyself-perceived objectiv-ity(UhlmannandCohen,2007),cherrypicking,andconfirmation bias(e.g.,Simon,1955,1956).Anotherpotentiallyrelevant mech-anismconcernsexpectancyconfirmationsequences.Inthiscase, individuals wouldbeconditionedbyselectiveattentionleading themtoconsideronlyinformationthatconfirmstheirbeliefs,while ignoringinformationthatcontradictstheirexpectations(Hamilton, 1981;Bergeretal.,1980;DarleyandFazio,1980).

Previousstudiesemphasizedtherelevanceofsocialnetworks forinequalitiesofemployment(e.g.,Montgomery,1991;Stoveland Fountain,2009; Beamanand Magruder,2012).Wages,job posi-tions, or workconditions coulddepend onsocial networks (cf. Montgomery,1991,1992;TianandLiu,2018).Weemphasizedthat socialnetworkeffectsinhiringcannotbeconsideredasasingle mechanism.Atleasttwoverydifferentmechanismsareatplay(cf. Gërxhanietal.,2013).Oneisworkerreferralthatfacilitateslabor

(10)

marketsegregationgiventheirhomophilouscharacter.Anotheris informationflowaboutworkersvianetworktiesofemployers,for instance,intheformofrecommendationsoractivesearchsuchas man-hunting.Accordingtothefirstnetworkmechanism,the affec-tivecontentof socialrelationshipscouldcreate obligationsthat makerecommendingandhiringfriendsmorelikely.Thisdisrupts thebasiclogicofa‘perfect’marketandresultsinsuboptimal allo-cationoflaborforce(e.g.,IoannidesandLoury,2004;Tassierand Menczer,2008).

Ourresultsconfirmedthatworkerreferralsincrease discrimina-tion(Hypothesis3).Wefoundincreaseddiscriminationwithworker referralsinourexperiment, althoughwe assumednoclustering ofworkerrelationsbyquality.Inamorerealisticscenario,where workersaremorelikelytogivereferralstoworkersofthesame groupandofsimilarquality,onecouldprobablyobserveaneven strongerbiasfavoringonegroupovertheother(cf.Montgomery, 1991). When contacts are homophilous, referral networks can reduceinequalityviaaninvertedadvantagemechanismonlyif ini-tialadvantageisnegativelycorrelatedwiththenewstatusvalue (DiMaggioandGarip,2012).

Contrarytoourexpectations(Hypothesis4),informationflow between employers increased discrimination. Previous studies showedthatbusinesscontactsareimportanttoreducetheeffectof informationasymmetryandhelpemployerstoevaluateproperly thelabormarketpotentialofanemployee(e.g.,Rosenbaumetal., 1990;Uzzi,1996).Ontheotherhand,incaseofdifficultevaluation ofquality,networkscanenlargefalsegeneralizationsandmight magnifytherandominitialbias.Evenunprejudicedemployersseek and rely on evaluationsof others. In case of racial discrimina-tion,thisleadstowhatisknownasracialprofiling(Groggerand Ridgeway,2006;FernandezandGreenberg,2013).

Thereisempiricalevidencethatpeoplearelargelyinfluenced bytheirsocialnetwork(e.g.,MarsdenandFriedkin,1993)and fol-lowadvicesometimesevenwhentheyhavedirectobservations (Sommerfeldetal.,2007;Gilbertetal.,2009).Weobtainedsome evidencethatintheinformationflowcondition(+E)ofour experi-ment,subjectsplayingemployerswereinfluencedtosomeextent byinformation they received. Adifferencein themean quality valuesofworkershiredbytheconnectedemployermadehiring fromthebettergroupmore likely. Participants,therefore, have learntfromtheexperiencesintheirnetwork,whichisconsistent withearlierresearchonlearninginnetworks(e.g.,Barreraandvan deBunt,2009;Hofstraetal.,2015;MasonandWatts,2012).At thesametime,discriminationwasprobablynotfullyconscious andwasnotonlyduetorationalsociallearning,asimpartiality inhiringwasoftencopiedfromtheconnectedemployer. Follow-ingthepreferencesofothersisindicativeofsocialinfluencethat resultedinsomebiascontagioninthenetwork.Furthermore, sub-jectscouldhavedevotedselectiveattentiontothegroupreputation estimatesoftheircontacts.Theypotentiallyconfirmedtheirbelief thathadfavoredoneofthegroupsifthiswasinaccordancewith theestimateoftheotheremployer.Otherwise,iftheestimateof theotheremployerwasnotinlinewiththeirs,theyprobably han-dledthisinformationwithlessattention.Thesefactorsaltogether haveresultedinsomespreadofdiscriminationinthenetwork. Indi-vidualbiasesdidnotbalanceeachotheroutcompletely,causinga certainextentofinequalityintheinformationflowcondition.

Furthermore, our resultsshowed that these factors interact witheach otherin complex ways. It is important tonote that thecombinedeffectofthesefactorswasnotastatisticalillusion duetotheparticularmethodused.Wefoundthatemployerswith highstandardshavemadeuseofinformationflowinawaythat decreaseddiscrimination.Theinteractionofhighqualitystandards andworkerreferralshadasimilardiminishingimpact.

Itseemsthatnetworkscontributedtomorepartialdecisionsof employerswithhighstandards,whohadtobemorecarefulabout

whomtheyemploy(TakácsandSquazzoni,2015).Moreover,the jointpresenceofinformationflowbetweenemployersandworker referralsdecreaseddiscrimination,probablybecausegroupquality informationoriginatingfromthesesourcesoffseteachother.We alsofoundathree-wayinteractioneffectofhighqualitystandards, informationflow,andworkerreferrals.Thisinteractioncouldhave occurredbecauseemployerswithhighstandardsweremorelikely tofallintoconfirmationbiasandneglectedthemorebalancedjoint perspectiveofinformationflowandworkerreferrals.

Obviously,ourresultsneedtobeinterpretedcautiouslygiven the high level of abstraction of the study from the real labor market.Severalimportantfeaturesofhiring processeswerenot coveredinourexperimentaldesign.Therewasnoapplication pro-cedureandhiringbydifferentemployerstookplacesimultaneously andwasrepeatedinthesamefashionseveraltimes.Participants werearrangedaccordingtoadirectedcirclenetworkandnoother informationflowstructureswereinvestigated.Workerswerenot decisionmakers,theyinfactdidnotwork,andtheircharacteristics didnotchangeovertime.Therewerenodifferencesinwagesand everyjobwasacceptabletoworkers.Theseandotherempirically relevantcharacteristicfeaturesofthehiringprocesswereexcluded onpurposeinordertoilluminatetheimpactofqualitystandards, informationflowinemployernetworks,andhomophilousworker referralsonhiringdiscrimination.

Participants themselvesplayingtherole of employersmight havediscountedtheadequatenessofthelabormarketframingfor thedecisionsituation.Theymighthaveperceivedthedecisiontask asanoptimizationproblemthatcanbeapproachedusingacertain hiringstrategy.Infact,thisisnotunrealisticatall,asmany employ-eesarestrategic intheirhumanrelations policyandlearn from theexperienceofothers.Conclusionsfromourexperiment, more-over,couldberelevanttocontextsotherthanthelabormarket. Qualitystandards,recommendations,andinformationfloware rel-evantfactorsinanyrepeatedselectiontask.Thesamemechanisms potentiallycontribute,forinstance,toconsumerdiscrimination.

Theidealisticconditionsinthelabwereaimedtohighlightsome fundamentaltendenciesofdiscriminationthatcouldbe strength-ened,altered,orevencuredinacomplexinstitutionalizedsetting. Inordertounderstandtheseaspectsbetter,furtherempiricaland fieldanalysisisneeded.Here,forinstance,empiricalstudiesthat lookatcross-culturalcomparisonscouldenrichour understand-ing of social and institutional embeddedness of discriminative outcomes(e.g.,Zschirntand Ruedin, 2016; Tianand Liu,2018). Providinga‘clean’testofcertainsimplehypotheseswhileleaving contextualeffectsinthebackgroundisanimportantstepto under-standemployerdiscriminationandexplorecountermeasuresthat couldhelpusreducethesedistortions.

Funding

Financial support for the conduct of the research has been providedbytheIntra-EuropeanFellowshipProgramofthe Euro-peanUnion(“0Discrimination”,GA-2009-236953).Thefirstauthor acknowledgessupportfromtheEuropeanResearchCouncil(ERC) undertheEuropeanUnion’sHorizon2020researchand innova-tionprogramme(GrantagreementNo648693).WethankMarco CastellaniandNiccolòCasnicifortheirpracticalhelp.

AppendixA. Supplementarydata

Supplementarydataassociatedwiththisarticlecanbefound, intheonlineversion,athttps://doi.org/10.1016/j.socnet.2018.03. 005.

(11)

References

Agerström,J.,2014.Whydoesheightmatterinhiring?J.Behav.Exp.Econ.52,

35–38,http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2014.06.002.

Aigner,D.J.,Cain,G.G.,1977.Statisticaltheoriesofdiscriminationinlabormarkets.

Ind.LaborRelat.Rev.30,175–187.

Ariely,D.,2008.PredictablyIrrational.TheHiddenForcesThatShapeOur

Decisions.HarperCollins,NewYork.

Arrow,K.J.andBorzekowski,R.2004LimitedNetworkconnectionsandthe

DistributionofWages.SSRNWorkingPaper.https://www.researchgate.net/

profile/KennethArrow/publication/5034990Limitednetworkconnections andthedistributionofwages/links/00463523741cbc1421000000.pdf.

Arrow,K.J.1973TheTheoryofDiscriminationinAshenfelter,OrleyandAlbert

Rees(ed.)DiscriminationinLaborMarkets,PrincetonUniversityPress.3–33.

Barr,T.,2009.Withfriendslikethese:endogenouslabormarketsegregationwith

homogeneous,nonprejudicedagents.Am.J.Econ.Sociol.68(3),703–746.

Barrera,D.,Buskens,V.,2009.Third-partyeffectsontrustinanembedded

investmentgame.In:Cook,K.,Snijders,C.,Buskens,V.,Cheshire,C.(Eds.), eTrust:FormingRelationshipsintheOnlineWorld.RussellSage,NewYork.

Barrera,D.,vandeBunt,G.G.,2009.Learningtotrust:networkseffectsthrough

time.Eur.Sociol.Rev.25(6),709–721,http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/esr/jcn078.

Beaman,L.,Magruder,J.,2012.Whogetsthejobreferral?evidencefromasocial

networksexperiment.Am.Econ.Rev.,3574–3593.

Beaman,L.,Keleher,N.,Magruder,J.,2013.DoJobNetworksDisadvantage

Women?EvidencefromaRecruitmentExperimentinMalawi.Departmentof Economics,NorthwesternUniversity(WorkingPaper).

Berger,J.,Rosenholtz,S.J.,Zelditch,M.,1980.Statusorganizingprocesses.Ann.Rev.

Sociol.6,479–508.

Berninghaus,S.,Erhart,K.M.,Keser,C.,2002.Conventionsandlocalinteraction

structures:experimentalevidence.GamesEcon.Behav.39(1),177–205.

Bertrand,M.,Chugh,D.,Mullainathan,S.,2005.Implicitdiscrimination.Am.Econ.

Rev.95(2),103–110.

Bian,Y.,Huang,X.,Zhang,L.,2015.Informationandfavoritism:thenetworkeffect

onwageincomeinChina.SocialNetworks40,129–138.

Bielby,W.T.,Baron,J.N.,1986.Menandwomenatwork:sexsegregationand

statisticaldiscrimination.Am.J.Sociol.91(4),759–799.

Boero,R.,Bravo,G.,Castellani,M.,Laganà,F.,Squazzoni,F.,2009a.Pillarsoftrust:

anexperimentalstudyonreputationanditseffects.Sociol.Res.Online14(5) (URL<http://www.socresonline.org.uk/14/5/5.html>).

Boero,R.,Bravo,G.,Castellani,M.,Squazzoni,F.,2009b.Reputationalcuesin

repeatedtrustgames.J.Socio-Econ.38,871–877.

Bohnet,I.,2009.Experiments.In:Hedström,P.,Bearman,P.(Eds.),TheOxford

HandbookofAnalyticalSociology.OxfordUniversityPress,pp.639–665.

Brashears,M.E.,Gladstone,E.,2016.Errorcorrectionmechanismsinsocial

networkscanreduceaccuracyandencourageinnovation.SocialNetworks44, 22–35.

Brashears,M.E.,Quintane,E.,2015.Themicrostructuresofnetworkrecall:how

socialnetworksareencodedandrepresentedinhumanmemory.Social Networks41,113–126.

Bravo,G.,Squazzoni,F.,Takács,K.,2015.Intermediariesintrust:indirect

reciprocity,incentives,andnorms.J.Appl.Math.2015(234528)(URL <http://www.hindawi.com/journals/jam/aa/234528/>).

Brewer,M.B.,1979.In-Groupbiasintheminimalintergroupsituation:a

cognitive-Motivationalanalysis.Psychol.Bull.86,307–324.

Brewer,M.B.,1996.In-Groupfavoritism:thesubtlesideofintergroup

discrimination.In:Messick,D.M.,Tenbrunsel,A.E.(Eds.),CodesofConduct. BehavioralResearchintoBusinessEthics.RussellSageFoundation.

Calvó-Armengol,A.,Jackson,M.O.,2004.Theeffectsofsocialnetworkson

employmentandinequality.Am.Econ.Rev.94(3),426–454.

Calvó-Armengol,A.,Jackson,M.O.,2007.Networksinlabormarkets:wageand

employmentdynamicsandinequality.J.Econ.Theory132,27–46.

Camerer,C.F.,2003.BehavioralGameTheory.PrincetonUniversityPress,Princeton.

Caria,A.S.andHassen,I.W.2013TheFormationofJobReferralNetworks.Evidence

fromaLab-in-the-FieldExperimentinUrbanEthiopia.InternationalFood

PolicyResearchInstitute(IFPRI)DiscussionPaper,No.1282.

Chapin,F.S.,1932.TheexperimentalapproachI.theadvantagesofexperimental

sociologyinthestudyoffamilygrouppatterns.Soc.Forces11,200–207.

Corten,R.,2009.Co-evolutionofSocialNetworksandBehaviorinSocialDilemmas

TheoreticalandEmpiricalPerspectives.ICSDissertationSeries,Utrecht.

Darley,J.M.,Fazio,R.H.,1980.Expectancyconfirmationsequences.Am.Psychol.35,

867–881.

Denrell,J.,LeMens,G.,2011.Seekingpositiveexperiencescanproduceillusory

correlations.Cognition119(3),313–324.

Denrell,J.,2005.Whymostpeopledisapproveofme:experiencesamplingin

impressionformation.Psychol.Rev.112,951–978.

DiMaggio,P.,Garip,F.,2012.Networkeffectsandsocialinequality.Ann.Rev.

Sociol.38,93–118.

Dovidio,J.F.,Kawakami,K.,Gaertner,S.L.,2002.Implicitandexplicitprejudiceand

interracialinteraction.J.Pers.Soc.Psychol.82,62–68.

Elliott,J.R.,1999.Socialisolationandlabormarketinsulation:networkand

neighborhoodeffectsonless-Educatedurbanworkers.Sociol.Quarterly40(2), 199–216.

Elliott,J.R.,2001.Referralhiringandethnicallyhomogeneousjobs:howprevalent

istheconnectionandforwhom?Soc.Sci.Res.30,401–425.

Engström,P.,Hesselius,P.,Holmlund,B.,2012.Vacancyreferrals,jobsearch,and

thedurationofunemployment:arandomizedexperiment.Labour26(4), 419–435.

Falk,A.,Fehr,E.,2003.‘Whylabormarketexperiments?LaborEcon.10,399–406.

Falk,A.,Heckman,J.J.,2009.Labexperimentsareamajorsourceofknowledgein

thesocialsciences.Science326,535–538.

Fehr,E.,Gintis,H.,2007.Humanmotivationandsocialcooperation:experimental

andanalyticalfoundations.Ann.Rev.Sociol.33,43–64.

Fernandez,R.M.,Fernandez-Mateo,I.,2006.Networks,race,andhiring.Am.Sociol.

Rev.71,42–71.

Fernandez,R.M.,Greenberg,J.,2013.Race,networkhiring,andstatistical

discrimination.Res.Sociol.Work24(2013),81–102.

Fernandez,R.M.,Castilla,E.J.,Moore,P.,2000.Socialcapitalatwork:networksand

employmentataphonecenter.Am.J.Sociol.105(5),1288–1356.

Fiedler,K.,Juslin,P.,2006.Takingtheinterfacebetweenmindandenvironment

seriously.In:Fiedler,K.,Juslin,P.(Eds.),InformationSamplingandAdaptive Cognition.Cambridge,UniversityPress.

Fischbacher,U.,2007.Z-Tree:zurichtoolboxforready-madeeconomic

experiments.Exp.Econ.10,171–178.

Fiske,S.T.,2009.SocialBeings:CoreMotivesinSocialPsychology.Wiley,NewYork.

Flache,A.,Mäs,M.,Feliciani,T.,Chattoe-Brown,E.,Deffuant,G.,Huet,S.,Lorenz,J.,

2017.Modelsofsocialinfluence:towardsthenextfrontiers.J.ArtificialSoc.

SocialSimulation20(4),2http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/20/4/2.html.

Fontaine,F.,2008.Whyaresimilarworkerspaiddifferently?theroleofsocial

networks.J.Econ.Dyn.Control32(12),3960–3977.

Fountain,C.,Stovel,K.,2014.Turbulentcareers:socialnetworks,employerhiring

preferences,andjobinstability.In:Manzo,G.(Ed.),AnalyticalSociology.,pp. 339–370.

Gërxhani,K.,Brandts,J.,Schram,A.,2013.Theemergenceofemployerinformation

networksinanexperimentallabormarket.SocialNetworks35,541–560.

Galton,F.,1907.Voxpopuli(Thewisdomofcrowds).Nature75(7),450–451.

Gemkow,S.,Neugart,M.,2011.Referralhiring,endogenoussocialnetworks,and

inequality:anagent-Basedanalysis.J.Evol.Econ.21,703–719.

Gilbert,D.T.,Killingsworth,M.,Eyre,R.N.,Wilson,T.D.,2009.Thesurprisingpower

ofneighborlyadvice.Science323(5921),1617–1619.

Godechot,O.,2016.Thechanceofinfluence:anaturalexperimentontheroleof

socialcapitalinfacultyrecruitment.SocialNetworks46,60–75.

Granovetter,M.,1973.Thestrengthofweakties.Am.J.Sociol.78,1360–1380.

Granovetter,M.,1974.GettingaJob:AStudyofContactsandCareers.Universityof

ChicagoPress,Chicago.

Greiner,B.,2004.Anonlinerecruitmentsystemforeconomicexperiments.In:

Kremer,K.,Macho,V.(Eds.),ForschungUndWissenschaftlichesRechnen2003. Ges.fürWiss.Datenverarbeitung,Göttingen,pp.79–93.

Grogger,J.,Ridgeway,G.,2006.Testingforracialprofilingintrafficstopsfrom

behindaveilofdarkness.J.Am.Stat.Assoc.101(475),878–887.

Hamilton,D.L.(Ed.),1981.Erlbaum,Hillsdale,N.J.

Hoeffer,S.,Ariely,D.,West,P.,2006.Pathdependentpreferences:theroleofearly

experienceandbiasedsearchinpreferencedevelopment.Organ.Behav.Hum. Decis.Process.101,215–229.

Hofstra,B.,Corten,R.,Buskens,V.,2015.Learninginsocialnetworks:selecting

profitablechoicesamongalternativesofuncertainprofitabilityinvarious networks.SocialNetworks43,100–112.

Ioannides,Y.M.,Loury,L.D.,2004.Jobinformationnetworks,neighborhoodeffects,

andinequality.J.Econ.Lit.42,1056–1093.

Jackson,M.,2009.Disadvantagedthroughdiscrimination?theroleofemployersin

socialstratification.Br.J.Sociol.60(4),669–692.

Kaufman,R.L.,2002.Assessingalternativeperspectivesonraceandsex

employmentsegregation.Am.Sociol.Rev.67(4),547–572.

Kaufmann,M.C.,Krings,F.,Sczesny,S.,2015.Lookingtooold?howanolderage

appearancereduceschancesofbeinghired.Br.J.Manage.27(4),727–739.

Keser,C.,Ehrhart,K.M.,Berninghaus,S.K.,1998.Coordinationandlocalinteraction:

experimentalevidence.Econ.Lett.58,269–275.

Keuschnigg,M.,Wolbring,T.,2015.Theuseoffieldexperimentstostudy

mechanismsofdiscrimination.Anal.Kritik38(1),179–202.

Kosfeld,M.,2004.Economicnetworksinthelaboratory:asurvey.Rev.Network

Econ.3(1).

Krauth,B.V.,2004.Adynamicmodelofjobnetworkingandsocialinfluenceson

employment.J.Econ.Dyn.Control28(6),1185–1204.

Kugler,A.D.,2003.Employeereferralsandefficiencywages.LabourEcon.10(5),

531–556.

Lane,T.,2016.Discriminationinthelaboratory:ameta-Analysisofeconomics

experiments.Eur.Econ.Rev.90,375–402.

LeMens,G.,Denrell,J.,2011.Rationallearningandinformationsampling:onthe

‘Naivety’assumptioninsamplingexplanationsofjudgmentbiases.Psychol. Rev.118(2),379–392.

Lee,S.,Pitesa,M.,Pillutla,M.,Thau,S.,2015.Whenbeautyhelpsandwhenithurts:

anorganizationalcontextmodelofattractivenessdiscriminationinselection decisions.Organ.Behav.Hum.Decis.Process.128(May),15–28.

Lin,N.,Ensel,W.M.,Vaughn,J.C.,1981.Socialresourcesandstrengthofties:

structuralfactorsinoccupationalstatusattainment.Am.Sociol.Rev.46, 393–405.

Lorenz,J.,Rauhut,H.,Schweitzer,F.,Helbing,D.,2011.Howsocialinfluencecan

underminethewisdomofcrowdeffect.Proc.Natl.Acad.Sci.108(22), 9020–9025.

Marsden,P.V.,Friedkin,N.E.,1993.Networkstudiesofsocialinfluence.Sociol.

(12)

Mason,W.,Watts,D.J.,2012.Collaborativelearninginnetworks.Proc.Natl.Acad. Sci.109(3),764–769.

McBrier,D.B.,2003.Genderandcareerdynamicswithinasegmentedprofessional

labormarket:thecaseoflawacademia.Soc.Forces81(4),120–1266.

McCall,J.J.,1970.Economicsofinformationandjobsearch.Q.J.Econ.84(1),

113–126.

McDonald,S.,2011.What’sintheoldboysnetwork?Accessingsocialcapitalin

genderedandracializednetworks.SocialNetworks33(4),317–330.

McPherson,M.,Smith-Lovin,L.,Cook,J.M.,2001.Birdsofafeather:homophilyin

socialnetworks.Ann.Rev.Sociol.27,415–444.

Midtbøen,A.H.,2014.Thecontextofemploymentdiscrimination:interpretingthe

findingsofafieldexperiment.Br.J.Sociol.,193–214,http://dx.doi.org/10.

1111/1468-4446.12098.

Model,S.,1993.Theethnicnicheandthestructureofopportunity:Immigrantsand

minoritiesinNewYorkCity.In:Katz,M.(Ed.),TheUnderclassDebate:Views fromHistory.PrincetonUniversityPress,Princeton,pp.161–193.

Montgomery,J.,1991.Socialnetworksandlabor-marketoutcomes:towardan

economicanalysis.Am.Econ.Rev.81,1408–1418.

Montgomery,J.,1992.Jobsearchandnetworkcomposition:implicationsofthe

strengthofweaktieshypothesis.Am.Sociol.Rev.57,586–596.

Mortensen,D.,1986.Jobsearchandlabormarketanalysis.In:Ashenfelter,O.,Card,

D.(Eds.),TheHandbookofLaborEconomics2.(Amsterdam:North-Holland).

Mouw,T.,2002.Racialdifferencesintheeffectsofjobcontacts:conflicting

evidencefromcross-sectionalandlongitudinaldata.Soc.Sci.Res.31(4), 511–538.

Olian,J.D.,Schwab,D.P.,Haberfeld,Y.,1988.Theimpactofapplicantgender

comparedtoqualificationsonhiringrecommendations:ameta-analysisof experimentalstudies.Organ.Behav.Hum.Decis.Process.41(2),180–195.

Ostrom,E.,2010.Revisingtheoryinlightofexperimentalfindings.J.Econ.Behav.

Organ.73(1),68–72.

Pager,D.,Bruce,W.,Bonikowski,B.,2009.Discriminationinalow-Wagelabor

market:afieldexperiment.Am.Sociol.Rev.74,777–799.

Petersen,T.,Saporta,I.,2004.Theopportunitystructurefordiscrimination.Am.J.

Sociol.109,852–901.

Petersen,T.,Saporta,I.,Seidel,M.-D.L.,2000.Offeringajob:meritocracyandsocial

networks.Am.J.Sociol.106,763–816.

Polman,E.,2010.Whyaremaximizerslesshappythansatisficers?becausethey

maximizepositiveandnegativeoutcomes.J.Behav.Decis.Making23,179–190.

Ponzo,M.,Scoppa,V.,2010.TheuseofinformalnetworksinItaly:efficiencyor

favoritism?J.Socio-Econ.39(1),89–99.

Rogers,J.K.,2000.Temps:TheManyFacesoftheChangingWorkplace.ILRPress.

Rooth,D.O.,2010.‘Automaticassociationsanddiscriminationinhiring:realworld

evidence.LabourEcon.17(3),523–534.

Rosenbaum,J.E.,Kariya,T.,Settersten,R.,Maier,T.,1990.Marketandnetwork

theoriesofthetransitionfromhighschooltowork:theirapplicationto industrializedsocieties.Ann.Rev.Sociol.16,263–299.

Roth,A.E.,1993.Theearlyhistoryofexperimentaleconomics.J.Hist.Econ.

Thought15,184–209.

Rubineau,B.,Fernandez,R.M.,2013.Missinglinks:referrerbehaviorandjob

segregation.Manage.Sci.59(11),2470–2489.

Rubineau,B.,Fernandez,R.M.,2015.Howdolabormarketnetworkswork?In:

RobertScott,A.,StephenKosslyn,M.(Eds.),EmergingTrendsintheSocialand

BehavioralSciences:AnInterdisciplinary,Searchable,andLinkableResource.,

pp.1–15,http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/9781118900772.etrds0168.

Simon,H.,1955.Abehavioralmodelofrationalchoice.Q.J.Econ.69,99–118.

Simon,H.,1956.Rationalchoiceandthestructureoftheenvironment.Psychol.

Rev.63(2),129.

Smith,V.L.,1991.PapersinExperimentalEconomics.CambridgeUniversityPress.

Smith,V.L.,2010.Theoryandexperiment:whatarethequestions?J.Econ.Behav.

Organ.73(1),3–15.

Solnick,S.J.,Schweitzer,M.E.,1999.Theinfluenceofphysicalattractivenessand

genderonultimatumgamedecisions.Organ.Behav.Hum.Decis.Process.79 (3),199–215.

Sommerfeld,R.D.,Krambeck,H.-J.,Semman,D.,Milinski,M.,2007.Gossipasan

alternativefordirectobservationingamesofindirectreciprocity.Proc.Natl. Acad.Sci.104,17435–17440.

Spoonley,P.,2008.Utilisingademand-ledapproachinalocallabormarket.Local

Econ.:J.LocalEcon.PolicyUnit23(1),19–30.

Stigler,G.J.,1961.Theeconomicsofinformation.J.PoliticalEcon.69(3),213–225.

Stigler,G.J.,1962.Informationinthelabormarket.J.PoliticalEcon.70(5),94–105.

Stovel,K.,Fountain,C.,2009.Matching.In:Hedström,P.,Bearman,P.(Eds.),The

OxfordHandbookofAnalyticalSociology.OxfordUniversityPress.

Surowiecki,J.,2005.TheWisdomofCrowds.Anchor.

Takács,K.,Squazzoni,F.,2015.Highstandardsenhanceinequalityinidealized

labormarkets.J.Artif.Soc.SocialSimul.18(4),2http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/

18/4/2.html.

Takács,K.,Squazzoni,F.,Bravo,G.,Castellani,M.,2015.Employernetworks,

priming,anddiscriminationinhiring:anexperiment.In:Manzo,G.(Ed.), AnalyticalSociology.WileyandSons,Chichester.

Takács,K.,Flache,A.,Mäs,M.,2016.Discrepancyanddislikingdonotinduce

negativeopinionshifts.PLoSOne11(6),e0157948.

Tassier,T.,Menczer,F.,2008.Socialnetworkstructure,segregation,andequalityin

alabormarketwithreferralhiring.J.Econ.Behav.Organ.66,514–528.

Tian,F.F.,Liu,H.,2018.Gendereddoubleembeddedness:findingjobsthrough

networksinthechineselabormarket.SocialNetworks52,28–36.

Tilly,C.,1998.DurableInequality.UniversityofCaliforniaPress,Berkeley.

Uhlmann,E.L.,Cohen,G.L.,2007.Ithinkit,thereforeit’strue:effectsof

self-Perceivedobjectivityonhiringdiscrimination.Organ.Behav.Hum.Decis. Process.104(2),207–223.

Ule,A.,2008.Partnerchoiceandcooperationinnetworks.theoryand

experimentalevidence.LectureNotesinEconomicsandMathematical Systems,vol.598.Springer.

Uzzi,B.,1996.Thesourcesandconsequencesofembeddednessfortheeconomic

performanceoforganizations:thenetworkeffect.Am.Sociol.Rev.61(4), 674–698.

Webster,M.,Sell,J.,2007.LaboratoryExperimentsintheSocialSciences.Academic

Press.

Wegener,B.,1991.Jobmobilityandsocialties:socialresources,priorjob,and

statusattainment.Am.Sociol.Rev.56,60–71.

Willer,D.,Walker,H.,2007.BuildingExperiments:TestingSocialTheory.Stanford

UniversityPress,Stanford.

Wilson,W.J.,1987.TheTrulyDisadvantaged.UniversityofChicagoPress,Chicago,

IL.

Zschirnt,E.,Ruedin,D.,2016.Ethnicdiscriminationinhiringdecisions:a

meta-analysisofcorrespondencetests.J.EthnicMigrationStud.42(7), 1115–1134.

Figura

Table 1 Treatment overview. Treatment High standards Informationflow Worker referrals Pure effects −S −E −W
Fig. 2. Social influence on discrimination in the information flow (+E) treatment.

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

Airway remodeling has been studied systematically only in severe equine asthma, while one recent study reported remodeling of the central airways in horses with mild to

Et por esto seyendo en la ciudat de Burgos el Rey en la coronacion et en sus caballerias, sopo por cierto que Joan Martinez de Leyva traía fabla con Don Joan Nuñez para se

Using a 384-SNP custom-design GoldenGate assay, under strict criteria for genotype intensity (R.0.1) and concordance between sample replicates (r 2 .0.95), 84% (306) of

In particular, the first step of the Exohab1 project is presented here, achieved with the testing of a mission simulation performed with the ExoLab module - appositely developed as

In this paper, after a preliminary presentation of the results obtained by a new criterion for predicting the non-propagation of cracks under rolling contact fatigue conditions, a

We recouped GR binding sites, epigenetic features and gene expression data using topologically associated domains (see below).. This did not reveal convincing instances of repressed

L’approccio metodologico alla topografia antica, di matrice chiaramen- te umanistica, colloca Pomponio Leto all’interno di quel filone di studi anti- quari della prima

In line with detrimental effects produced by NMDAR overstimulation, persistent elevation of D -aspartate levels in Ddo ⫺/⫺ brains is associated with appearance of dystrophic