• Non ci sono risultati.

Some Business Cycle Consequences of Trade Agreements: Th e Case of the North American Free Trade Agreement

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "Some Business Cycle Consequences of Trade Agreements: Th e Case of the North American Free Trade Agreement"

Copied!
27
0
0

Testo completo

(1)EUI Working Papers RSCAS 2007/03. Some Business Cycle Consequences of Trade Agreements: The Case of the North American Free Trade Agreement. Maria Bejan.

(2) EUROPEAN UNIVERSITY INSTITUTE, FLORENCE ROBERT SCHUMAN CENTRE FOR ADVANCED STUDIES. Some Business Cycle Consequences of Trade Agreements: The Case of the North American Free Trade Agreement MARIA BEJAN. EUI Working Paper RSCAS 2007/03.

(3) This text may be downloaded only for personal research purposes. Additional reproduction for other purposes, whether in hard copies or electronically, requires the consent of the author(s), editor(s). Requests should be addressed directly to the author(s). If cited or quoted, reference should be made to the full name of the author(s), editor(s), the title, the working paper, or other series, the year and the publisher. The author(s)/editor(s) should inform the Robert Schuman Centre for Advanced Studies at the EUI if the paper will be published elsewhere and also take responsibility for any consequential obligation(s).. ISSN 1028-3625. © 2007 Maria Bejan European University Institute Badia Fiesolana I – 50014 San Domenico di Fiesole (FI) Italy http://www.eui.eu/RSCAS/Publications/ http://cadmus.eui.eu.

(4) Robert Schuman Centre for Advanced Studies The Robert Schuman Centre for Advanced Studies (RSCAS), directed by Stefano Bartolini since September 2006, is home to a large post-doctoral programme. Created in 1992, it aims to develop inter-disciplinary and comparative research and to promote work on the major issues facing the process of integration and European society. The Centre hosts major research programmes and projects, and a range of working groups and ad hoc initiatives. The research agenda is organised around a set of core themes and is continuously evolving, reflecting the changing agenda of European integration and the expanding membership of the European Union. Details of this and the other research of the Centre can be found on: http://www.eui.eu/RSCAS/Research/ Research publications take the form of Working Papers, Policy Papers, Distinguished Lectures and books. Most of these are also available on the RSCAS website: http://www.eui.eu/RSCAS/Publications/ The EUI and the RSCAS are not responsible for the opinion expressed by the author(s)..

(5)

(6) Abstract This paper investigates the effects of signing a trade agreement on the correlations of the business cycle fluctuations of consumption, investment and output between two countries. We construct an international business cycle model with trade costs and we calibrate it to the United States and Mexico in order to estimate the impact of NAFTA on their co-movements. Although there exist some discrepancies between the theory and data in the degree of correlation, the direction of change corresponds to the one in the data.. Keywords International Business Cycles, Trade Agreements, International Co-movements. JEL Classifications: E32,F15.

(7) Maria Bejan ITAM (InstitutoTecnologicoAutonomodeMexico) Av. Caminoa Santa Teresa #930, Col. Héroes de Padierna C.P. 10700 Del. Magdalena Contreras México, D.F. email: mbejan@itam.mx tel:(+52)(55)5628-4000 ext.6531. Acknowledgments I would like to thank Timothy Kehoe for many discussions and suggestions. I am grateful to Klaus Desmet for advising and encouraging me. I also wish to thank Camelia Bejan, Michele Boldrin, Beatriz de Blas, Giancarlo Corsetti, Omar Licandro, Marco Maffezzoli, Felipe Meza, Salvador Ortigueira, Morten Ravn as well as the participants at the Luncheon Seminar at the Robert Schuman Center. All remaining errors are mine. I wish to thank the Economics Departments at Bocconi University, Robert Schuman Center for Advanced Studies and University of Minnesota for their hospitality while part of this research was conducted. Financial support from the Jean Monnet Fellowship Program is gratefully acknowledged..

(8) 1. Introduction. Globalization and trade agreements are very contemporary subjects and a reality affecting many economic variables. The purpose of this paper is to study the effects of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) from the business cycles point of view. More explicitly, we analyze the empirical evidence for the US-Mexico comovements before and after signing NAFTA then we test the ability of the international business cycles model to fit the data. One could believe that countries with stronger international trade linkages tend to have higher correlated business cycles in consumption but less correlated cycles in investment. The argument behind this statement is that trade integration (or signing a trade agreement) decreases trade costs, facilitating the trade in goods and thus making the consumption paths of the countries involved more correlated . On the other hand a reduction in trade barriers also means that the investment from one country could flow to the other, thus decreasing the correlation. In terms of output the intuition can lead us to two different rational scenarios. Standard trade theory tells us that increased trade leads to more specialization. On one hand, if the specialization induces more inter-industry trade and the shocks driving the business cycles are sector-specific than there is no reason to think that trade intensification would lead to higher comovements in output. On the other hand, if what is intensified is the intra-industry trade, we can expect an increase in the comovement of outputs of the countries involved, induced by the "back-and-forth" trade. However, this intuition is not supported either by the empirical or theoretical literature. Until now only the relationship between trade barriers and output comovements received direct attention in both empirical and theoretical studies. Frankel and Rose (1998) and Imbs (2004), among others, show that stronger trade linkages are associated with higher correlations of outputs in the data. Kose and Yi (2001, 2006) examine whether these patterns can be explained by the standard international business cycle model. With the calibration they chose (for US, Germany and Japan), the model failed to fit the data. There is a large branch of literature that studies the economic impact of NAFTA. This literature analyses the impact of the trade agreement on the volume of trade between the countries involved. Krueger (1999) presents empirical evidence that in the case of NAFTA, trade creation was bigger than trade diversion. From a theoretical point of view, this analysis of the implication of NAFTA on the volume of trade is usually done using static applied general equilibrium models based on increasing returns and imperfect competition (see Kehoe (2003) for a survey). However, the static nature of these models makes them unfit for our purpose. To understand the effects of NAFTA on the countries’ business cycles, one needs to analyze the behavior of macroeconomic aggregates. As Kehoe and Kehoe (1994) emphasized in their paper, accounting for changes in productivities is vital for capturing changes in the macroeconomic aggregates. We therefore use a business cycle model with productivity shocks to analyze the comovements in the main economic aggregates: consumption, investment and output. Our analysis is thus related to the international business cycle literature. The focus of this literature is on two major discrepancies between the data and the predictions of the international business cycle models. The international business cycle models with complete markets predict negative cross-country correlations of investment (while in the data these correlations are positive) and cross-country correlations for consumption much higher than for output (while in the data the opposite is. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan.

(9) Maria Bejan. true).1 Many economists tried to solve these so called “puzzles”, by introducing various frictions in the international business cycle models. Among the frictions considered, the most frequent are the transportation costs2 and incomplete financial markets.3 The expected consequences of these frictions are a reduction in the correlations of consumption and an increase in the correlations of output and investment. Several papers show that these frictions are able to reduce the existing anomalies, and even completely eliminate them.4 Nevertheless these papers focus on the US-Canada or US-Europe aggregate data and therefore their models are calibrated for these particular situations. The focus of the present paper is on the US and Mexico and the effects of NAFTA on these countries’ consumption, investment and output comovements. A stylized, simplified way of incorporating trade agreements into theoretical economic models is in the form of changes in trade costs between countries.5 Therefore we introduce a trade cost in intermediate goods in the standard international business cycle model (a la Backus, Kehoe, Kydland (1995)) and simulate the signing of NAFTA by a reduction in this cost. We show that a decrease in the trade cost is able to reproduce the direction of changes in comovements but not the size. The paper is organized as follows: we start by presenting the empirical evidence in section 2, then set up the model in section 3. Section 4 describes the calibration of the model and section 5 presents the results. Finally, the last section concludes and presents lines for future research.. 2. Empirical evidence. The objective of this section is to analyze the changes in the correlations of consumption, investment and output for the case of USA and Mexico. Our main focus is on the patterns of the correlations around the year 1994 when the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) came into force. Although NAFTA was signed by USA, Mexico and Canada, we present here only the empirical evidence for the case of USA and Mexico while the evidence regarding the other two pairs of countries (USA-Canada, Canada-Mexico) is presented in Appendix 2. We made this choice for two reasons. First since USA and Canada have had intense trade-relationship even before 1994 (for example, the Canadian Free Trade Agreement signed between Canada and USA came into force in 1989) one would not expect any strong impact of NAFTA on their macroeconomic paths. Second, the case of Mexico-Canada is not so interesting because the volume of trade between Canada and Mexico is only 4 percent of existing trade between US and Mexico.6 1. See Backus, Kehoe, Kydland (1992) for details. See Mazzenga and Ravn (2002) 3 See Kose and Yi (2001, 2006), Kehoe and Perri (2002), Heathcote and Perri (2002) 4 See Kehoe and Perri (2002). 5 Since a trade agreement represents more than a reduction in the trade barriers, this paper represents the first step in our intent to see all the efects that trade liberalization can have over the international comovements. 6 The static applied general equilibrium models also conclude that NAFTA is likely to have a strong positive impact on the Mexican economy, only a small impact on the US economy and almost no impact on the Canadian economy. See Kehoe and Kehoe (1994) for more details. 2. 2. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan.

(10) Some Business Cycle Consequences of Trade Agreements: The Case of the North American Free Trade Agreement. Table 1 displays the evolution of the cross-country correlations of consumption, investment and output. To compare correlations before and after signing NAFTA, we compute correlations over equal periods of time, before and after 1994.7 TABLE 1. Mexico – USA: Empirical evidence Corr / NAFTA. Before. After. corr (c1, c2). -0.28. 0.32. corr (i1, i2). -0.40. 0.58. corr (y1, y2). -0.19. 0.56. Source: OECD Quarterly National Accounts Note: c = consumption, i = investment, y = output. All the variables are Hodrick-Prescott-filtered with a smoothing parameter of 1600. The periods “before” and “after” corresponds to the following quarters: “before”: 1985:1 – 1993:4, “after”: 1994:1 – 2002:4. Comparing the correlations for USA and Mexico before and after 1994 we observe a clear increasing tendency in all the three macroeconomic variables considered. However, this evidence is not enough to conclude that there is any possible impact of NAFTA. The table above only shows that the correlations after 1994 are higher than before. This might be just the natural consequence of a constant increase in the correlations. To eliminate this possibility we analyze the evolution of the comovements in time by considering correlations over a “flying” 5-year window. Figure 1 illustrates the correlations in time for consumption, investment and output. The smoothed lines represent the trends of the comovements while the more volatile line, the fluctuations around this trend.8 The figure shows, for all the variables, a clear change in the tendency in 1992, the year when the Figure 1. Correlations Mexico – USA. correlation. consumption. investment. output. 0.6. 1.2. 0.8. 0.4. 0.8. 0.6. 0.2. 0.4. 0.0. 0.0. -0.2. -0.4. 0.4 0.2 0.0 -0.2 -0.4. -0.8. -0.4 86. 88. 90. 92. CORR. 94. 96. 98. 00. 02. CORR_TREND. 86. 88. 90. 92. USA_MEX. 94. 96. 98. 00. 02. HP_USAMEX. 84. 86. 88. 90. 92. 94. 96. CORR_5_USA_MEX. 98. 00. 02. TREND. time Note: Correlations are computed over a 5-year moving window. Smooth line represents the HP trend.. Appendix 3 presents data on trade and comparative statistics. 7 See Appendix 1 for a more detailed description of data. 8 We applied Hodrick-Prescott filter to abtain the trend and the fluctuations.. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan. 3.

(11) Maria Bejan. We interpret these results as an evidence of NAFTA’s impact on the comovements between USA and Mexico. The rest of the paper investigates the ability of the standard international business cycle model to generate these results. The following section describes in detail the model we use.. 3. The International Business Cycle Model. We consider a standard neoclassical growth model “a la” Backus, Kehoe, Kydland (1995) (BKK henceforth). The economy consists of two countries that produce different, imperfectly substitutable intermediate goods which can be traded between countries. After the trade, each country uses as final good a combination of the domestic and imported goods. The difference from the BKK model consists in the “iceberg” trade cost τ we introduce in this model. The rough way in which we simulate a trade agreement in this economy is through reducing τ . Two new features are studied here. First, we investigate how the correlations in consumption, investment and output evolved in time after the reduction in trade cost. Second, due to the specifics of the case we want to study, USA-Mexico, Backus et all.(1995) or Mazzenga and Ravn (2002) ’s assumption that the equilibrium is symmetric cannot be applied. This complicates the way the model is solved and the calibration we make in order to simulate the results. In the following subsections we will present in more detail the model. Preferences Each country, i, is represented by a continuum of identical, infinitely lived agents having the preferences characterized by the following expected utility function ∞ X ui = E0 β ti Ui (cit , 1 − nit ) , i = 1, 2,. (1). t=0. where cit and nit represents per capita consumption and time devoted to labor in country µ i and β is the intertemporal discount factor. The utility function is Ui (ci , 1 − ni ) = [ci i (1 − ni )1−µi ]1−γ i /(1−γ i ), where µi represents the consumption share and γ i the coefficient of relative risk aversion. The endowment of time is normalized to 1 in each period t. Therefore (1 − nit ) represents time devoted to leisure, per capita, in country i. We denote by Ψ the relative mass of population of country 1. Technologies Intermediate goods Each country specializes in the production of a single intermediate good, labeled a for country 1 and b for country 2. Production of these goods takes place in each country using as inputs domestic capital, k, and domestic labor, n (both internationally immobile) and it is affected by the technology shocks, z. Some of the intermediate goods are used domestically for the production of final goods while the rest is exported. This gives rise to the resource constraints:. 4. a1t + a2t = y1t = z1t F (k1t , n1t ). (2). b1t + b2t = y2t = z2t F (k2t , n2t ). (3). EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan.

(12) Some Business Cycle Consequences of Trade Agreements: The Case of the North American Free Trade Agreement. i in country 1 and 2 respectively, where F (ki , ni ) = kiθi n1−θ and zit represents the productivity i shock specific to country i. The productivity shocks follow the process zit+1 = Ai zit +εit+1 , where corr(Ai , Aj ) 6= 0 and the innovations ε1t+1 and ε2t+1 are correlated. The variable yit represents output per capita in country i and a2t , b1t represent the quantities exported to country 2 (good a), respectively to country 1 (good b), also per capita.. Final goods Consumption and investment in each country are composites of the foreign and domestic intermediate goods: c1t + x1t = G(a1t , b01t ). (4). G(b2t , a02t ). (5). c2t + x2t =. 1. where G(a, b) is the Armington aggregator: G(a, b) = [ω 1 a1−α + ω 2 b1−α ] 1−α 9 and b01t , a02t represents the quantities imported by country 1 and 2 respectively. Parameters α, ω 1 , ω 2 are positive, σ = α1 represents the elasticity of substitution between goods a and b and ω 1 , ω 2 represent the home, and, respectively, foreign bias in the composition of domestically produced final goods. The law of motion for the capital stock is given by kjt+1 = (1 − δ j )kjt + xjt. (6). where δ j ∈ (0, 1) is the depreciation rate and xjt represents the amount of final good devoted to investment in country j. Trade cost As we said at the beginning, we introduce a trade cost, τ ∈ [0, 1] in this economy. This cost affects international trade in intermediate goods in the following way: if a quantity q is exported, only a fraction (1 − τ ) of q reaches the destination. Therefore the feasibility conditions for the final goods could be rewritten as: c1t + x1t = G(a1t , (1 − τ )b1t ) c2t + x2t = G(b2t , (1 − τ )a2t ). 3.1. (7) (8). Equilibrium. Defining a competitive equilibrium for this economy with complete contingent claims markets is straightforward but notationally burdensome. We prefer to determine the equilibrium allocations by exploiting their welfare properties. Each country is populated by identical consumers who will choose identical consumption and investment plans in the equilibrium. In the equilibrium consumers use contingent claims to diversify country-specific risk across states of nature. By doing so, consumers end up equating the marginal utility of consumption across countries for each 9. This is like having the preferences defined over goods a and b. But for computational simplicity we call goods a and b ”intermediate goods” and the aggregation of both (i.e. G(a, b)) we call it the final good.. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan. 5.

(13) Maria Bejan. state of nature thus, each equilibrium allocation is Pareto optimal. Therefore the equilibrium in this model is that Pareto optimal allocation in which the consumers from the same country choose the same allocations. For this reason we can consider a representative consumer for each one of the economies. Moreover, if we consider the continuum of agents in country 1 having the relative mass Ψ (relative to the total of consumers in the economy), the relative mass of country 2 will be 1 − Ψ.10 The equilibrium allocation under complete markets specification is thus fully characterized in the following proposition. ∗ , k ∗ , n∗ , n∗ ) is an equilibProposition 1: The allocation (a∗1t , a∗2t , b∗1t , b∗2t , c∗1t , c∗2t , x∗1t , x∗2t , k1t 2t 1t 2t rium allocation of the economy, given the transportation cost τ , if it solves the following problem:. max Ψu(c1t , 1 − n1t ) + (1 − Ψ)u(c2t , 1 − n2t ) subject to. (9). c1t + x1t = G(a1t , (1 − τ )b1t ) c2t + x2t = G(b2t , (1 − τ )a2t ). Ψa1t + (1 − Ψ)a2t = Ψz1t F (k1t , n1t ). Ψb1t + (1 − Ψ)b2t = (1 − Ψ)z2t F (k2t , n2t ) k1t+1 = (1 − δ 1 )k1t + x1t k2t+1 = (1 − δ 2 )k2t + x2t. In order to figure out the decision rules in equilibrium, we solve for the deterministic steady state of the model and approximate the dynamics of the model in response to exogenous productivity shocks. We do so by linearizing the first order conditions around the steady state, as described in King, Plosser, Rebelo (1988).. 4. Calibration. The complete list of parameters we have to calibrate is the following: the intertemporal discount factor β i , the consumption share in the utility function µi , the degree of risk aversion γ i , the technology coefficient θi , the depreciation rate δ i , the home and foreign bias in final good production ω i1 and ω i2 , the elasticity of substitution between intermediate goods αi , the persistence matrix for technology shocks A and the variance-covariance matrix of shocks V . Some of these parameters can be estimated from the available data, others we borrow from other papers. We will start with the last ones: the value for the relative risk aversion coefficient is taken from BKK: γ 1 = γ 2 = γ = 2. In the next section we run a sensitivity analysis to see 10 Taking into account that we want to calibrate this model for the case of USA and Mexico, we cannot impose the symmetry. Thus Ψ 6= 0.5. 6. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan.

(14) Some Business Cycle Consequences of Trade Agreements: The Case of the North American Free Trade Agreement. if this value match the best our predictions with the empirical evidence we have. Also we take the discount factor to be 0.99 in both countries (the value normally used in the literature. See BKK(1995), Kehoe, Perri(2002)) To estimate the rest of the parameters in the model we use data from OECD (Quarterly National Accounts) for the period 1980:1-2002:4. First we estimate the time devoted to work (n) in steady state: using the first moment approximation we obtain a share of 0.34 in USA and 0.36 in Mexico. Also from Kaldor’ stylized facts we know that ky is roughly constant. Our estimation is: ( ky )U SA = 13.28, ( ky )MEX = 11.13. The estimates for consumption shares of output are ( yc )USA = 0.66,( yc )MEX = 0.68.11 To approximate the labor share we use the following formula (as in Gollin (2002)):. labor_share =. employees_compensation nr_employees. · work_f orce. GDP With this approximation we obtain an average labor share of 0.64. Therefore θ1 = θ2 = θ = 0.36. Having these estimates and the first order conditions from above we can determine the depreciation rates:. δ=. 1−. c y. k y. ⇒ δ USA = 0.025; δ MEX = 0.028.. Also using first order conditions we can estimate the consumption share in the household’s utility, µ :. µ=. 1 1+. 1−θ 1−n k 1 θ c n(β. − 1 + δ). ⇒ µU SA = 0.34; µMEX = 0.38.. We calibrate the relative mass of the countries (Ψ) such that the commercial deficit USAMexico computed from the model to fit the data. In this way,Ψ = ΨU SA = 0.61, 1 − Ψ = ΨMEX = 0.39. Table 2 summarizes the values of the parameters used in our experiments. 11 For the US we use the estimated ratios capital-to-output, consumption-to-output from Neumeyer and Perri (2005). For Mexico, we estimate the ratios using capital, consumption and GDP series from Heathcote and Perri (2004).. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan. 7.

(15) Maria Bejan. TABLE 2. Parameter Values. Type. Name. Symbol y value. β = 0.99. Discount Factor* Preferences. Technology. Curvature parameter *. µUSA = 0.34  µ MEX = 0.38 γ =2. Capital share. θ = 0.36. Depreciation rate. δ USA = 0.025  δ MEX = 0.028. Consumption share. * Imported from BKK. We also consider the steady state share of imports to outputs as being constant, and we estimate it from the available data, before and after signing NAFTA: sU SA (bef ore) = 0.10, sMEX (bef ore) = 0.15, sU SA (after) = 0.13, sMEX (after) = 0.29. Using these ratios and the above values we can calibrate the foreign bias from Armington aggregator and the elasticity of substitution between intermediate goods. We obtain them as functions of τ :12 elasticity of substitution from Armington aggregator α (. 1 α1 1 − q1a ( 1−s = q1b ( qsa1 )α1 (1 − τ )α1 −1 q1a ) 1 a ( s2 )α2 (1 − τ )α2 −1 2 α2 1 − q2b ( 1−s ) = q b 2 q qb 2. 2. weights from Armington aggregator ω ij 13      ω =   11.       ω21 =. a (1−τ ) 1−α q1 ) α ]−α b q1 q a (1−τ ) 1−α 1+[( s1 −1)∗( 1 b ) α ]−α q1 1 q b (1−τ ) 1−α [( s1 −1)∗( 2 qa ) α ]−α 2 2 q b (1−τ ) 1−α 1+[( s1 −1)∗( 2 qa ) α ]−α 2 2. [( s1 −1)∗( 1. It is interesting to observe here how the elasticity of substitution and the weights each country puts on its domestically produced good change with the intensity of the trade barriers (τ ). Higher trade barriers are associated with lower import shares, higher elasticities of substitution and lower weights the imports receive in the final good production. We can interpret this as a link between trade intensity and specialization: lower trade barriers generate more intensive trade and in the same time induce a decrease in the elasticity of substitution. The intermediate 12 13. 8. For a more detailed example of calibation for the Armington aggregator coefficients see Appendix 4. 1 Gi (a, b) = [ω i1 a1−α + ωi2 b1−α ] 1−α .. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan.

(16) Some Business Cycle Consequences of Trade Agreements: The Case of the North American Free Trade Agreement. goods of the two countries become “more” complements and this makes each country specialize in one good.14 The last parameters we need to estimate are related to the productivity shocks processes. First we compute the total factor productivity in each one of the countries using Solow residuals: ln T F P = ln(y) − capital_share · ln(k) − labor_share · ln(L), where we use the GDP for output, the stock of capital we constructed using series of investment and we use the total number of hours worked as a measure of labor. The last step is to effectively estimate the productivity shock process:. where. µ. ε1t ε2t. ¶. µ. z1t+1 z2t+1. ¶. =. µ. A11 A12 A21 A22. ¶ µ ¶ µ ¶ z1t ε1t+1 ∗ + , z2t ε2t+1. ˜N (0, Σ).. Estimates for elements of A and Σ are presented in Table 3. Numbers in parentheses represent standard errors. TABLE 3. Productivity shock. Productivity transition matrix. Std. dev. of innovations to productivity Correlation between innovations to productivity.  0.951 − 0.011 ( 0.006 )  A =  ( 0.023) 0.939  0( 0.045 .020 ) ( 0.025)  σ ε 1 = 0.0089  σ ε 2 = 0.0976 corr (ε 1 , ε 2 ) = 0.276. We have now all the ingredients needed to compute the steady state, to log-linearize the system around this steady state and then to apply the King Plosser Rebelo (1987) procedure.. 5. Results. This section reports the average results across 1000 stochastic simulations. One period in the model corresponds to one quarter in the data. Therefore, for the case of USA-Mexico we simulate the economy over 72 periods. In Table 4 we present the result of these simulations and compare them with what we observed in data. 14. This is the missing link between trade and specialization in Kose and Yi(2001).. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan. 9.

(17) Maria Bejan. In the first exercise we made, whose results we present in Table 4, we consider a decrease in trade costs from 45% to 15%. Table 5 shows what happens with the predictions for a bigger fall in the trade costs. Comparing our results to the data we can see that the model performs well in predicting the correlation in consumption: a jump from -0.18 to 0.27 in the model corresponds to the jump observed in the data, from -0.28 before NAFTA to 0.32 after NAFTA. However, in the data the increase is higher than what our model predicts. In terms of investment, the predicted jump is far smaller than what we found in the empirical study. Moreover, the initial level of correlation is bellow the data. In the case of output correlation, we observe the same smaller jump in the predictions than in the data. However, for all the correlations, the direction of changes coincides with the one found in the data: all the correlations increase. Moreover, Figures 4 shows that the pattern followed by the model predictions has the same U-shape as the data, although the curvature is much softer than in the data. TABLE 4. Benchmark experiment Mexico - USA. Before. After Data. corr (c1, c2). -0.28. 0.32. corr (i1, i2). -0.40. 0.58. corr (y1, y2). -0.19. 0.56 Model. corr (c1, c2). -0.18. 0.27. corr (i1, i2). -0.72. -0.68. corr (y1, y2). 0.21. 0.35. Note: c = consumption, i = investment, y = output. All the variables are Hodrick-Prescott-filtered with a smoothing parameter of 1600. The periods “before” and “after” corresponds to 1985:1 – 1993:4, respectively 1994:1 – 2002:4.. Table 5 presents the results of our simulation for a bigger fall in the trade cost, τ . We consider the extreme case where before the trade agreement there is almost no trade between countries (this corresponds to a trade cost τ = 0.95), then, when the trade agreement is signed, the trade cost becomes very close to 0 (τ = 0.05). On the one hand, the results show that all the correlations are very sensitive to changes in trade cost. On the other, all the predictions after NAFTA are relatively far bellow what we observe in the data. This is an evidence that, although a reduction in the trade costs is an important feature of a trade agreement, it is not a perfect proxy for all the changes a trade agreement means. Table 6 presents a sensitivity analysis with respect to the coefficient of relative risk aversion, γ. Since we do not have any exact estimation of this parameter, it is useful to see if the results change with different values of the parameter and which is the value which fits the best our predictions with the empirical evidence. 10. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan.

(18) Some Business Cycle Consequences of Trade Agreements: The Case of the North American Free Trade Agreement. A first look at this table suggests that the correlations in investment and output follow a clearly decreasing pattern. The dynamics of the consumption correlation is not monotonic. There is an increasing tendency for γ ≤ 1.50 then the pre-NAFTA correlations remain more or less constant, while post-NAFTA correlations decrease. A more detailed analysis of the results15 provides the same results: the best match between the empirical evidence and simulated results is obtained for γ between 1.25 and 2. Figure 4. Correlations Mexico – USA. consumption. investment. 0,45. output. 0,75 0,65. 0,35 0,55. 0,55. correlation. 0,25 0,45. 0,15. 0,35. simulated results. 0,35. 0,05. s i mul a t e d r e s ul t s. 0,25. 0,15 -0,05. 0 , 15. data -0,15. -0,05. -0,25. 0,05 -0,05. simulated results. data. -0,25. - 0 , 15. -0,35 -0,45 1987. 1989. 1991. 1993. 1995. 1997. 1999. -0,45 1987. 2001. da t a. -0,25. 1989. 1991. 1993. 1995. 1997. 1999. 19 8 7. 2001. 19 8 9. 19 9 1. 19 9 3. 19 9 5. 19 9 7. 19 9 9. 2001. time Note: Correlations are computed over a 5-year moving window. TABLE 5. Sensitivity analysis Mexico - USA. Before. After Benchmark experiment. corr (c1, c2). -0.18. 0.27. corr (i1, i2). -0.72. -0.68. corr (y1, y2). 0.21. 0.35 Huge fall in trade cost. corr (c1, c2). -0.93. 0.28. corr (i1, i2). -0.90. -0.65. corr (y1, y2). -0.01. 0.30. Note: c = consumption, i = investment, y = output. All the variables are Hodrick-Prescott-filtered with a smoothing parameter of 1600. The periods “before” and “after” corresponds to 1985:1 – 1993:4, respectively 1994:1 – 2002:4.. 15 use as an accuracy measure for the predictions error(predictioni ) = s We (cpred − creal )2 + (xpred − xreal )2 + (ypred − yreal )2 where c, x, y represents consumption, investment and output respectively.. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan. 11.

(19) Maria Bejan. TABLE 6. γ-Sensitivity analysis correlations. corr (c1, c2). corr (i1, i2). corr (y1, y2). period. before. after. before. after. before. after. γ=0.75. -0.54. -0.25. -0.23. 0.00. 0.31. 0.49. γ=1. -0.44. 0.14. -0.38. -0.20. 0.27. 0.43. γ=1.25. -0.28. 0.38. -0.51. -0.36. 0.25. 0.40. γ=1.5. -0.20. 0.42. -0.60. -0.51. 0.22. 0.37. γ=1.75. -0.19. 0.35. -0.66. -0.59. 0.23. 0.36. γ=2 (Benchmark exp). -0.18. 0.28. -0.72. -0.67. 0.21. 0.34. γ=3. -0.19. -0.01. -0.84. -0.83. 0.20. 0.31. γ=4. -0.18. -0.14. -0.90. -0.88. 0.19. 0.30. Data. -0.28. 0.32. -0.40. 0.58. -0.19. 0.56. Note: c = consumption, i = investment, y = output. All the variables are Hodrick-Prescott-filtered with a smoothing parameter of 1600. The periods “before” and “after” corresponds to 1985:1 – 1993:4, respectively 1994:1 – 2002:4.. 6. Conclusions and future research. The empirical evidence we have shows that the correlations in consumption, investment and output between Mexico and the US increased after 1992, when the preparatives for signing the North American Free Trade Agreement finished. We interpret these results as an evidence of NAFTA’s impact on the US-Mexico comovements. We have shown that the model provides good qualitative results: a reduction in the trade barriers produces an increase in the comovements in all the three macroeconomic variables (consumption, investment and output). On the other hand, the model fail to give the quantitative increase in comovements we observe in the data. This could suggest that a reduction in the trade barriers it is not a perfect proxy for all the changes a trade agreement means.meant One missing link we think could be the financial integration of Mexico. We therefore think it would be interesting for future research to find empirical evidence of Mexico’s financial integration after signing the North American Free Trade Agreement. It is our belief that, enriching the international business cycle model so that to account not only for reduction in the cost of trade but also for the financial liberalization would provide predictions that are closer to the empirical evidence.. 12. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan.

(20) Some Business Cycle Consequences of Trade Agreements: The Case of the North American Free Trade Agreement. 7. Bibliography • AMBER, S., CARDIA, E. et al., C., 2002. ’International Transmission of the Business cycle in a multi-sector model’, European Economic Review, 46, pp. 273-300 • ANDERSON, H.M., KWARK, N. et al. Does International Trade Synchronize Business Cycles?, Monash University Working Paper No.1999/8 • BACKUS, K., KEHOE, P. et al. 1992. ’International Real Business Cycles’, Journal of Political Economy,100 (4), pp.745-775. • BACKUS, K., KEHOE, P.et al. 1995. ’International Business Cycles: Theory vs. Evidence’, in Cooley (ed.), Frontiers of Business Cycles Research: Princeton, pp. 331-356 • BAXTER, M. 1995. ’International Trade and Business Cycles’, in G. Grossman and K. Rogoff (ed), Handbook of International Economics, vol 3 : North-Holland • BAXTER, M., CRUCINI, M.. 1995. ’Business Cycles and the Asset Structure of Foreign Trade’, International Economic Review, 36(4), pp. 821-854 • BLACK, F. , B. 1990. Business Cycles and Equilibrium. New York: Blackwell • BUSSE, M.. 1996. ’NAFTA’s Impact on the European Union’, Aussenwirtschaft 51 (3), pp. 363-382 • CALDERON,C., CHONG,A. et al. Trade Intensity and Business Cycle Synchronization: Are Developing Countries Any Different?, Central Bank of Chile Working Paper No. 2002/195 • CUEVAS, A.; MESSMACHER, M. et al. "Changes in the Patterns of External Financing in Mexico Since the Approval of NAFTA", Banco de Mexico (July, 2002) • FAVERO,C.A. 2001. ’Applied Macroeconometrics’, Oxford University Press • GOLLIN, D. 2002. ’Getting Income Shares Right’, Journal of Political Economy, 110 (2), pp. 458-474. • HEATHCOTE, J., PERRI, F. 2002. ’Financial Autarky and International Business Cycles’, Journal of Monetary Economics 49/3, pp. 601-627 • HEATHCOTE, J., PERRI, F.. 2003. ’Why has the US Economy Become Less Correlated With the Rest of the World?’, American Economic Review, 93 (2), pp. 63-69. • HEATHCOTE, J., PERRI, F., 2004. ’Financial globalization and real regionalization’, Journal of Economic Theory 119(1), pp. 207-243 • JEREMY, D. 1991 International Technology Transfer : Europe, Japan and the USA, 17001914, London: Edward Elgar. • KEHOE,T. An Evaluation of the Performance of Applied General Equilibrium Models of the Impact of NAFTA, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Working Paper No.2003/320.. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan. 13.

(21) Maria Bejan. • KEHOE, P., KEHOE, T., 1994. ’Capturing NAFTA’s Impact with Applied General Equilibrium Models’, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 18(2), pp.17—34 • KEHOE, P., PERRI, F. 2002 ’International Business Cycles with Endogenous Incomplete Markets’, Econometrica, 70(3), pp.907-928. • KOSE, M.A., YI, K-M., 2001 ’International Trade and Business Cycle: Is Vertical Specialization the Missing Link?’, American Economic Review, 91(2), pp.371-375 • KOSE, M.A., YI, K-M., 2006, ’Can the Standard International Business Cycle Model Explain the Relationship between Trade and Comovement?’, Journal of International Economics, 68, pp.267-295 • KRUEGER, A., 1999. Trade Creation and Trade Diversion under NAFTA, NBER Working Paper No. 7429 • KYDLAND, F. , PRESCOTT, E. 1982. ’Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations’, Econometrica, 50(6), pp. 1345-70. • MAZZENGA, E., RAVN, M. International Business Cycles: The Quantitative Role of Transportation Costs, CEPR Working Paper No. 2002/3530 • NEUMEYER, A., PERRI, F., 2005. ’Business cycles in emerging economies: the role of interest rates’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(2), pp.345-380 • SENHADJI, A. 1997. ’Two Common Problems Related to the Use of the Armington Aggregator in Computable General Equilibrium Models’, Applied Economics Letters 4 (1), pp. 23-25. • TORNELL, A., WESTERMANN, F. et al. 2003. ’Liberalization, Growth and Financial Crises: Lessons from Mexico and the Developing World’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity No. 2, pp. 1-112 • ZIMMERNMANN, C. Technology Innovations and the Volatility of Output: An International Perspective, CREFE Working Paper No. 1997/34 • WILLENBOCKEL, D.1999. ’On Apparent Problems with the Use of the Armington Aggregator in Computable General Equilibrium Models’, Applied Economics Letters 6 (9), pp. 589-91.. 14. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan.

(22) Some Business Cycle Consequences of Trade Agreements: The Case of the North American Free Trade Agreement. 8. Appendix 1: Data description. Data used to compute correlations in consumption, investment and output is taken from OECD Quarterly National Account and International Monetary Fund (International Financial Statistics). From OECD, Main Economic Indicators we took quarterly data for weekly hours of work and we use it to calculate a proxy for labor used in production for the case of United States. For Mexico the data I use comes basically from INEGI and it was provided to me by Felipe Meza. Consumption in this model is computed as the sum between private and government consumptions and investment like gross fixed capital formation plus changes in inventories. Then, in order to compute the stock of capital we take the quarterly depreciation rate equal to 2.5%.. 9. Appendix 2: Empirical evidence Figure 1. Correlations Mexico – USA. correlation. consumption. investment. output. 0.6. 1.2. 0.8. 0.4. 0.8. 0.6. 0.2. 0.4. 0.0. 0.0. -0.2. -0.4. 0.4 0.2 0.0 -0.2 -0.4. -0.8. -0.4 86. 88. 90. 92. CORR. 94. 96. 98. 00. 86. 02. 88. 90. 92. 94. USA_MEX. CORR_TREND. 96. 98. 00. 84. 02. 86. 88. 90. 92. 94. 96. CORR_5_USA_MEX. HP_USAMEX. 98. 00. 02. TREND. time Note: Correlations are computed over a 5-year moving window. Smooth line represents the HP trend.. Figure 2. Correlations Canada – Mexico. correlation. consumption. investment. 0.6. 1.2. 0.4. 0.8. 0.2. 0.4. 0.0. 0.0. output 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 -0.2. -0.2. -0.4. -0.4. -0.8. -0.4 86. 88. 90 CORR. 92. 94. 96. 98. 00. CORR_TREND. 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 CAN_MEX. HP_CANMEX. -0.6 84. 86. 88. 90. 92. 94. CORR_5_CAN_MEX. 96. 98. 00. TREND. time Note: Correlations are computed over a 5-year moving window. Smooth line represents the HP trend.. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan. 15.

(23) Maria Bejan. Figure 3. Correlations USA – Canada. consumption. investment. 1.0. 1.2. 0.8. 0.8. output 1.0 0.8. correlation. 0.6. 0.4. 0.4. 0.6. 0.0. 0.2 0.0. 0.4. -0.4. -0.2. 0.2. -0.8. -0.4. -1.2. -0.6 70. 75. 80 CORR. 85. 90. 95. 00. 0.0. 1970. CORR_TREND. 1975. 1980. 1985. CAN_USA. 1990. 1995. 2000. 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 CORR_5_USA_CAN. HP_CANUSA. TREND. time Note: Correlations are computed over a 5-year moving window. Smooth line represents the HP trend. TABLE 1. Empirical evidence Corr / NAFTA. Before. After Mexico – USA. corr (c1, c2). -0.28. 0.32. corr (i1, i2). -0.40. 0.58. corr (y1, y2). -0.19. 0.56 Mexico – Canada. corr (c1, c2). -0.14. 0.43. corr (i1, i2). -0.55. 0.71. corr (y1, y2). -0.38. 0.34 USA – Canada. corr (c1, c2). 0.71. 0.72. corr (i1, i2). 0.38. 0.46. corr (y1, y2). 0.92. 0.47. Source: OECD Quarterly National Accounts Note: c = consumption, i = investment, y = output. All the variables are Hodrick-Prescott-filtered with a smoothing parameter of 1600. The periods “before” and “after” corresponds to the following quarters: México – USA: 1985:1 – 1993:4, 1994:1 – 2002:4 Canada – Mexico: 1987:1 – 1993:4, 1994:1 – 2000:4 USA – Canada: 1987:1 – 1993:4, 1994:1 – 2000:4. 16. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan.

(24) Some Business Cycle Consequences of Trade Agreements: The Case of the North American Free Trade Agreement. 10. Appendix 3: Trade data. This appendix contains comparative trade statistics for the US, Mexico and Canada. The data used is from Krueger (1999). The next graph shows how in 1994 the percentage of trade USA-CAN of the total trade of USA decreased instead of increase.. Trade USA -- CAN (percentage of total trade of USA) 25.05 Exports USA --> CAN Imports USA <-- CAN. 20.05. 15.05. 10.05. 5.05. 0.05 1990. 1991. 1992. 1993. 1994. 1995. 1996. 1997. 1998. The next graphs represent a comparative study in order to highlight the difference between the importance of the US and Canada in Mexico’s trade. The exports/imports of MEX to/from USA and CAN are represented as the percentage of total exports/imports of Mexico.. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan. 17.

(25) Maria Bejan. Mexico: exports (percentage of total exports of MEX) 100.05 90.05 80.05. Exports MEX --> USA. 70.05 60.05 50.05 40.05 30.05 20.05 10.05. Exports MEX --> CAN. 0.05 1991. 1992. 1993. 1994. 1995. 1996. 1997. 1998. Mexico: imports (pecentage of total imports of MEX) 90.05 80.05 70.05 60.05 Imports MEX <-- USA. 50.05 40.05 30.05 20.05 10.05. Imports MEX <-- CAN. 0.05 1990. 11. 1991. 1992. 1993. 1994. 1995. 1996. 1997. 1998. Appendix 4: Calibration for Armington aggregator. This appendix describe in detail how we calibrate the parameters for Armington aggregator: the elasticity of substitution between intermediate goods and the weight every country give to. 18. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan.

(26) Some Business Cycle Consequences of Trade Agreements: The Case of the North American Free Trade Agreement. its domestically produced good. • Elasticity of substitution between intermediate goods: α from Armington aggregator: From first order conditions for intermediate goods we impose the condition that the sum of Armington aggregator to be 1:. α a a (1 − ω 1 )a−α 1 G1 = q1 =⇒ ω 1 = 1 − q1 (. a1 α ) G1. b1 α ) (1 − τ )α−1 G1 b2 = q2b =⇒ ω 2 = 1 − q2b ( )α G2 a2 = q2a =⇒ ω 2 = q2a ( )α (1 − τ )α−1 G2. α b b ω 1 (1 − τ )1−α b−α 1 G1 = q1 =⇒ ω 1 = q1 ( α (1 − ω2 )b−α 2 G2 α ω 2 (1 − τ )1−α a−α 2 G2. Taking into account that in steady state we have constant share of imports in output, we can compute a1 1 − s1 b1 s1 a2 s2 b2 1 − s2 = and = b, = a and = a G1 q1 G1 q2 G2 q1 G2 q2b Therefore •. — for the first country we have a coefficient α satisfying 1 − q1a (. 1 − s1 α s1 ) = q1b ( a )α (1 − τ )α−1 a q1 q1. — for the second country we have a coefficient α satisfying 1 − q2b (. 1 − s2 α s2 ) = q2a ( b )α (1 − τ )α−1 b q2 q2. Therefore we have in both countries α like a function of τ . • Coefficients for Armington aggregator (weights): The functional form we use for Armington aggregator is 1. G(ai , bi ) = ((1 − ω)a1−α + ω(1 − τ )1−α b1−α ) 1−α i i In order to calibrate the coefficient ω we start from the imports share of output, ratio calibrated with the existing data. Therefore, if we denote this share by s we have that s1 =. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan. q1b b1 q2a a2 , s2 = p1 G(a1 , b1 ) p2 G(b2 , a2 ). 19.

(27) Maria Bejan. Since we normalized both prices of final goods with 1, we have that p1 = p2 = 1. We will compute the coefficient only for the first economy since for the second one will be completely symmetric taking into account the symmetry of our system. From the cost minimization problem in the final good production, we have:. min(q1a a1 + q1b b1 ) s.t.(1 − ω)a1−α + ω(1 − τ )1−α b1−α = G1−α 1 1 1 First order conditions: ¾. b1 α q1a ω(1 − τ )1−α ) = b =⇒ a1 1−ω q1 b1 q a ω(1 − τ )1−α 1/α =⇒ = ( 1b ) a1 1−ω q1. q1a = λ(1 − ω)(1 − α)a−α 1 q1b = λω(1 − α)(1 − τ )1−α b−α 1. =⇒ (. Now, from the share of imports we will get the coefficients: ) q1b b1 q1b b1 s1 = p1 G(a 1 ,b1 ) = ⇒ s 1 q1a a1 + q1b b1 p1 G(a1 , b1 ) = q1a a1 + q1b b1 1 1 = qa qa ω(1−τ )1−α s1 = qa ⇒ 1 a1 1 1 +1 ( )−1/α + 1 1−ω q b b1 qb qb 1. =⇒ ω1 =. ω2 =. 20. q1a (1−τ ) 1−α −α ) α ] q1b qa (1−τ ) 1−α ∗ ( 1 qb ) α ]−α 1. [( s11 − 1) ∗ ( 1 + [( s11 − 1). [( s12 − 1) ∗ (. q2b (1−τ ) 1−α −α ) α ] q2a. 1 + [( s12 − 1) ∗ (. 1. 1. q a (1 − τ ) 1−α −α 1 ω ) α ] =⇒ = [( − 1) ∗ ( 1 b ⇒ 1−ω s1 q1. q2b (1−τ ) 1−α −α ) α ] q2a. =. =. q1a (1−τ ) 1−α −α ) α ] q1b q a (1−τ ) 1−α s1 + [(1 − s1 ) ∗ ( 1 qb ) α ]−α 1. [(1 − s1 ) ∗ (. [(1 − s2 ) ∗ (. q2b (1−τ ) 1−α −α ) α ] q2a. s2 + [(1 − s2 ) ∗ (. q2b (1−τ ) 1−α −α ) α ] q2a. in the first country. in the second country. EUI-WP RSCAS 2007/03 © 2007 Maria Bejan.

(28)

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

M. In a high elevation alpine larch stand in Montana, the dominant pathogenic species Heterobasidion occidentale has hybridized with a rare Eastern North American population of

Inoltre, in virtù della nostra imperiale autorità, e- sentiamo e solleviamo del tutto i cavalieri e il popolo di Valcamonica dalla servitù e dal dominio e dalle pretese di tutti

under the hypothesis of ψð3686Þ → ¯pK þ π 0 Λ, with the invariant mass of the two photons constrained to the π 0 mass. For events with more than one combination meeting

Ces exemples attestent qu’il est beaucoup plus fréquent que le terme uxor disparaisse lorsqu’une femme est citée dans un témoignage et qu’il réap- paraisse plus volontiers dans

In this demo, a flexible SDN/NFV orchestrator is used to create and instantiate virtual network functions and to connect them using a SDN-based multi-layer network, including

The smart behaviour of the polymer was significantly improved by the addi- tion of low amounts (10% w/w) of a proper plasticizer, benzyl alcohol in the specific instance, which

In particular, participants perceived both still and carbonated mineral water as fresher and more pleasant when the liquid was tasted in a plastic cup as compared to conditions

Blue-stained titanium foil, d amount of heparin on HA-heparin coated titanium foils as a function of the heparin concentration used in the electrodeposition bath (0.2/5 g L -1 )..