• Non ci sono risultati.

Seeing like the IMF on capital account liberalization

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "Seeing like the IMF on capital account liberalization"

Copied!
35
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

This is an author version of the contribution published on:

New Political Economy,

2012, 17(1), pp. 59-76. doi: 10.1080/13563467.2011.569021

The definitive version is available at:

http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/13563467.2011.569021#.UxY g26XnXG4

(2)

Seeing like the IMF on capital account liberalization

Manuela Moschella

Abstract

This paper pursues a twofold objective. First, the paper is in interested in understanding how the IMF made the issue of capital account liberalization legible. That is to say, the paper aims at unveiling the legibility map adopted by the IMF and sponsored across its membership. Second, the paper is interested in understanding how the IMF’s map was accepted by member states. Specifically, the paper investigates how member countries were persuaded to adopt the policies prescribed by the Fund. In order to assess the persuasiveness of the IMF’s map, the paper traces the debate within the IMF Board related to the decision to amend the IMF’s Articles of Agreement to give the Fund mandate and jurisdiction over capital account liberalization so to complement the Fund’s existing mandate and jurisdiction over current account transactions. Tracing the negotiations on the amendment, the paper argues and illustrates that the IMF used the ambiguities that characterized its cognitive map on capital account liberalization to persuade member countries about the need to amend the Articles. Nevertheless, when the Asian crisis vividly showed the urgency of solving the ambiguities in the Fund’s cognitive map in order to effectively manage the integration of world’s capital markets, the persuasiveness of the IMF’s map declined.

Keywords: IMF; capital account liberalization; ambiguity; influence;

(3)

Few issues have sparked such lively debate among scholars and policymakers as the merits of capital account liberalization, that is, the removal of controls from cross-border capital transactions. For some, the free movement of capital flows leads to an efficient allocation of capital and diversification of risk. Augmenting domestic savings, the transfer of capital to its most productive uses boosts investments and economic growth thereby benefiting individual countries as well as the world economy. For others, the free movement of capital flows does not necessarily improve the chances of economic growth. Since economies are rife with distortions, such as incomplete and asymmetric information, free capital mobility does not guarantee that capital is allocated to its most productive use thereby creating an economically suboptimal situation while raising systemic risk.1

The International Monetary Fund (IMF) has been at the forefront of the debate on the merits of capital account liberalization, particularly because of its distinctive organizational mandate and features. For one thing, the IMF has the responsibility to oversee the international monetary and financial system. The Fund accomplishes this task by monitoring member countries’ economic policies through its Article IV surveillance reports.2 For another, the Fund possesses its own in-house research capacity being an institution primarily staffed with PhD economists 3 The organizational structure of the IMF, which is made up of area and thematic departments, including a research department,

(4)

make the Fund well-placed for elaborating and disseminating theoretical and empirical studies on topics relevant to its activities. As the analytic institutions introduced in the Introduction to this Special Issue, the purpose of the Fund’ departments is that of defining a policy problem, diagnosing its causes, and prescribing the economic policies that member states are expected to adopt for its solution.

For instance, starting at the beginning of the 1990s, the IMF developed a specific cognitive map for solving the problem posed by the progressive integration of world’s capital markets. Specifically, IMF staff helped elaborate the policy idea of orderly liberalization that revolved around two dimensions. First, there was a normative dimension that defined liberalization as both inevitable and desirable course of economic policy for its positive effects on member countries’ economic performance. Second, there was a procedural dimension that pertained to the economic policies that members were expected to pursue in order to reap the benefits of global financial integration.

Unveiling the Fund’s cognitive map on capital account liberalization, this paper builds on James C. Scott’s (1998) work that aims at understanding how states make societies legible and at examining the distance between how policies are designed and how they are received by the affected population. Following on Scott’s argument, this paper pursues a twofold objective. First, the paper is in interested in understanding how the IMF made the issue of capital account liberalization legible. That is to say, the paper aims at unveiling the legibility map adopted by the IMF and sponsored across its membership. Second, the paper is interested in understanding how the IMF’s

(5)

map was accepted by member states. Specifically, the paper investigates how member countries were persuaded to adopt the policies prescribed by the Fund, thereby contributing to this special issue’s interest in connecting the internal business of IOs with their external influence.

In order to assess the persuasiveness of the IMF’s map, the paper traces the debate within the IMF Board related to the decision to amend the IMF’s Articles of Agreement to give the Fund mandate and jurisdiction over capital account liberalization so to complement the Fund’s existing mandate and jurisdiction over current account transactions.4 Tracing the negotiations on the amendment, the paper argues and illustrates that the IMF used the ambiguities that characterized its cognitive map on capital account liberalization to persuade member countries about the need to amend the Articles.

In particular, the ambiguities related to the use of capital controls, the sequence of liberalization, and the availability of Fund’s financial support in the event of capital flight were pivotal in forging consensus within the IMF membership. Indeed, these ambiguities contributed to make the IMF’s map compatible with the varieties of national interests represented in the IMF Board and, in particular, with the competing interests of industrial and developing countries.5 In other words, by casting the IMF’s advice in general rather in detailed form, the ambiguities present in the Fund’s map on capital liberalization helped neutralized the political divide within the IMF Board, thereby facilitating an agreement. As the empirical analysis is going to illustrate, by postponing the debate on the most contentious implications related to the decision to amend the Articles, the ambiguities in the idea of

(6)

orderly liberalization facilitated the emergence of consensus within the IMF Board to the extent that the amendment seemed to simultaneously respond to the concerns of industrial countries, which wanted to consolidate and expand globalization across the globe, and to the concerns of developing countries that aspired to the levels of income and stability achieved by the advanced economies.

Nevertheless, when the Asian crisis vividly showed the urgency of solving the ambiguities in the Fund’s cognitive map in order to effectively manage the integration of world’s capital markets, the distance between the IMF’s general map and member countries’ practical concerns became evident and with it the decreasing influence of the IMF over its members. Indeed, as a result of the Asian crisis, which showcased the useful role that capital capital controls can play in stemming capital flight and the importance of an appropriately sequenced financial liberalization, the IMF found itself entrapped in its own intellectual map. On the one hand, the ambiguities present in the IMF’s map prevented the Fund to provide operational guidance to its members. On the other, clarifying the ambiguities in its map contributed to politicizing the debate within the Board making an agreement difficult to be reached.

I develop my argument in three steps. In the next section, I specify the content of the IMF’s legibility map on capital account liberalization; specifically, I review the idea of orderly liberalization bringing to the surface its inherent ambiguities. The second and third section illustrate the debate within the IMF Board on capital account liberalization from 1995 to 1998

(7)

showing how IMF staff’s legibility map influenced member countries’ choice to amend the Articles of Agreement and how such an influence weakened as the ambiguities in the Fund’s legibility map dissolved in the aftermath of the Asian crisis. The paper concludes with a summary of the findings and with some reflections on the inner workings of the IMF.

1. Capital account liberalization from 19th Street: the legibility map

of orderly liberalization

In the early 1990s, IMF staff helped shape the policy idea of orderly liberalization – which in the Fund’s language meant to proceed securely along the path of liberalization but in a manner that was not disruptive for national and international stability. Specifically, this idea, which can be considered as a legibility map in Scott’s terms, revolved around two dimensions: a normative and a procedural dimension.

The normative dimension of orderly liberalization

The normative dimension of the idea of orderly liberalization revolved around the notion that the liberalization of capital markets is inevitable and desirable course of economic policy. Drawing on the experience of industrial countries, which by the mid-1990 had all liberalized their capital accounts, several internal studies led to the conclusion that it was logical to assume that developing countries would and should liberalize their capital account at some stage in the course of their development (Quirk 1994). The progressive pattern

(8)

of removal of capital controls in developing countries, the speed of information technology advances and the associated decrease in transaction costs also lent significant support to the presumption that the integration of capital markets was unlikely to be reversed. In addition, the collapse of the planned economies at the end of the 1980s and progress in international trade talks, with the conclusion of the Uruguay round and the creation of the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 1995, accelerated the momentum behind the view of an ever-expanding global integration.6

The perception that liberalization would have proceeded apace was further re-enforced by pointing to the still unrealized potential of global financial integration. ‘Since international portfolio diversification is far from complete, the scale of international financial flows is bound to continue increasing for some time’ Stanley Fischer, IMF First Deputy Managing Director, (1997b) noted. This statement reflected the awareness that information about investment opportunities in developing country markets and international diversification of portfolios in industrialized countries had not still reached their full potential. Hence, from the IMF’s perspective, it was logical to assume that as soon as information and diversification expanded so would financial integration.

Not only was liberalization seen as inevitable. It was also conceived as desirable because of its impact on member countries’ economic prospects. Specifically, IMF staff maintained that liberalization was beneficial as a mechanism of economic growth (welfare-enhancing argument) and as a mechanism to enforce sustainable economic policies (discipline argument). In

(9)

other words, IMF staff identified a clear positive causal relationship between liberalization and economic growth.

Seen from 19th Street, there were few doubts about the benefits of liberalization. ‘The globalization of financial markets is a very positive development,’ Camdessus (1995a) forcefully and repeatedly commented, depicting capital flows as ‘one of the driving forces of global growth in recent years’ (see also Camdessus 1995b). The rate of growth of the high-inflows countries in Latin American and Asia, which were growing at an average rate of 4 and 7 percent a year respectively in the period from 1990 to 1994, contributed to corroborating the presumption that capital inflows were an important feature in the economic growth of developing countries (IMF 1994: 6-8, 22-7, 57-61).7 Together with boosting investments and growth, the beneficial effects of the free movement of capital flows were deemed to work through the domestic financial system. Indeed, strong views were expressed that the opening of the capital account might increase the efficiency of the domestic financial system by introducing competition from abroad and stimulating innovation (Fischer 1997a; see also Guitiàn 1996).

From the Fund’s perspective, another factor made the liberalization of international capital flows beneficial for member countries’ economic growth: market discipline. Specifically, the argument was that increased global financial integration would accrue to the domestic welfare by narrowing the scope for economic mismanagement. ‘Normally, when the market’s judgment is right,’ Fischer (1997a) noted, ‘this discipline is a valuable one, which

(10)

improves overall economic performance by rewarding good policies and penalizing bad.’

The agreement on the benefits of liberalization did not remain at the conceptual level but translated into the IMF’s actual advice to member countries. Indeed, the IMF had few doubts about the compelling need for member countries to integrate with global financial flows. As the Managing Director Michel Camdessus (1997b) put it, member countries faced a ‘stark choice’ under conditions of globalization. They can ‘either … integrate themselves into the international economy or … become marginalized from it and thus fall farther and farther behind in terms of growth and development.’ Hence, as a departmental study on IMF surveillance reveals, until the late 1997, ‘the Fund has tended […] to welcome members’ actions taken to liberalize capital account transactions.’ Specifically, with regard to inflows, ‘the tightening of controls […] was generally discouraged’ and the staff has general conveyed to national authorities of both industrial and developing countries a sense of ‘general distaste’ for the imposition of controls on outflows, even as a way of addressing balance of payments difficulties.8

The procedural dimension of orderly liberalization

Not only did the voice coming from the Fund posit the inevitability and the desirability of capital account liberalization. It also identified the policy measures that members were required to adopt in order to reap the benefits of global financial integration. Indeed, opening to international capital flows poses significant risks to domestic macroeconomic stability. Among other

(11)

effects, capital inflows may lead to inflationary pressures, loss of competitiveness induced by exchange rate appreciation, and increased vulnerability to crisis caused by sudden shifts in markets sentiment. Hence, as a legibility map, the idea of orderly liberalization suggested member countries specific economic reforms in order to manage the consequences of global financial integration. Specifically, the Fund’s institutional preferences mainly regarded three issues: capital controls, macro and structural preconditions, and the role of the IMF to help members liberalize.

On the first issue, the voice coming from the Fund systematically argued that capital controls were no longer an effective tool for policy makers to avoid overheating and vulnerability to crises because of their increasing costs and ineffectiveness. For one thing, in an environment in which the liberalization of current account transactions was a reality, the opportunity to circumvent controls abounded.For the other, numerous theoretical studies and empirical observations lent substantial support to the hypothesis that capital controls were becoming increasingly ineffective, especially in the long-run. For instance, drawing on the data of a large panel of developing countries’ experience with capital account liberalization, the research conducted by IMF departments documented that capital flight is likely to occur the introduction of capital controls notwithstanding.9 The experience of those countries that resorted to controls during the 1993 Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) crisis is illustrative here. Indeed, from the Fund’s perspective, the temporary controls imposed by Ireland and Portugal on short-term capital flows during

(12)

the crisis proved ineffective in the reducing the speculative pressures on their currencies (Quirk et al. 1995: 12).

Not only were capital controls ‘ineffective.’ From the Fund’s perspective, they were also viewed as damaging in that ‘they may discourage longer-term portfolio and direct investment flows’ and spillover to other countries.10 In the words of an IMF’s internal study, ‘controls imposed by one country typically affect others adversely (for example, by delaying necessary exchange rate adjustments, or limiting the repatriation of invested capital or financial market access) and can, therefore, be destructive of international prosperity.’11 In essence, the mainstream view inside the Fund conceived of capital liberalization as the ‘first best’ solution. ‘The rapid integration of capital markets has shifted the balance of costs and benefits away from the controls.’12

The second set of policies upon which IMF staff focused as a means to manage the process of capital account liberalization pertained to the macroeconomic and structural policies deemed necessary in the sequence of liberalization. Looking within the IMF’s general call for ‘sound’ macroeconomic policies, the voice coming from the IMF tended to emphasise certain policies over others. Specifically, the IMF showed some preference for fiscal policy over monetary and exchange rate policy as an instrument to stem the demand pressure arising from the decision to open the domestic economy to international capital flows (Camdessus 1996a; IMF 1996: 62-4). As far as concerns structural policies, then, IMF staff and management repeatedly emphasized the importance of an efficient domestic financial system for a

(13)

member country to integrate with the international financial system. As Michel Camdessus (1996c) repeatedly put it, ‘we [at the IMF] believe banking systems [can] be strengthened.’

Finally, based on the research carried out by the IMF departments, the IMF invited member countries to strengthen the powers of the Fund to manage the challenges posed by growing financial integration. Specifically, by strengthening the Fund’s powers over capital account liberalization, member countries would have enjoyed Fund advice and financial assistance to cope with the risks of global financial integration. Seen from the IMF’s perspective, ‘the IMF …. with its nearly universal membership … is well-placed to distil and disseminate the lessons of experience from our 182 member countries.’13 Furthermore, the fact that the Fund may be called upon to finance balance of payments problems associated with the capital account provided another compelling reason for the IMF to help countries to manage the challenge of globalized finance. Drawing on this line of reasoning, IMF management and staff forcefully advocated an amendment to the IMF’s Articles of Agreement that would have extended the Fund’s mandate and jurisdiction to the promotion of capital account liberalization. Specifically, by assuming the mandate, the promotion of capital liberalization would be inserted into the goals that the IMF pursues (Article I). By assuming jurisdiction, member countries would have lost their existing right to impose capital controls (Article VI) while the IMF would have been empowered to ask a country to remove capital controls. (Article VIII) similarly to the Fund’s existing powers to promote the liberalization of current account transactions.

(14)

The discussion led thus far is not meant to suggest the existence of an unambiguous legibility map on capital liberalization inside the Fund. Rather, there were several unresolved questions including the use of capital controls, the sequence of liberalization, and the role of the IMF. For instance, IMF staff did not disaggregate the notion of capital controls. In other words, limited attention was devoted to the assessment of the effectiveness and costs of different types of controls, including reserve requirements on foreign deposits, quantitative controls, controls on inflows or outflows. As late as September 1997, for instance, Fischer (1997a) noted that the Fund had still ‘to develop its analysis and evaluation of different types of capital controls, to advise countries on which types of controls are most likely to help them attain their goals, and on optimal methods of liberalization.’ Furthermore, there was an issue as to how flexible the criteria for approving capital controls should be had the IMF expanded its jurisdiction to capital flows through an amendment. The amendment, indeed, would have given the IMF the powers to approve capital controls akin to the existing powers over controls on current account transactions. However, until late in 1997, IMF staff did not provide a preview of the operational criteria that would be applied to temporary and non-temporary restrictions14 and to restrictions on inflows and outflows introduced for balance of payments reasons. As IMF staff conceded, ‘the criterion of “balance of payments purposes” would require elaboration in the case of inflows.’15

Ambiguity also coloured the IMF’s advice on ‘sound’ macroeconomic and structural policies as preconditions to liberalization. For all the emphasis

(15)

on the importance of fiscal restraint over alternative macroeconomic tools, the IMF did not specify the exact policy mix. For instance, it is hard to find prescriptions on the extent of fiscal adjustment as compared to monetary tightening or on the interaction between monetary and exchange rate choices. Interestingly, as late as 1995, the choice of the exchange rate was not considered ‘a critical factor in successfully moving to capital account convertibility.’16 Furthermore, in spite of the importance attached to the development of an efficient domestic financial system, IMF staff did not articulate specific guidelines on banking regulation, supervision, and transparency to assess member countries’ performance.17 As the Independent Evaluation Office’ report on the IMF approach to capital account liberalization makes this point, the broad range of prudential regulations and requirements to strengthen domestic financial sector ‘largely remained at the conceptual level and did not lead to operational advice’ to member countries (IEO 2005: 4, 29, 57).

Finally, the implications of the IMF’s advice to extend the Fund jurisdiction to the promotion of capital liberalization were left ambiguous. In particular, it was not clear whether the IMF would have had sufficient resources to go to the rescue of a country suffering a crisis in its capital account and whether, even if granted such resources, the IMF would have actually used them to go to the rescue. For instance, at certain points, staff memoranda excluded the possibility that the IMF would use its financial resources to help a country facing capital flight had the amendment won support. IMF staff motivated this position by appealing to moral hazard

(16)

concerns – the implicit assurance that the IMF would go to the rescue raised the probability of capital flight by inducing investors and policy makers to take on risky behaviour.18 At other points, however, IMF staff and management suggested that the IMF would have not let a member face a crisis on its own. In his speeches, the Managing Director, for instance, repeatedly emphasized that one of the main functions performed by the IMF over time had been the provision of timely and adequate financial assistance to its members – implying that members could expect the same treatment in the foreseeable future (Camdessus 1994; 1996b).

In sum, in the first half of the 1990s, the IMF has developed a distinct legibility map on the problem posed by global financial integration. This map was built on the stock of internal theoretical and empirical studies proving the positive effects of capital flows on member countries’ economic performance. As a result, IMF’s advice to member countries was that of removing capital controls. At the same time, the IMF encouraged member countries to implement domestic financial and macroeconomic reforms and to extend the powers of the IMF to the promotion of capital liberalization. Behind these apparent strong views, however, the IMF had yet to specify many implications of member countries’ movement toward capital convertibility. As Stanley Fischer (1997a) noted, the IMF ‘can envisage members eventually accepting the obligation to liberalize the capital account fully.’ Nevertheless, ‘what precisely that means will have to be worked out.’

(17)

2. The Influence of the IMF’s Map: The Early Negotiations

Starting in the mid-1990s, the IMF Executive Board met several times to discuss IMF staff approach to capital account liberalization. These meetings took chiefly place within the framework of the negotiations for an amendment to the IMF’s Articles of Agreement that, as already noted, was one of the IMF’s preferred institutional choice (Camdessus 1997b; Fischer 1997a; Guitiàn 1992).19

Given the politically demanding requirements for the amendment to be adopted, prescribing the support of three-fifth of members, having 85 percent of the total voting power, IMF staff had to secure the support of both industrial and developing countries around its preferred policy solution. In particular, the influence of the IMF over its members seemed being dependent on the Fund’s ability to address some of the reservations that circulated among Executive Directors at the prospect of extending the Fund jurisdiction to capital flows through an amendment to the Article of Agreement. Among these reservations, which pertained most to developing countries that had not yet fully liberalized their capital account, three practical concerns stood out. First, in various Board meetings, Executive Directors inquired IMF staff about the conditions under which members countries would have retained their existing right to impose capital controls had the amendment won support – the so-called approval policies. For instance, it was frequently asked whether the IMF would have used greater flexibility in approving controls than under the policy presently applied to payments and transfers for current international

(18)

transactions. Second, several Directors asked IMF staff to know at what point in the reform process member countries would be asked to open the capital account. Indeed, an extension of the jurisdiction over capital movements needed to provide for transitional arrangements to assure that liberalization was sequenced with macro and structural policies thereby reflecting the circumstances of individual countries. Finally, EDs had reservations on the effects of capital account liberalization on the demand for Fund financing. For instance, one of the oft-repeated questions raised during Executive Board meetings was whether the IMF had sufficient financial resources to help countries face capital account crises.20

Notwithstanding these practical concerns, the legibility map developed by the IMF on capital liberalization proved able to persuade member countries about the appropriateness of the choice to amend the Articles. In particular, the ambiguities in the IMF’s map, which accentuated its general character, proved able to bridge the divide between the IMF’s preferred institutional choices and member countries’ variegated concerns. In other words, the fact that the Fund’s legibility map did not take position on the most controversial issues related to capital liberalization but remained at the level of general principles helped it to become influential across its membership.

For instance, IMF staff papers did address the issues of the conditions on the use of capital controls, the sequence of liberalization, and the size of IMF resources. Nevertheless, IMF staff addressed these issues without pressing Executive Directors to solve those issues in their current discussions. Rather, IMF management and staff depicted the issues of the conditions on the

(19)

use of capital controls, the sequence of liberalization and the size of IMF resources as ‘technicalities’ whose implications could be debated and fixed later in the negotiation process. For instance, in a number of staff memoranda prepared from 1996 through 1997, IMF staff systematically analyzed different aspects of the potential amendment. However, IMF staff also stressed that it was not feasible to consider all of the issues related to an amendment in a few documents and that the treatment of several important aspects, including the treatment of transitional arrangements, approval policies and the financial implications of the amendment would be addressed separately.21 In this connection, during a meeting held in April 1997, IMF management strongly invited Executive Directors to accept the amendment to the Articles in spite of the still unresolved issues, noting that ‘the time it would take for members to ratify the amendment would have given members the additional time they were looking for’ to clarify many of the outstanding questions on capital account liberalization.22 That is to say, Executive Directors were encouraged to agree with the basic thrust of the approach to capital account liberalization as delineated in IMF papers.

In sum, the IMF’s legibility map framed the discussion around the questions if capital account liberalization is good for economic growth and if the IMF is the right institution to help member countries move along the path of liberalization. Behind the successful framing, the persuasiveness of the IMF over its members was certainly helped by the positive economic outlook. Indeed, in an environment in which developing countries were experiencing high rate of growth significantly financed by foreign capital, the IMF’s map

(20)

that posited the benefits of financial integration seemed compatible with what member countries were actually experiencing. In this context, the much more complicated questions of how capital account liberalization is beneficial and

how the IMF may help member countries in the liberalization process were

postponed. As a result, practical issues such as approval and transitional arrangements and the relationship between capital account liberalization and the Fund resources were relegated to the margins of the debate. Given the lack of specification of these issues, it is not surprising that several Executive Directors recall the negotiations on the amendment as revolving around technicalities.23 Some Directors even complained about the lack of clarification of the operational implications of the amendment. For instance, in a 1998 Board meeting, the Chilean representative Nicolas Eyzaguirre retrospectively noted that ‘discussions thus far have privileged the consideration of procedural and legal aspects, but some important conceptual issues remain somehow obscure.’24

Nevertheless, by avoiding to solve the most controversial political issues, the ambiguities present in the IMF’s legibility map on capital liberalization contributed to diluting the political divide between industrial and developing countries. As Camdessus (1997a) captured the outcome of the negotiations within the Board that led to the decision to proceed with the amendment to the Articles, ‘we will certainly have a lot of work to do to define the modalities of the process leading to this full liberalization.’ However, ‘we have the unanimous support of the membership on the objective.’ Indeed, if no practical issue was really at stake in the ongoing

(21)

negotiations, industrial and developing countries could easily converge around the views that capital account liberalization is welfare-enhancing and that the IMF has the capacity to help member countries in moving towards such a desirable policy course. As a result, by April 1997, Executive Directors went public with the proposal to amend the Articles, suggesting an extension of mandate and jurisdiction over capital transactions (IMF 1997: 39).

This is not to say that the influence of the IMF’s legibility map was undisputed. Whereas Directors agreed on the principle to liberalize the capital account eventually and on the importance of the role of the IMF in the process, reservations persisted on the conditions for the use of capital controls, on the timing of liberalization and on the extent of help that could be granted by the IMF in event of capital flight. However, the persuasiveness of the IMF’s legibility map lied in its ability of postponing discussion among member countries on the practical implications of the suggested reform to the IMF’s Articles. For instance, in one of the Executive Board meetings that preceded the issuance of the IMF Annual Report (1997) where EDs endorsed the proposal to amend the Articles, the UK representative Gus O´Donnell remarked, ‘it is important at this stage not to be bogged down in details,’ suggesting hat the crucial issues at stake were recognizing the benefits of free capital flows and the importance of the role of the IMF in the international system characterized by growing capital flows.25 Similarly, Benny Andersen, representative of the Scandinavian constituency, noted ‘there are still many operational aspects of an expanded mandate that need to be addressed.’ Nevertheless, ‘we can ... agree with the basic thrust of the approach ... outlined

(22)

by the staff.’26 Still, a number of developing countries’ representatives made clear that they could accept to move toward the amendment only with the understanding that its details would clearly be refined over a longer period of time.27

Of course, the influence of the IMF’s map on the decision to amend the Articles can also be understood in light of some structural factors such as the positive economic outlook and the United States’ economic interest in international financial integration. While these factors certainly created a permissive environment to the decision to amend the Articles, they cannot solely explain the convergence of views within the IMF Board. For instance, what is striking is that until the Asian crisis burst virtually no country mounted a significant opposition to the refocusing of the IMF’s activities in the direction of supporting financial liberalization. Rather than a case of conflicting interests, the proposed amendment thereby represent a case of non-decision, that is, an instance in which alternatives are not even considered. This is not to say that, absent overt conflict, power considerations are not at play. Nevertheless, the absence of conflict warns against drawing easy correlation between distribution of interests and policy choices.

3. The declining Influence of the IMF’s Map: The Late Negotiations

On the heels of the Asian crisis, what had been an asset in the negotiations within the Board thus far suddenly became a liability. The crisis, indeed, showed that some of the ambiguities in the Fund’s thinking on capital account liberalization needed urgent clarification had the international community to

(23)

reduce the likelihood of capital account crises. The stance of Malaysian national authorities, for instance, who vehemently opposed the IMF’s ‘orthodoxy’ by introducing capital controls to stem capital flight, vividly called for specifying the conditions under which the IMF and its members can legitimate their use. Still, the fact that financial and corporate sector weaknesses and hastened liberalization contributed to the crisis along with macroeconomic imbalances spoke to the importance of clarifying the prerequisites for successful liberalization. Finally, the fact that the IMF disbursed large financial packages that proved unable to restore market confidence vividly exposed the need to specify the role of the IMF as a manager of globalised finance. In other words, the crisis unveiled a huge distance between the IMF’s legibility map and what member countries were really experiencing.

Clarifying outstanding ambiguities thereby became a matter for debate within the IMF Board. As archival documents reveal, several Directors now gave the issue of specifying the conditions to (re)introduce capital controls the greatest prominence. This was true for both industrial and developing countries, the latter being probably more vociferous now following industrial countries’ changed stance. For instance, the French ED forcefully remarked that the ‘regulation of short-term capital flows deserves to be addressed. It is a serious issue. It is not only a technical point; it is a serious policy issue.’ Similarly, the Brazilian Director Kafka emphasized the importance of clarifying ‘the distinction between controls and regulation on the one hand and prudential measures on the other.’28 The Australian Director, in turn, invited

(24)

the Board ‘to carefully and clearly delineate the specific circumstances under which [controls] might be considered.’29

The issue of preconditions and sequencing, then, jumped on top of EDs’ remarks. Several Directors called for ‘practical measures and advice’ as well as clarifications on ‘appropriate prerequisites.’30 As the representative of the African constituency Barro Chambrier explicitly put it, ‘we need also to pay particular attention to the timing and the sequencing of the liberalization of capital movements.’31 The Canadian Executive Director was the most explicit on this point,

The Fund had to consider clearly the detailed prerequisites of liberalization – a strong regulatory framework, a sound banking system, an adequate supervisory structure – as well as the appropriate sequencing of liberalization measures.

Finally, clarifying the exact implications of the expansion of the Fund’s mission to the promotion of capital liberalization became a top concern. In this connection, a number of Directors argued that agreement could not be reached ‘without ample discussion based on a detailed staff paper’ on the implications of granting jurisdiction to the Fund.32 Specifically, the implications in terms of size of IMF resources became the object of close scrutiny. For instance, some Directors peremptorily noted that ‘during the recent crisis … it had rapidly become apparent that the Fund did not have the resources to adequately help

(25)

those members in need,’33 thereby strengthening the arguments that a number of EDs had been raised in the past years on the importance to know how much help a country should expect from the IMF in the event of capital flight. In sum, the mismatch between the IMF’s map and members’ actual experience grew large.

In an attempt to address the practical concerns raised by Executive Directors, IMF staff submitted a number of papers to the Board during 1998 that tried to qualify the IMF’s previous thinking on capital account liberalization.34 However, whereas the ambiguities in the Fund’s thinking had helped forged consensus in 1997 around the IMF’s preferred institutional choices, the push for dissipating them made consensus difficult to be achieved. In particular, the attempt to reach an agreement on the conditions under which to impose capital controls, on the prerequisites for liberalization and on the ability of IMF to stem capital outflows clashed with the differing needs of industrial and developing counties. In other words, the IMF lost its influence over its members because its map could no longer bridge the divide between industrial and developing countries. The position of industrial and emerging/developing countries on capital controls is illustrative here.

On the one hand, the UK, the U.S. and the German representatives were particularly active in preventing capital controls from being introduced into the language of the IMF staff-prepared report to the Interim Committee.35 Bernd Esdar German ED, for instance, noted that ‘the Fund needed to avoid giving the impression that the institution was prepared to rethink its entire approach just because a couple of members had introduced capital controls.’

(26)

His position was echoed in the statements issued by the UK Director, while the United States representative in the Board staunchly opposed any suggestions that the Board might endorse staff papers where the conditions for the use of capital controls would go too far.36

On the other hand, developing countries asked for more flexibility in the use of controls and for specifying the conditions of their reintroduction. For instance, while acknowledging the risks entailed in ‘unilaterally backsliding on capital market liberalization,’ the Chilean Director Eyzaguirre forcefully argued that ‘all the major financial crises of the past 20-25 years had resulted from premature liberalization.’37 Hence, he invited the Board and IMF staff to recognize the effectiveness of ‘relatively well-accepted measures such as prudential regulations aimed at discouraging excessive short-term capital flows.’38 Interestingly, within the G7 countries, there were significant divisions too. Substantially modifying the Japanese’ stance in the Board, Yoshimura remarked that in light of the events in Asia ‘the Fund could no say that no reversals of capital account liberalization were appropriate.’ He thereby concluded that the issue ‘needed to be discussed further.’39

While IMF staff and management continued to battle to persuade member countries to proceed with the amendment to the IMF’s Articles,40 the IMF found itself entrapped in its own intellectual map. On the one hand, the distance between the IMF’s general map on capital liberalization and the practical concerns of member countries grew large. On the other hand, clarifying the ambiguities related to the extension of the Fund’s jurisdiction over capital flows accentuated the political conflict within the IMF

(27)

membership weakening the influence of the IMF’s legibility map over its members. As a result, the initiative to amend the Articles of Agreement failed and disappeared from the IMF agenda.

Conclusions

Investigating IMF ideas on capital account liberalization during the 1990s, many issues are worthy of attention. For instance, it could be asked whether IMF ideas are mostly shaped by the interests of powerful member countries or by the organization’s bureaucratic culture. Alternatively, it could be asked whether IMF ideas were empirically sound or not. In this article, however, I took a different tack dealing with these issues only indirectly. Indeed, the primary focus of the article has been on investigating the contours and content of the IMF’s legibility map on capital liberalization and on unveiling the mechanisms that IMF staff used to influence member countries to adopt the policies suggested by its map.

Reconstructing the idea of capital liberalization into its normative and procedural dimensions, the paper identified its general nature, which was applicable to both industrial and developing countries. Generality, however, was purchased at the cost of ambiguities, such as those pertaining to the use of capital controls, the sequencing of reforms, and the use of the Fund’s resources. The paper also found that the ambiguities present in the IMF’s map were crucial in influencing member countries to adopt the Fund’s preferred

(28)

institutional choices as attested by the decision to amend the IMF’s Article in the late 1997.

Hence, contrary to a well-established conclusion that the IMF influences its members’ economic policies by virtues of its technical and highly specialized expertise (Barnett and Finnemore 2004), the paper has here suggested that the IMF may well be influential even when its theoretical and empirical arguments are not neatly articulated. Indeed, in the negotiations for the amendment, the ambiguities embedded in the idea of orderly liberalization helped the Fund’s map not to enter into collision with the practical needs of industrial and developing countries represented in the IMF Board. By remaining at a general level, the ambiguities helped to defer the debate on the most controversial issues, thereby avoiding exacerbating the divide among competing interests. In contrast, when the IMF started specifying its map as a consequence of the Asian crisis, the process of clarification of existing ambiguities brought to the surface the divide between industrial and developing countries leading to the collapse of the initiative to amend. In sum, analogously with what Scott’s has shown in his study on social engineering, the IMF map proved influential until it did not clash with the practical needs of member countries. Of course, the permissive stance of the Fund’s most powerful members certainly contributed in allowing the emergence of the consensus within the IMF Board. Nevertheless, it cannot solely explain the converge of developing countries’ views around the Fund’s preferred institutional choice.

(29)

Finally, exploring the process through which the ideas held by IMF staff members are accepted by the Executive Directors sitting in the IMF Board, the paper has also attempted to fill in a gap in the constructivist literature on the inner workings of IOs. In particular, the paper has addressed the limitations of existing bureaucratic approaches that have primarily investigated the ideas articulated by staff members without specifying the mechanisms through these ideas are endorsed by state representatives within the organization. This lacuna has sometimes been presented as a deliberate research goal with some constructivist scholars claiming to be solely interested in the Fund’s ‘informal’ approach to capital account liberalization, that is, in ‘the ideas the IMF staff share’, rather than in ‘the official policies or rules governing the IMF’ (Chwieroth 2007: 14).

Rather than a deliberate research goal, however, a bureaucratic explanation that solely focuses on a single community of actors (IMF staff) as the only relevant agent that shapes the IMF’s policies does not do justice of the way in which the IMF actually works. In other words, the bureaucratic explanation seems largely ignoring the fact that the IMF is an intergovernmental organization, that is, an organization made by states to solve states’ economic problems and that draws its legitimacy from states. Hence, when we talk about ‘the IMF’s approach’ or ‘the IMF’s policies’ the appropriate empirical reference is not the position of individual staff members, no matter how influential they are. The policies of the IMF are the outcome of the meetings of the Executive Board. Bringing to the surface the role of ambiguity is thereby of help in specifying our understanding of the

(30)

inner-workings of the IMF because it suggests one of the mechanisms through which IMF staff win the consensus of Executive Directors.

(31)

1 Examples of these different positions can be found in Greenspan (1998), Bhagwati (1998), and Stiglitz (2000). For a

thorough discussion on the benefits and costs of financial liberalization, see, for instance, Caprio et al. (2006) and Fischer (1998).

2 Originally confined to surveillance over members’ exchange rate policies, the scope and modalities of surveillance

have changed over time. Today, Article IV consultations generally cover not only exchange rate policies, but also a broad range of macroeconomic and structural policies.

3 Statistics on IMF staff’s recruitment are available at the IMF’s webpage

http://www.imf.org/external/np/adm/rec/workenv/aboutst.htm#RecruitmentStatistics.

4 Article VIII establishes an obligation for member countries to remove controls on the making of payments ad transfers

for current account transactions. Once a member has accepted this general obligation, it is not allowed to maintain or introduce new restrictions without the approval of the Fund.

5 About the ‘constructive role’ of ambiguity in shaping political outcomes in the realm of global finance see (about the

constructive role of ambiguities Best 2005). On the strategic use of ambiguity by IMF staff in the policy area of current account convertibility see also Broome, A.J. (2008).

6 IMF Archives, SM795/164.

7 Economic growth refers here to a rise in real GDP.

8 IMF Archives, Sm/95/164: 8-10. For more details on Fund’s treatment in its surveillance activity see, also, IMF

Archives SM/95/165 Sup.1 and SM/97/32 Sup. 1.

9 IMF Archives, SM/95/164: 7-9; 17. 10 IMF Archives, SM/94/202: 20. 11 IMF Archives, SM/97/32: 6. 12 IMF Archives, SM/94/202: 25. 13 IMF Archives, MD/Sp/98/5.

14 For instance, the staff memoranda prepared in 1997 suggested alternative courses of actions rather a definitive list of

criteria. See, among others, IMF Archives SM/97/89 and IMF Archives SM/97/173.

15 IMF Archives, SM/97/32: 25. 16 IMF Archives, SM/95/164: 4.

17 The first operational guidance to the staff in the area of capital convertibility were issued in December 1995. 18 IMF Archives, SM/97/173: 23.

19 Several accounts have convincingly shown that IMF management and staff pushed the amendment into the IMF

agenda. See, for instance, Abdelal (2007) and Leiteritz (2005).

20 See, for instance, the reservations raised by EDs in the following meetings. IMF Archives EBM/97/38, EBM/97/66,

EBM/97/87.

21 See, for instance, IMF Archives SM/97/86 and SM/97/146.

22 IMF Archives EBM/97/38: 31. See also the statement prior to the meeting and the concluding remarks of the

Chairman in IMF Archives EBM/97/66.

23 Author’s interviews with IMF officials. IMF, March-June 2006.

24 IMF Archives EBM/97/93: Nicolas Eyzaguirre Alternate Director Chile (and Argentina, Bolivia, Paraguay, Peru,

Uruguay): 7.

25 IMF Archives EBM/97/38. Gus O’Donnel, UK Executive Director: 5.

26 IMF Archives EBM/97/38. Benny Andersen, Alternate Director Denmark (and Estonia, Finland, Iceland, Latvia,

Lithuania, Norway, and Sweden): 21.

27 IMF Archives EBM/97/38. Sulaiman M. Al-Turki Executive Director Saudi Arabia: 24-5; Dinah Z. Guti Executive

Director Zimbabwe (and Angola, Bostwana, Burundi, Eritrea, Gambia, Kenia, Lesotho, Liberia, Malawi, Mozambique, Namibia, Nigeria, Sierra Leone, South Africa, Swaziland, Tanzania Uganda, Zambia): 27; A. Shakour Shalaan

Executive Director Egypt (and Barhain, Iraq, Jorda, Kuwait, Lebanon,Lybia, Maldives, Oman, Quatar, Syrain Arab Repubic, United Arab Emirates, Yemen): 28.

28 IMF Archives EBM/98/38. Milleron, French Executive Director: 20; and Alexandre Kafka, Executive Director Brazil

(and Colombia, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Guiana, Haiti, Panama, Suriname, Trinidad and Tobago): 25.

29 IMF Archives EBM/98/103. Gregory Taylor Executive Director Australia (and Kiribati, Korea, Marshall Islands,

Mongolia, New Zealand, Papua New Guinea, Philippines: 12.

30 IMF Archives EBM/98/38. Gregory Taylor: 27.

31 IMF Archives EBM/98/38. A. Barro Chambrier Alternate Director Gabon (and Benin, Burkina Faso, Cameroon, Cape

Verde, Central Africa Republic, Chad, Comoros, Congo, Cote d´Ivoire, Djibouti, Equatorial Guinea, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Madagascar, Mali, Mauritania, Mauritius, Niger, Rwanda, Sao Tome and Principe, Senegal, Togo): 27.

32 IMF Archives EBM/98/38. Gregory Taylor: 28; and Alexandre Kafka: 25.

33 IMF Archives EBM/98/38. M. R. Sivaraman, Executive Director India (and Bangladesh, Bhutan, Sri Lanka): 9; See

also IMF Archives X Dinah Z. Guti, Executive Director Zimbabwe: 29.

34 IMF Archives SM/98/172; also IMF Archives SM/98/187.

(32)

36 IMF Archives EBM/98/103. Bernd Esdar, Executive Director Germany: 11; Jon Shields, Executive Director UK: 10;

and Karen Lissakers, Executive Director U.S: 14.

37 IMF Archives EBM/98/38. Nicolas Eyzaguirre Alternate Director Chile: 12. 38 IMF Archives EBM/98/103. Nicolas Eyzaguirre: 10.

39 IMF Archives EBM/98/103. Yoshimura Japanese Executive Director: 14.

40 See, for instance, the statements from the IMF Managing Director in IMF Archives EBM/98/38: 9.

References

Abdelal, R. (2007), Capital Rules. The Construction of Global Finance (Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA).

Barnett, M.N. and Finnemore, M. (2004), Rules for the World: International Organizations in

Global Politics (Cornell University Press: Ithaca, New York).

Best, J. (2005), The Limits of Transparency. Ambiguity and History of International Finance (Cornell University Press Ithaca).

Bhagwati, J. (1998), ‘The Capital Myth: the Difference Between Trade in Widgets and Dollars’,

Foreign Affairs, 77(3), pp. 7-12.

Camdessus, M. (1994), International Cooperation for High-Quality Growth: The Role of the IMF

at 50, Address at the Complutense University, Madrid, Spain, December 21, 1994.

Camdessus, M. (1995a), The IMF and the Challenges of Globalization - The Fund’s Evolving

Approach to its Constant Mission: The Case of Mexico, Address at the Zurich Economics

Society, Zurich, Switzerland, November 14, 1995.

Camdessus, M. (1995b), Prospects and Challenges in our Globalized World Economy, Address at the Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, April 4, 1995.

Camdessus, M. (1996a), Challenges Facing the IMF and Malaysia, Address at a Meeting of Financial and Business Leaders. Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia, July 15, 1996.

Camdessus, M. (1996b), The International Monetary Fund: Increasing Economic Opportunities

and Meeting the Challenges in the Global Economy, Remarks at the Mid-America

Committee, Chicago, Illinois, April 11, 1996.

Camdessus, M. (1996c), Promoting Safe and Sound Banking Systems: An IMF Perspective, Remarks at the Conference on ‘Safe and Sound Financial Systems: What Works for Latin America.’ Inter-American Development Bank, Washington, D.C., September 28, 1996 Camdessus, M. (1997a), Joint Press Conference of Philippe Maystadt, Chairman, Interim

Committee and Michel Camdessus, Managing Director, International Monetary Fund. Washington, D.C., April 28, 1997.

Camdessus, M. (1997b), Do We Still Need the IMF in an Era of Massive Private Capital Flows?, Remarks at the Economic Club of New York, New York, June 6, 1997.

(33)

Caprio, G., Honohan, P. and Stiglitz, J.E. eds. (2006), Financial Liberalization: How Far, How

Fast? (Cambridge University Press: Cambridge).

Chwieroth, J.M. (2007), ‘Testing and Measuring the Role of Ideas: The Case of Neoliberalism in the International Monetary Fund’, International Studies Quarterly, 51(1), pp. 5-30.

Fischer, S. (1997a), Capital Account Liberalization and the Role of the IMF, Paper prepared for the International Monetary Fund’s Seminar on ‘Asia and the IMF’, Hong Kong, September 19, 1997.

Fischer, S. (1997b), How to Avoid International Financial Crises and the Role of the International

Monetary Fund, Address at 15th Annual Cato Institute Monetary Conference, Washington

D.C., October 14, 1997.

Fischer, S. ed. (1998), Should the IMF pursue capital-account convertibility? (Department of Economics, Princeton University: Princeton).

Greenspan, A. (1998), ‘The Globalization of Finance’, Cato Journal, 17(3), pp. 243-250.

Guitiàn, M. (1992), The Unique Nature of the Responsibilities of the International Monetary Fund. IMF Pamphlet Series N° 46 (Washington, D.C: International Monetary Fund).

Guitiàn, M. (1996) ‘The Issue of Capital Account Convertibility: A Gap Between Norms and Reality’, in Nsouli, S.M. and Guitián, M., eds., Currency Convertibility in the Middle East

and North Africa (International Monetary Fund: Washington, D.C.).

IEO, 2005. The IMF’s approach to capital account liberalization: evaluation report, International Monetary Fund, Washington D.C.

IMF, 1994. World Economic Outlook, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C. IMF, 1996. World Economic Outlook, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C. IMF, 1997. Annual Report, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

IMF Archives EBM/97/38. Minutes of Executive Board Meeting. ‘Capital Account Convertibility -Consideration of Possible Amendment of Articles of Agreement - Further -Considerations’. April 15, 1997.

IMF Archives EBM/97/66. Minutes of Executive Board Meeting. ‘Capital Movements under an amendment of the Articles of Agreement - Concepts of ‘International Capital Movement’ and ‘Restrictions’’. June 30, 1997.

IMF Archives EBM/97/87. Minutes of the Executive Board. ‘Capital Movements Under an Amendment of the Articles of Agreement - Transitional Arrangements, Approval Policies, and Implications for Financing; and Legal Aspects of Capital Movements - Further Consideration’, August 26, 1997.

IMF Archives EBM/97/93. Minutes of Executive Board Meeting. ‘Capital Movements Under An Amendment of the Articles - Draft Report of Executive Board to Interim Committee’.

(34)

IMF Archives EBM/98/38. Executive Board Meeting. ‘Liberalization of Capital Movements Under an Amendment of Articles - Statement by the Managing Director’. April 2, 1998.

IMF Archives EBM/98/103. Executive Board Meeting. ‘Strengthening the Architecture of International Monetary System; Strengthening Financial Systems; and Orderly Capital Account Liberalization - Draft Reports of Managing Director to Interim Committee’. September 23, 1998.

IMF Archives MD/Sp/98/5. ‘Capital Account Liberalization and the Role of the Fund. Remarks by Michel Camdessus. Managing Director of the International Monetary Fund. IMF Seminar on Capital Account Liberalization’. Washington, D.C., March 9, 1998.

IMF Archives SM/94/202. ‘Issues and Developments in the International Exchange and Payments Systems’. August 1, 1994.

IMF Archives SM/95/164. ‘Capital Account Convertibility: Review of Experience and Implications for Fund Policies’. July 7, 1995.

IMF Archives SM/95/164, Sup. 1. ‘Capital Account Convertibility - Review of Experience and Implications for Fund Policies - Background Paper’. July 10, 1995.

IMF Archives SM/97/32. ‘Capital Account Convertibility and the Role of the Fund-Review of Experience and Consideration of a Possible Amendment of the Articles’. February 5, 1997. IMF Archives SM/97/32 Supplement 1. ‘Review of Experience with Capital Account Liberalization

and Strengthened Procedures Adopted by the Fund’. February 6, 1997.

IMF Archives SM/97/86. ‘Capital Account Convertibility and a Possible Amendment of the Articles: Further Considerations’. March 25, 1997.

IMF Archives SM/97/146. ‘Capital Movements Under an Amendment of the Articles: Concepts of ‘International Capital Movements’ and ‘Restrictions’’. June 10, 1997.

IMF Archives SM/97/173. ‘Capital Account Convertibility: Transitional Arrangements, Approval Policies and Financing Under an Amendment’. July 1, 1997.

IMF Archives SM/98/172. ‘Developments and Issues in the International Exchange and Payments System’. July 7, 1998.

IMF Archives SM/98/187. ‘Theoretical and Practical Aspects of Capital Account Liberalization’. July 17, 1998.

Leiteritz, R.J. (2005), ‘Explaining organizational outcomes: the International Monetary Fund and capital account liberalization’, Journal of International Relations and Development, 8(1), pp. 1-26.

Quirk, P.J., 1994. Capital Account Convertibility: A New Model for Developing Countries. IMF Working Paper N° 94/81 (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund).

(35)

Stiglitz, J.E. (2000), ‘Capital Market Liberalization, Economic Growth, and Instability’, World

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

Sono giardini da vivere e godere, al sole e all’ombra, dove spazi erbosi in morbi- de modellazioni sono circondati o si alternano a macchie di alberi e arbu- sti,

Following Galor and Zeira (1993), we study the effect of the world interest rate on inequality and growth for the period 1985-2005, char- acterized by falling world interest rates

Tali furono i casi di Savigliano, di Cuneo e di Fossano, tutti nell’orbita politica del comune di Asti, e proprio la Storia di Savigliano del 1844 costituisce un buon esempio

This kind of multi-method approach based both on netnography and field analysis could represent on one hand, the social learning phenomenon and on the other one, the

Italy has made progress in reducing the large number of pending court cases, but with more than a thousand days still needed to enforce a contract, a more efficient judicial system

distribution Forest structure Age structure and/or diameter distribution of forest and other wooded land, classified by availability for wood supply 1.4 Carbon stock Carbon stock

In particular, Thomas (1999) calculated chemical enrichment and stellar abundance ratios of galaxies within a hierarchical clustering scheme, by adopting star formation histories