• Non ci sono risultati.

How Has Recent Technology Changed the Labor Market? A Quantitative Macroeconomic Perspective

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "How Has Recent Technology Changed the Labor Market? A Quantitative Macroeconomic Perspective"

Copied!
33
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

How Has Recent Technology Changed the Labor Market? A Quantitative Macroeconomic Perspective

Christian vom Lehn

Brigham Young University

INAPP November 30, 2018

(2)

Two Major Changes in Labor Markets

I

U.S. labor markets of last several decades characterized by job polarization and declining labor share of income

−.20.2.4Log Change in Hours Share, 1982−2012

0 20 40 60 80 100

Occ Skill Distribution Percentile

50.0 52.0 54.0 56.0 58.0 60.0 62.0 64.0 66.0 68.0

194719481949195119521954195519561958195919611962196319651966196819691970197219731975197619771979198019821983198419861987198919901991199319941996199719982000200120032004200520072008201020112012201420152017

Labor Share of Income

Year

I

Job polarization also in Europe (Goos, Manning and Salomons (2009,2014); Michaels, Natraj and Van Reenen (2014)); labor share decline worldwide (Karabarbounis and Neiman (2013))

(3)

Two Major Changes in Labor Markets

I

U.S. labor markets of last several decades characterized by job polarization and declining labor share of income

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015

Year 0.2

0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5

Share of Total Hours

Abstract Routine Manual

50.0 52.0 54.0 56.0 58.0 60.0 62.0 64.0 66.0 68.0

194719481949195119521954195519561958195919611962196319651966196819691970197219731975197619771979198019821983198419861987198919901991199319941996199719982000200120032004200520072008201020112012201420152017

Labor Share of Income

Year

I

Not just U.S. – job polarization also in Europe (Goos, Manning and Salomons (2009,2014); Michaels, Natraj and Van Reenen (2014)) , labor share decline worldwide (Karabarbounis and Neiman (2013))

(4)

What We Know and What We Don’t

I

What We Know: Lots of empirical evidence supporting that technology of some form is a key driver of these changes

(e.g. Autor and Dorn (2013); Karabarbounis and Neiman (2013); Michaels et al. (2014);

Goos, Manning and Salomons (2014); Eden and Gaggl (2018b); vom Lehn (2018b))

I

What We Don’t Know (as much): Exact quantitative mechanisms driving these changes – the “how” of technology and labor markets

I

Remainder of This Talk:

I Start from natural macroeconomic benchmarks – falling price of machines/technology and neoclassical theories of production

I Highlight findings using neoclassical theory for polarization and labor share I Discuss recent and ongoing work to further address channels through which

technology impacts polarization and the labor share

(5)

What We Know and What We Don’t

I

What We Know: Lots of empirical evidence supporting that technology of some form is a key driver of these changes

(e.g. Autor and Dorn (2013); Karabarbounis and Neiman (2013); Michaels et al. (2014);

Goos, Manning and Salomons (2014); Eden and Gaggl (2018b); vom Lehn (2018b))

I

What We Don’t Know (as much): Exact quantitative mechanisms driving these changes – the “how” of technology and labor markets

I

Remainder of This Talk:

I Start from natural macroeconomic benchmarks – falling price of machines/technology and neoclassical theories of production

I Highlight findings using neoclassical theory for polarization and labor share I Discuss recent and ongoing work to further address channels through which

technology impacts polarization and the labor share

(6)

What We Know and What We Don’t

I

What We Know: Lots of empirical evidence supporting that technology of some form is a key driver of these changes

(e.g. Autor and Dorn (2013); Karabarbounis and Neiman (2013); Michaels et al. (2014);

Goos, Manning and Salomons (2014); Eden and Gaggl (2018b); vom Lehn (2018b))

I

What We Don’t Know (as much): Exact quantitative mechanisms driving these changes – the “how” of technology and labor markets

I

Remainder of This Talk:

I Start from natural macroeconomic benchmarks – falling price of machines/technology and neoclassical theories of production

I Highlight findings using neoclassical theory for polarization and labor share I Discuss recent and ongoing work to further address channels through which

technology impacts polarization and the labor share

(7)

What We Know and What We Don’t

I

What We Know: Lots of empirical evidence supporting that technology of some form is a key driver of these changes

(e.g. Autor and Dorn (2013); Karabarbounis and Neiman (2013); Michaels et al. (2014);

Goos, Manning and Salomons (2014); Eden and Gaggl (2018b); vom Lehn (2018b))

I

What We Don’t Know (as much): Exact quantitative mechanisms driving these changes – the “how” of technology and labor markets

I

Remainder of This Talk:

I Start from natural macroeconomic benchmarks – falling price of machines/technology and neoclassical theories of production

I Highlight findings using neoclassical theory for polarization and labor share I Discuss recent and ongoing work to further address channels through which

technology impacts polarization and the labor share

(8)

What We Know and What We Don’t

I

What We Know: Lots of empirical evidence supporting that technology of some form is a key driver of these changes

(e.g. Autor and Dorn (2013); Karabarbounis and Neiman (2013); Michaels et al. (2014);

Goos, Manning and Salomons (2014); Eden and Gaggl (2018b); vom Lehn (2018b))

I

What We Don’t Know (as much): Exact quantitative mechanisms driving these changes – the “how” of technology and labor markets

I

Remainder of This Talk:

I Start from natural macroeconomic benchmarks – falling price of machines/technology and neoclassical theories of production

I Highlight findings using neoclassical theory for polarization and labor share

I Discuss recent and ongoing work to further address channels through which technology impacts polarization and the labor share

(9)

What We Know and What We Don’t

I

What We Know: Lots of empirical evidence supporting that technology of some form is a key driver of these changes

(e.g. Autor and Dorn (2013); Karabarbounis and Neiman (2013); Michaels et al. (2014);

Goos, Manning and Salomons (2014); Eden and Gaggl (2018b); vom Lehn (2018b))

I

What We Don’t Know (as much): Exact quantitative mechanisms driving these changes – the “how” of technology and labor markets

I

Remainder of This Talk:

I Start from natural macroeconomic benchmarks – falling price of machines/technology and neoclassical theories of production

I Highlight findings using neoclassical theory for polarization and labor share I Discuss recent and ongoing work to further address channels through which

technology impacts polarization and the labor share

(10)

Machines are Getting Cheaper

I

Benchmark way to think of technological change is that innovation makes machines cheaper and cheaper over time

−.4−.3−.2−.10.1.2Log Relative Price of Investment (1980=0)

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020

PWT WDI KLEMS

FIGUREVII

Declining Global Price of Investment Goods

Source: Karabarbounis and Neiman (2013)

I

Reduction in price of machines impacts labor demand – firms to substitute from certain workers to machines, reducing labor income and changing job composition

(11)

Neoclassical Production Framework

I

Aggregate production function (in spirit of Autor and Dorn (2013)):

Y=K1−α

µnrL

γnr −1

nrγnr + (1− µnr)

 µrL

γr −1

rγr + (1− µr)Mγr −1γr

γr −1γr γnr −1γnr

(1−α) γnr γnr −1

Lnr :Non-routine workers Lr :Routine workers M:Machines K: Other capital

Key parameters: elasticities of substitution (γnrr), production weights (µnr, µr)

(12)

Implications for Polarization and Labor Share

I

How will declining price of machines (PM) impact share of employment in routine jobs (sr) and labor share of income (Lsh)?

I

Assuming profit maximization and competitive markets, comparative statics imply:

sr

∂PM PM

=srξM(1sr) (γr− γnr)

Lsh

∂PM PM

=Lsh(1Lsh)

1− ξMsincnr

γr+ ξMsincnrγnr1

I

Three critical quantitative objects:

I γr,γnr: elasticities of substitution

I ξM=P PMM

MM+wrLr: share of income machines receive relative to routine workers (function of prices and parameters)

I ∂PPmm: amount of change in price of machines

(13)

Implications for Polarization and Labor Share

I

How will declining price of machines (PM) impact share of employment in routine jobs (srL Lr

r+Lnr) and labor share of income (Lsh)?

I

Assuming profit maximization and competitive markets, comparative statics imply:

sr

∂PM PM

=srξM(1sr) (γr− γnr)

Lsh

∂PM PM

=Lsh(1Lsh)

1− ξMsincnr

γr+ ξMsincnrγnr1

I

Three critical quantitative objects:

I γr,γnr: elasticities of substitution

I ξM=P PMM

MM+wrLr: share of income machines receive relative to routine workers (function of prices and parameters)

I ∆PPmm: amount of change in price of machines

(14)

Implications for Polarization and Labor Share

I

How will declining price of machines (PM) impact share of employment in routine jobs (srL Lr

r+Lnr) and labor share of income (Lsh)?

I

Assuming profit maximization and competitive markets, comparative statics imply:

sr

∂PM PM

=srξM(1sr) (γr− γnr)

Lsh

∂PM PM

=Lsh(1Lsh)

1ξMsincnr

γrMsincnrγnr1

I

Three critical quantitative objects:

I γr,γnr: elasticities of substitution

I ξM=P PMM

MM+wrLr: share of income machines receive relative to routine workers (function of prices and parameters)

I ∆PPmm: amount of change in price of machines

(15)

Implications for Polarization and Labor Share

I

How will declining price of machines (PM) impact share of employment in routine jobs (srL Lr

r+Lnr) and labor share of income (Lsh)?

I

Assuming profit maximization and competitive markets, comparative statics imply:

sr

∂PM PM

=srξM(1sr) (γr− γnr)

Lsh

∂PM PM

=Lsh(1Lsh)

1− ξMsincnr

γr+ ξMsincnrγnr1

I

Three critical quantitative objects:

I γr,γnr: elasticities of substitution

I ξM=P PMM

MM+wrLr: share of income machines receive relative to routine workers (function of prices and parameters)

I ∆PPmm: amount of change in price of machines

(16)

Findings: Eden and Gaggl (2018b, RED)

I

Eden and Gaggl (2018) – use version of this framework to show technological change can account for 50% of labor share declineA. Labor Share

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 57

58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66

Income Share (% of GDP)

Labor Share: Baseline Labor Share: Constant ICT price Labor Share: Data (BLS) Initial SS

I

Caveat: requires a re-nesting of routine and non-routine labor – capital-skill complementarity (Krusell et al. (2000)); model can’t fit the data with Autor and Dorn (2013) nesting.

(17)

Findings: Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017, JME)

I

Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017) study polarization in generalized neoclassical production technology

I

Contrast: use movements in quantities of machines (MM) instead of prices (PPMM)

I

Quantitative exercises:

I estimateMM1 I ξM=0.0845 I γr=1

I

=⇒account for roughly 10% of observed changes in employment between routine and non-routine jobs

I

To exactly match observed polarization, needMM >20,000%of observed change.

I

Results may be sensitive to using prices vs. quantities and capital aggregation (see Eden and Gaggl (2018a, WP))

(18)

Findings: Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017, JME)

I

Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017) study polarization in generalized neoclassical production technology

I

Contrast: use movements in quantities of machines (MM) instead of prices (PPMM)

I

Quantitative exercises:

I estimateMM1 I ξM=0.0845 I γr=1

I

=⇒account for roughly 10% of observed changes in employment between routine and non-routine jobs

I

To exactly match observed polarization, needMM >20,000%of observed change.

I

Results may be sensitive to using prices vs. quantities and capital aggregation (see Eden and Gaggl (2018a, WP))

(19)

Findings: Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017, JME)

I

Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017) study polarization in generalized neoclassical production technology

I

Contrast: use movements in quantities of machines (MM) instead of prices (PPMM)

I

Quantitative exercises:

I estimateMM ≈1 I ξM=0.0845 I γr=1

I

=⇒account for roughly 10% of observed changes in employment between routine and non-routine jobs

I

To exactly match observed polarization, needMM >20,000%of observed change.

I

Results may be sensitive to using prices vs. quantities and capital aggregation (see Eden and Gaggl (2018a, WP))

(20)

Findings: Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017, JME)

I

Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017) study polarization in generalized neoclassical production technology

I

Contrast: use movements in quantities of machines (MM) instead of prices (PPMM)

I

Quantitative exercises:

I estimateMM ≈1

I ξM=0.0845 I γr=1

I

=⇒account for roughly 10% of observed changes in employment between routine and non-routine jobs

I

To exactly match observed polarization, needMM >20,000%of observed change.

I

Results may be sensitive to using prices vs. quantities and capital aggregation (see Eden and Gaggl (2018a, WP))

(21)

Findings: Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017, JME)

I

Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017) study polarization in generalized neoclassical production technology

I

Contrast: use movements in quantities of machines (MM) instead of prices (PPMM)

I

Quantitative exercises:

I estimateMM ≈1 I ξM=0.0845

I γr=1

I

=⇒account for roughly 10% of observed changes in employment between routine and non-routine jobs

I

To exactly match observed polarization, needMM >20,000%of observed change.

I

Results may be sensitive to using prices vs. quantities and capital aggregation (see Eden and Gaggl (2018a, WP))

(22)

Findings: Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017, JME)

I

Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017) study polarization in generalized neoclassical production technology

I

Contrast: use movements in quantities of machines (MM) instead of prices (PPMM)

I

Quantitative exercises:

I estimateMM ≈1 I ξM=0.0845 I γr=1

I

=⇒account for roughly 10% of observed changes in employment between routine and non-routine jobs

I

To exactly match observed polarization, needMM >20,000%of observed change.

I

Results may be sensitive to using prices vs. quantities and capital aggregation (see Eden and Gaggl (2018a, WP))

(23)

Findings: Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017, JME)

I

Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017) study polarization in generalized neoclassical production technology

I

Contrast: use movements in quantities of machines (MM) instead of prices (PPMM)

I

Quantitative exercises:

I estimateMM ≈1 I ξM=0.0845 I γr=1

I

=⇒account for roughly 10% of observed changes in employment between routine and non-routine jobs

I

To exactly match observed polarization, needMM >20,000%of observed change.

I

Results may be sensitive to using prices vs. quantities and capital aggregation (see Eden and Gaggl (2018a, WP))

(24)

Findings: Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017, JME)

I

Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017) study polarization in generalized neoclassical production technology

I

Contrast: use movements in quantities of machines (MM) instead of prices (PPMM)

I

Quantitative exercises:

I estimateMM ≈1 I ξM=0.0845 I γr=1

I

=⇒account for roughly 10% of observed changes in employment between routine and non-routine jobs

I

To exactly match observed polarization, needMM >20,000%of observed change.

I

Results may be sensitive to using prices vs. quantities and capital aggregation (see Eden and Gaggl (2018a, WP))

(25)

Findings: Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017, JME)

I

Cortes, Jaimovich and Siu (2017) study polarization in generalized neoclassical production technology

I

Contrast: use movements in quantities of machines (MM) instead of prices (PPMM)

I

Quantitative exercises:

I estimateMM ≈1 I ξM=0.0845 I γr=1

I

=⇒account for roughly 10% of observed changes in employment between routine and non-routine jobs

I

To exactly match observed polarization, needMM >20,000%of observed change.

I

Results may be sensitive to using prices vs. quantities and capital aggregation (see Eden and Gaggl (2018a, WP))

(26)

Findings: vom Lehn (2018a, WP)

I

vom Lehn (2018a) extends production to treat high-skill (abstract) and low-skill (manual) non-routine occupations separately:

Y=

µmL

γm1 γm

m + (1− µm)

µaL

γa1 γa

at + (1− µa)

 (1− µr)M

γr1 γr t + µrL

γr1 γr rt



γra1) r1a

γam1) a1m

γm γm1

I

MeasureξM using all equipment capital instead of just ICT; use investment price data to generate price of machines

I

To maximize fit of technology hypothesis, calibrate model to match polarization over subsample of the data (1980s)

I

General Equilibrium – consider both representative household and heterogeneous workers

(27)

Findings: vom Lehn (2018a, WP)

I

Even with favorable calibration, can’t match observed polarization and labor share behavior post-2000

1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015

Year -0.15

-0.1 -0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2

Change in Occ. Hours Shares (1982 Trend =0)

A: Model A: Data R: Model R: Data M: Model M: Data

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015

Year -0.08

-0.07 -0.06 -0.05 -0.04 -0.03 -0.02 -0.01 0 0.01 0.02

Change in Labor Share (1982 Trend=0) Data Model

I

Robust to labor supply, endogenous occupational and educational choices, calibration window, nesting structures, ICT instead of all equipment

I

Can fit data if fall in price of machines counterfactually actually ends in 2000

I

Key point: single set of elasticities of substitution can’t reconcile changing dynamics of polarization over time

(28)

Possible Resolutions

I

Other shocks (e.g. trade)

I

Changing relationship between technology and high-skill labor I due to role of skills in technology production/adoption I due to evolution of technological capabilities

(29)

Slowdown in Demand for Skills: Beaudry, Green and Sand (2016, JOLE)

I

Beaudry, Green and Sand (2016) find slowing employment growth in high skill jobs post-2000

I

Hypothesize: Slowing investment post-2000 (due to slowing fall in price of machines) means fewer high skill workers are needed to produce/install/adopt new technology

(30)

Quantitative Application (vom Lehn (2018a, WP))

I

Extending neoclassical framework to have high skill workers produce investment improves fit of technology hypothesis

1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015

Year -0.15

-0.1 -0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15

Change in Occ. Hours Shares (1982 Trend =0)

A: Model A: Data R: Model R: Data M: Model M: Data

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015

Year -0.08

-0.07 -0.06 -0.05 -0.04 -0.03 -0.02 -0.01 0 0.01 0.02

Change in Labor Share (1982 Trend=0)

Data Model: Abs Investment

I

Caveat: strong assumption about all investment produced by high skill workers

(31)

Evolution of Technology and Skills: vom Lehn (2018b, EER)

I

vom Lehn (2018b) studies cross-industry relationship between worker tasks and labor share declines

I

Construct measure of high-skill occupations most susceptible to automation –

“abstract replaceable”

I

OLS and IV evidence finds that industries with large fraction of abstract replaceable jobs in 2004 saw accelerated labor share declines post-2004

I

Suggestive evidence that technology may be evolving to replace some high-skill occupations

(32)

Conclusion

I

Both anecdotal and empirical evidence suggest that technology has substantially impacted labor markets

I

Understanding quantitative mechanisms for how technology impacts labor markets still a work in progress

I

Key aspect of future research is understanding the exact interaction of technology with higher skilled workers

(33)

References

Autor, D. H., Dorn, D., 2013. The growth of low-skill service jobs and the polarization of the us labor market. American Economic Review 103 (5), 1553–1597.

Beaudry, P., Green, D. A., Sand, B. M., 2016. The great reversal in the demand for skill and cognitive tasks. Journal of Labor Economics 34 (S1), S199–S247.

Cortes, G. M., Jaimovich, N., Siu, H. E., 2017. Disappearing routine jobs: Who, how, and why?

Journal of Monetary Economics 91, 69–87.

Eden, M., Gaggl, P., 2018a. The macroeconomic effects of automation: Does capital aggregation matter? Tech. rep., Working paper.

Eden, M., Gaggl, P., 2018b. On the welfare implications of automation. Review of Economic Dynamics 29, 15–43.

Goos, M., Manning, A., Salomons, A., 2014. Explaining job polarization: Routine-biased technological change and offshoring. American Economic Review 104 (8), 2509–2526.

Karabarbounis, L., Neiman, B., 2014. The global decline of the labor share. Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (1), 61–103.

Michaels, G., Natraj, A., Van Reenen, J., 2014. Has ict polarized skill demand?: Evidence from eleven countries over 25 years. Review of Economics and Statistics 96 (1), 60–77.

vom Lehn, C., 2018a. Labor market polarization, the decline of routine work, and technological change: A quantitative analysis. Tech. rep., Working paper, Brigham Young University.

vom Lehn, C., 2018b. Understanding the decline in the us labor share: Evidence from occupational tasks. European Economic Review 108, 191–220.

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

Source: Author’s calculations using Harris County District Clerk’s criminal court records (1980-2013), Harris County Sheriff’s county jail records (1980-2013), Texas Department

Sfruttando il feedback ricevuto dagli utenti, è stato deciso di non implementare l'opzione relativa alla tripartizione dei contenuti e di utilizzare grafiche diverse

One explanation may be that there was a much higher proportion of sub- jects < 65 years included in the first-line studies compared with second-line studies, which also reported

AD = autoimmune disease; BM = bone marrow; CTL = cytotoxic T lymphocyte; DC = dendritic cell; GvHD = graft versus host disease; IDO = indoleamine 2 ′,3′-dioxygenase; IFN =

Our model generates occupation earnings distributions which are right skewed, have firm fixed effects, and large changes in aggregate earnings inequality without significant

responsible for ensuring compliance with these regulations, such as maintaining their car in a way that conforms to company rules. This level of control highlights the

acquiring education non-working unemployed flexworker permanent employee Job-seekers seeking permanent positions: 24 months after start of the temporary employment phase

But they also suggest that these penalizations likely reflect stereotypes on lower productivity of women with children, since mothers, by the time the child starts school, do