• Non ci sono risultati.

The Rise and Fall of Polluter-Pays Principle in Developing Countries

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "The Rise and Fall of Polluter-Pays Principle in Developing Countries"

Copied!
10
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

ContentslistsavailableatSciVerseScienceDirect

International

Review

of

Law

and

Economics

The

rise

and

fall

of

the

polluter-pays

principle

in

developing

countries

Barbara

Luppi

a,∗

, Francesco

Parisi

b,c

, Shruti

Rajagopalan

d

aUniversityofModenaandReggioEmilia,DepartmentofEconomicsandCenterforEconomicResearch(RECENT),VialeBerengario41,Modena,Italy

bUniversityofMinnesotaLawSchool,UnitedStates

cUniversityofBologna,DepartmentofEconomics,Italy

dGeorgeMasonUniversity,DepartmentofEconomics,UnitedStates

a

r

t

i

c

l

e

i

n

f

o

Articlehistory:

Received7December2010

Receivedinrevisedform28August2011

Accepted17October2011 JELclassification: K13 K32 Q56 Keywords: Environmentalprotection Polluter-paysprinciple Stateliability

a

b

s

t

r

a

c

t

Thepolluter-paysprinciplestipulatesthatthepersonwhodamagestheenvironmentmustbearthecost ofsuchdamage.Anumberofdevelopingcountrieshaverecentlyextendedthisprincipletocreatean obli-gationonthestatetocompensatethevictimsofenvironmentalharm.Thisvariationofthepolluter-pays principleisaimedatensuringvictims’compensationwhenpolluterscannotbeidentifiedorareinsolvent andatprovidingstrongerincentivesforlocalgovernments’monitoringofenvironmentallyrisky activ-ities.Theseregimesholdlocalgovernmentsprimarilyorjointly-and-severallyliableforenvironmental damageandallowthemtoactinsubrogationagainstthepolluters.Inthispaperwestudytheeffectof theseformsofgovernmentalliabilityonthepolluters’incentivesandonaggregatelevelsof environmen-talharm.Wedevelopaneconomicmodeltostudytheconditionsunderwhichgovernmentalliability maybepreferabletodirectpolluters’liabilityasaninstrumentofenvironmentalprotection.We con-cludebysuggestingthatthesevariationsofthepolluter-paysregimemaybedesirableinenvironments characterizedbywidespreadpoverty,highinterestrates,judicialdelaysanduncertaintyinadjudication. © 2011 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction

Theideathatapollutershouldpayfortheenvironmentalharm

itcausesiswell-rootedinWesternlegalhistory.1Inpresenttimes,

thepolluter-paysprinciplestandsasaninternationalguidelinefor

environmentalpolicystipulatingthatthepersonorfirmwho

dam-agestheenvironmentmustbearthecostofsuchdamage.Since

anenvironmentalharmisoftenanexternality, liabilityinduces

theresponsiblepartytointernalizethefullsocialcostofhis

activ-ity,therebybringingtheenvironmentalharmdowntotheoptimal

level.Inthispaper,weshallconsiderarecenttrendobservedin

developing countries suchas India,Malaysia, Taiwan, Ecuador,

Chile,CostaRica,Kenya, and SouthAfrica, whoadopteda

vari-ation ofthepolluter-pays principlethrough judicial,legislative,

andconstitutionalreformsfocusedonmitigationofharmthrough

governmentalliability.Thesenewregimespurportedlyensure

vic-tims’ compensation when polluters cannot beidentified or are

∗ Correspondingauthor.

E-mailaddress:barbara.luppi@unimore.it(B.Luppi).

1AlreadyinacelebratedpassagebyPlatowefindastatementoftheprinciple

accordingtowhich:“Ifanyoneintentionallyspoilsthewaterofanother...lethim

notonlypaydamages,butpurifythestreamorcisternwhichcontainsthewater.”

TheDialoguesofPlato:TheLaws,vol.4,book8,section485(e),translatedbyJowett

B,Oxford:ClarendonPress(4thed.),1953.

insolvent. Reframing the original rationale of thepolluter-pays

principle,theseregimessuggestthattheprimaryaimisto

pro-videpromptcompensationtothevictimsofenvironmentalharm

andonlysecondarilytoimposeliabilityontheresponsible

par-ties.Inthelastfewdecadesseverallegalsystemshaverecognized

a primary obligation onlocal and central governments to

pro-videpromptreliefandcompensationtovictimsofenvironmental

harm.Werefertothisreinterpretationofthepolluter-paysregime

asthegovernment-paysregime.Localgovernments haveproven

quiteresponsivetothethreatofdirectliabilityandhaveboosted

theirmonitoringofenvironmentally-riskyactivitiestoavoidthe

financialandpoliticaldisruptionassociatedwithanenvironmental

accident.

Thispaperisstructuredasfollows.InSection2weprovidea

briefhistoryofthepolluter-paysprincipleanditsrecent

reinter-pretationandtransformation,withspecialreferencetothecase

ofIndiaandotherdevelopingcountries.InSection3wedevelopa

modeltoconsidertheincentivesystemcreatedbyaregimeofdirect

governmentalliabilityonprospectiveinjurersandtoevaluatethe

effectsofthisregimeonaggregatelevelsofenvironmentalharm.

WedevelopaStackelberg-typegamewheregovernmentschoose

theirlevelsofpreventivemonitoringeffortandfirmschoosetheir

levelofcareinresponsetothegovernment’saction.Wecompare

thegovernment’smonitoringlevelsandthefirms’carelevelsunder

thealternativepolluter-paysandthegovernment-paysregimes.

Weconsideralternativegovernmentalobjectivefunctionstoallow

0144-8188/$–seefrontmatter © 2011 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

(2)

forbothbenevolentwelfare-maximizinggovernmentsand

shirk-ingcost-minimizinggovernments.InSection4,wecomparethe

polluter-paysandthegovernment-paysregimesinthepresence

oflegalandenforcementimperfections.Weconsiderthewelfare

propertiesofthegovernment-paysregime,comparingitseffectsto

thosethatwouldbeinducedbyabenevolent,welfare-maximizing

government.Section5considersthecomparativeadvantageofthe

tworegimesaseffectiveinstrumentsofenvironmentalprotection.

Section6concludeswithsomepolicyconsiderations.

2. Theriseandfallofthepolluter-paysprinciple

Academicshavelongrecommendedadoptionofthe

polluter-paysprinciplewhich wasthebasisof formalrecommendations

oftheOrganizationforEconomicCooperationandDevelopment

(OECD)sincetheearly1970s.2TheextensiveworkoftheOECDover

thesubsequenttwodecadeswasresponsibleformetamorphosing

thiseconomicprincipleintoanestablishedlegalprinciple(OECD,

1992:9).Thepolluter-paysprinciplewasformallyadoptedbythe

EuropeUnionintheSingleEuropeanActof1987,3andin1992was

recognizedbytheUnitedNationsConferenceontheEnvironment

andDevelopmentdelegates(so-calledRioDeclaration).4

Theimplementationofthepolluter-paysprinciplebysovereign

states has enjoyed different incarnations in national legal

sys-tems(Finn,1975).Insomesituations,thepolluter-paysprincipleis

implementedbystategovernmentsthroughdirectregulationthat

createseconomicincentives,leadingthepollutertobearthecostof

theenvironmentalharmcausedbyitsactivitythroughregulation

thatimposesdirectenvironmentalliabilityonthepollutingagents.

Inthecontextofenvironmentalliability,overthelastfewdecades

internationalandnationalenvironmentalliabilitylawshavebeen

invariablybasedonstrictliability(CommissionoftheEuropean

Communities,1993).Theproponentsofthestrictliabilityrulealso

focuson“costinternalization,”whichrequireschargingapolluter

forthesocialcost ofanactivity.5 Furthermore,liabilityensures

thatthepriceofcommoditiesreflectstheharmcausedby

non-negligentpollutingactivities,resultinginamoreefficientallocation

ofresources(Krier&Stewart,1978).Underthenegligencerule,

non-negligentharmisnotinternalized,andtherecould,therefore,

beexcessiveentryoffirms,resultinginanincreaseinthe

probabil-ityofpollutionand/orenvironmentaldamage(Polinsky,1980).6It

2 The Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD)

expressestheeconomicfunctionofthepolluter-paysprincipleasforcing“prices

ofgoods(dependingonthequalityand/orquantityofenvironmentalresources)

toreflect,moreclosely,theirrelativescarcityandthateconomicagentsconcerned

reactaccordingly”(OECD,1972;OECD,1974).

3 SingleEuropeanAct,17February1986,1987O.J.(L169).Article174(2)ofthe

consolidatedversionsoftheTreatyonEuropeanUnionandoftheTreatyEstablishing

theEuropeanUnion,2002O.J.(C325)1providesthat:“Unionpolicyonthe

envi-ronmentshallaimatahighlevelofprotectiontakingintoaccountthediversityof

situationsinthevariousregionsoftheUnion.Itshallbebasedontheprecautionary

principleandontheprinciplesthatpreventiveactionshouldbetaken,that

envi-ronmentaldamageshouldasapriorityberectifiedatsourceandthatthepolluter

shouldpay.”

4 Principle16oftheRioDeclarationprovidesthat:“[n]ationalauthoritiesshould

endeavourtopromotetheinternalizationofenvironmentalcostsandtheuseof

economicinstruments,takingintoaccounttheapproachthatthepollutershould,

inprinciple,bearthecostofpollution.”

5 Thisisconsistentwiththeeconomicrationaleofthepolluter-paysprinciple,

whichmandatesthecost-internalizationprinciple(Bergkamp,2001).SeealsoOtt

andSchäfer(1996,2004).

6 Theeconomicrationaleforthisisthatstrictliabilityisapreferablerulein

sit-uationsofunilateralcareandwhereonlytheinjurercantakeeffectiveprecautions

topreventtheharm.Further,whilebothstrictliabilityandnegligencerulesinduce

theinjurertotaketheoptimalamountofcare,theadvantageofstrictliabilityin

environmentalcasesisthatonlytheharmmustbeobservable.Thelevelofcareis

irrelevantandthereforeneednotbeestablishedinacourtoflaw,therebyreducing

evidentiaryrequirements.Theotherreasonfortheincreaseduseofstrictliability

shouldbenotedthat,whileitistruethatmanycountriesembracea

strictpolluter-paysprinciplewithrespecttoprohibitedemissions,

severalcountriescontinuetotreatpermittedpollutionaslargely

free.7

2.1. Recentdeparturesfromthepolluter-paysprinciple

Incasesofenvironmentalpollutionanddegradationin

devel-opingcountries,adifferentvariationofthepolluter-paysprinciple

emergedfocusedprimarilyontheneedtoprovideimmediate

com-pensationtovictimsofenvironmentalharm.8Throughlegislation

andjudicial precedents,a number ofcountrieshavecreatedan

obligationonlocalgovernmentstoprovidedirectandprompt

com-pensationtothevictimsofenvironmentalharm.9 Thesejudicial

andlegislativereinterpretationsofthepolluter-paysprinciplehold

statesandlocalgovernmentsjointly-and-severallyliableforthe

environmentaldamagecausedbyprivateparties,allowingthese

publicbodiestoactinsubrogationagainsttheindividualpolluters

when possible. Thisvariant of thepolluter-pays principle

gen-erally seesa primary rolefor localand central governmentsto

providecompensationtovictimsofenvironmentalharm.This

vir-tuallysubvertsthelogicoftheprinciple bysuggestingthatthe

primarygoalis toprovideprompt compensationtothevictims

ofenvironmentalharm,andonlysecondarilytotransfertheloss

throughsubrogationontheresponsibleparties.Thisquite

dras-ticshiftawayfromthestrictliabilityregimeofthepolluter-pays

principleismotivatedbytheneedtocreatedirectmonetary

incen-tivesonlocalenvironmentalagenciesaugmentingtheirincentives

toengageinmonitoringofactivitiesthatcreatepotentialriskforthe

environment.

Thewisdomofthesereformsliesintheideathatlocal

govern-mentsrespondparticularlytothreatsoflitigationandpossessthe

necessaryadministrativeandlegalinstrumentsfortheeffective

monitoringofprospectivepolluters.Fiscalrevenuesheavily

con-strainthebudgetsoftheselocalgovernmentsandenvironmental

agenciesand,ifheldliablefor thedirectcompensationof

envi-ronmentalharm,theseentitiesfaceapossiblydisruptiveshortfall

withbothpoliticalandfinancialconsequences.Unlikeinsurance

companies, local governments transmit the care incentives to

potentialpolluters,notonlythroughthethreatofsubrogation,but

alsothroughseveralotheradministrativeinstruments(permits,

safety and emission controls, site inspections, etc.) and legal

inenvironmentprotection,especiallyinanagewhereallgovernmentsaretrying

tocurbindustrialpollution,isthatinamarketsetting,negligencemayprove

ineffi-cientcomparedtostrictliability,inasmuchasitdoesnotcreateadequateincentives

toreduceactivitylevelsandtoinvestinresearchanddevelopmentofnewcleaner

technology.

7MemberstatesoftheEUarestillfarfromshiftingtheentirecostof

environ-mentaldegradationonpollutingfirms.Forexample,withthepossibleexceptionof

Sweden,memberstateshavenotdevelopedacomprehensivesetoffeeson

per-mitteddischarges.Thepolluter-paysprinciple,therefore,onlyappliesuniformly

acrosstheEUtoimplythatallprohibitedandharmfuldischargeshouldbepaidfor.

Theextenttowhichthecostofpermittedpollutionistransferredontoactual

pol-lutersinsteadvariesacrossmemberstates.Thisisinmanywaysshortofwhatafull

implementationofthepolluter-paysprinciplewouldrequire(Faure,2009).

8Pigouviantaxationinstruments,involvingadirecttaxoneveryunitofpollution

oroneveryunitproducedbythepollutingactivity,havealsobeenconsideredas

alternativeimplementationsofthepolluter-paysprinciple.Athirdwayinwhich

thepolluter-paysprinciplehasbeeninterpretedandimplementedbynational

gov-ernmentsisthroughtheadoptionofmarket-basedinstruments,suchaspollution

permitsandbubble-typepollutionallowances.Inyetothersituations,government

interpretsthepolluter-paysprinciplebroadlyandimplementitthrough

command-and-controlmeasureswhereinthegovernmentmayspecificallyprohibitcertain

environmentallydangerousactivitiesordisallowcertainproducts,methods,or

sci-entifictechniques.

9Faure,Goodwin,&Weber(2010)pointouttheimportanceofoptimaldesignof

environmentallawindevelopingcountry,rathertoimportNorthernregulation,in

(3)

threats(fines,revocationandsuspensionoflicenses,etc.).10These

instrumentscanmakethemonitoringactivityoflocalgovernments

particularlyeffective.

2.2. Fromthepolluter-paystothegovernment-paysprinciple:

thecaseofIndia

Indiahasundertakenatranformativeapproachto

environmen-talprotectioninrecentyears,atboththeregulatoryandjudicial

level(Faureetal.,2010).11Recentdevelopmentsinenvironmental

protectioninIndiaexamplifyareinterpretingofthepolluter-pays

principlein themethoddiscussed above(Jaswal,2008).12 India

recentlyadoptedasystemofdirectgovernmentalliability

requir-ingthestatetopaydamagestothevictimofenvironmentalharm

andallowingthegovernmenttorecoveritsdisbursementsfrom

thepolluteratalatertimethroughanactionforsubrogation.13

TheStockholmDeclarationin1972providedatouchstonefor

Indian environmental legislation. India agreed with 113 other

nations on principles and plannedto protect the environment

resultinginanobligationtoimplementthesedomestically.Inthe

fulfillmentoftheobligationsarisingfromtheStockholm

Declara-tion,Indiawitnessedaproliferationofenvironmentallawsand

reg-ulations.Inkeepingwithinternationalstandards,theIndian

gov-ernmentenactedlegislationforenvironmentalprotection,water

pollution,airpollution,andwildlifeconservation.Mostnotably,the

implementationoftheStockholmDeclarationledtothe

amend-ment of the Indian Constitution,14 which incorporated Articles

48A15 and Article51A(g).16 Onthebasisof theseconstitutional

provisions,theIndianParliamentenactedtheWaterAct,1974,the

AirAct,1981,andtheEnvironmentalProtectionAct,1986(Krishna

Kumari,2007).Inconjunctionwiththeseregulations,Indiacreated

specializedauthoritieswithagrantofwidepowersincluding

clo-sureofindustriesandthepowertogiveanydirectionstoprotect

theenvironment.17Yettheseauthoritiessufferfromadministrative

failuressimilartothoseplaguingtherestoftheIndianbureaucracy

andexecutive.CitiesandriversinIndia,inparticular,underwent

unprecedenteddegradation.Withrisingenvironmental

degrada-tion,theincreasinglyactivistIndianjudiciarybegantotakegreater

noteofthesestandards,creatinganobligationonstate

govern-mentstoprovidecompensationtothevictimsofenvironmental

harmthathasnotbeensuccessfullypreventedbytheproactive

precautionarymeasuresofthespecializedauthorities.

The Indian judiciary took special interest in this matter on

counts of social justice, since most of the victims of such

10SeealsoNash(2000),Schäfer(2000)andGuelton(2002).

11 SeealsoOECD(1972,1974,1989,1992)andBabu,Eger,Raja,Schäfer,and Somashekhar(2010).

12 Furtheranalysisofthevariouslegislationandenvironmentalcasescanbefound

inJaswal(2008),whichhasprovidedacomprehensivesourceofinformationfor

thissection.TheWorldBankhaspredictedthatIndia’swater,air,soil,andforest

resourceswillbeundermorehumanpressurethanthoseofanyothercountryby

theyear2020.

13 FaureandRaja(2010)discussontheeffectivenessofenvironmental

regula-tioninIndia,withspecialreferencetopublicinterestlitigation.SeealsoCraigand

Deshpande(1989),Prasad(2004)andRajaandRathinam(2005).

14 SeeBakshi(2005)andJain(2005)forstudiesontheIndianConstitution.

15 Article48AisaDirectivePrincipleguidingthestateforthe“protectionand

improvementofenvironmentandsafeguardingofforestsandwildlife.”

16 Article51A(g)isaFundamentalDutyforthecitizensofIndiato“protectand

improvethenaturalenvironment.”

17 TheCentralPollutionControlBoard(CPCB)andStatePollutionControlBoards

(SPCBs)wereinitiallysetupundertheprovisionsoftheWaterAct,1974,andnow

alsocarryouttheirfunctionsundertheAirAct,1981.TheCPCBandtheSPCBsalso

performalladditionalfunctionsundertheEnvironmentalProtectionActandare

theprimeenvironmentalauthoritiesinIndia.Theyaresupportedbytherelevant

authoritiesforthesupervisionofcoastalzoneregulations:theNationalCoastalZone

ManagementAuthorityandStateCoastalZoneManagementAuthorities.

environmentaldegradation had nopossible meansof

individu-allysuingthepolluters toenforcethepolluter-paysprinciple.18

In several instances, the Supreme Court issued orders to the

relevantmunicipalauthority toconstitutemechanismstoclean

environmentaldamageandcompensatevictimsofpollution,

giv-ing the municipal authority an option to act in subrogation

against the responsibleparties. Evenwhen an action was

suc-cessfully brought against the polluting firm, it was established

that the government would remain liable to pay for residual

shortfalls.19

Asaresultofthesedevelopments,stateauthoritiesnowplay

amuchlargerrole.Thestateisnowinvolvedinall

environmen-talmatters,fromcreatingtheappropriateauthoritytocleanthe

environmentpollution,toactuallysteppinginforthepolluterand

payingdamages.Manylaudthismodelofgovernmentalliabilityfor

environmentalharm(thegovernment-paysregime)asthesavior

ofIndia’secology.

2.3. Theadoptionofthegovernment-paysprincipleinother

developingcountries

Similar incarnations of the government-pays principle have

beenobservedinahandfulofotherdevelopingcountries,especially

whereongoingeconomicdevelopmentputsseverepressureonthe

environment.CountrieslikeMalaysia,Taiwan,Ecuador,Chile,Costa

Rica,SouthAfrica,andKenyaadoptedremediesfocusedon

miti-gationoftheharmthroughgovernmentalliability.Thesesystems

carriedoutreformsthroughjudicial,legislativeandconstitutional

intervention,toensurevictims’compensationwhenpolluters

can-notbeidentifiedorareinsolvent.

SimilartothecaseofIndia,theseregimessubvertedtheoriginal

rationaleofthepolluter-paysprinciple,imposingongovernments

and localagenciestheobligationtoprovideprompt

compensa-tiontothevictimsofenvironmentalharm,andonlysecondarily

torecovercostsfromtheresponsibleparties.

Withinthiscontext,inthelastfewdecadesTaiwanwitnessed

much citizen activism leading tothe recognitionof a principle

which entitlesvictimstoreceive governmentcompensationfor

pollution.The1986protestagainstpollutionbyDuPontandthe

1988protestagainsttheLunyuanIndustrialZonecausinglivestock

deathsduetopollutionspurredthegovernmentintoaction.The

latterofthetwocausestookproteststotheextentofviolenceand

thegovernmentcompensatedthevictimsbyproviding$10million.

Insubsequentyears,protestersralliedagainstTaipowerandChina

PetroleumCompany,leadingtoasettlementofupto$250million

(Chen,1994).

AnotherinterestingexamplecomesfromtheMalaysian

Envi-ronmentalQualityAct.TheDirectorGeneralofMalaysiahaspowers

verysimilartohisIndiancounterpart.UnderSection47(1)ofthe

Environmental QualityAct,theDirectorGeneralmaytakesuch

actionnecessarytoremove,disperse,destroyormitigatethe

pol-lutionandmayrecoverfromthepolluterallcostsandexpenses

incurredinconnectiontherewith(Mustafa,1991).

18AlthoughIndianlawrecognizesaclasssuitorarepresentativesuit,whereinone

ormoremembersofaclasshavingthesameinterestmaysueordefendonbehalf

ofthemselvesandalltheothermembersoftheclass(Order1Rule8oftheCivil

ProcedureCodeof1908),fewcasesusedtheseactionsandwithlittlesuccessand

werenotregardedasaviablesolutiontotheproblemathand.

19Forexample,intheBhopalGasTragedy,afterfiveyearsoflitigation,an

out-of-courtsettlementwasreachedbetweenthepollutingcompany,UnionCarbide,and

theGovernmentofIndia.TheSupremeCourtheldthatifthesettlementfundthat

hadbeennegotiatedwasexhausted,theGovernmentofIndiashouldmakegood

thedeficiencyforallthepast,presentandfutureclaimsarisingfromthegasleak.

BhopalGasLeakDisaster(ProcessingofClaims)Act,1985.UnionCarbideCorporation

(4)

SouthAfricaand Kenyaexemplify twosimilardevelopments

fromthe African continent (Bruch, Coker, & VanArsdale, 2001;

Mustafa, 1991; Rabie, 1991). In the late 1980s South Africa

witnessedashifttowardsgovernmentcompensationfor

environ-mentalharmcausedbyprivateinjurers,whichledtolegislative

intervention.Section19oftheEnvironmentalConservationAct73

of1989empowersthegovernmenttotakethenecessarystepsto

repairthedamageandtorecoverthecostfromthepolluterforits

failuretotakeadequatemeasures(Rabie,1991).20Followingthe

footstepsofSouth Africa,in2002Kenya drafteda provisionfor

citizenredressagainstpollutionfromtheHighCourtinitsDraft

Constitution.Ifpassed,thisprovisionwouldempowercitizensto

directlyapproachthecourttoenforcetherighttoaclean

environ-ment(muchlikethejudicialinterpretationreadintoArticle21of

theIndianConstitution).Theprovisiongivesextensivepowersto

thecourttocompelthegovernmentoranypublicagencytotake

restorativemeasuresandtoprovidecompensationforanyvictim

ofpollutionandtocompensatethecostbornebyvictimsforthe

lostuseofnaturalresourcesasaresultofanactofpollution.21

Wealsoobservesimilardevelopmentsthroughlegislativeand

judicial intervention in South American countries. In the

Fun-daciónNaturacontraPetroEcuadorcase,anEcuadoriancourt,when

approachedbyanenvironmentalactivistNGO,orderedthestate

agency to assess the damage and to compensate the

commu-nity,holdingthat thestatecould suethecorporation oncethe

assessmentwascompleted.22InChile,theFrameworkLaw

con-tainsprovisionsforcitizen-suitstoredressenvironmentalharm.

The law allows individuals to commence legal actions against

localgovernmentstorecoverforenvironmentaldamages(Sullivan,

1996).Itprovidesthatvictimsofenvironmentalharmmayrequire

themunicipalityinwhichtheactivitydamagingtheenvironment

occurredtoactontheirbehalf,holdingthemunicipalityjointlyand

severallyliablefortheenvironmentaldamagewhichthepetitioner

hassufferedincaseofgovernmentinaction.23SimilarlyCostaRica

penalizesgovernmentinactionthroughtheOrganic Lawforthe

Environment(1995).Itgivestheauthoritythepowertoissue

warn-ings,admonitions,restrictionofanydamagingactivity,partialor

totalclosingorfacilities,partialortotalcancellation ofpermits,

patents,certificationofincorporationincaseofnonfulfillmentof

theauthority’sorders.Thelawgoesastepfurtherandprovidesthe

abovesanctionsforgovernmentofficialswhoviolatethelawsand

regulationsforactionoromission(Santos,1996).24

20 Section19and20EnvironmentalConservationAct73of1989.

21 Article241,Chapter12,DraftConstitutionoftheRepublicofKenya2002.

22 FundaciónNaturacontraPetroEcuadordelaProvinciadeBuenosAires,Expediente

No.221-98-RACorteConstitucionaldeEcuador,1998),upholdingFundaciónNatura

contraPetroEcuador,ExpedienteNo1314(Juzgadodecimoprimerodelocivilde

Pichincga,April15,1998).

23 FrameworkLaw,Tit.III,Art.54.

24 Althoughthetrendtowardsthegovernment-paysregimeisafrequent

phe-nomenonin developingcountries, someindustrialized countriesalso provide

scatteredexamplesofstatefundsforenvironmentalprotection,mostnotablyin

theUnitedStates,JapanandFrance(Cole,1991;Lin,2005).Thesepiecesof

regu-lationareratherexceptionalinnatureand,asnotedbelow,representvariations

ofthepolluter-paysprinciple,ratherthananembodimentofthegovernment-pays

principleobservedindevelopingcountries.IntheUnitedStates,the

Comprehen-siveEnvironmentalResponse,Compensation,andLiabilityActof1980,(CERCLA)

isthemainfederallawoftheUnitedStatesthataddressestheclean-upof

haz-ardoussubstances.TheSuperfundcreatedundertheActintendedtopayforthe

cleanupofhazardous-wastedumpsitesandspills,financedbyacombinationof

generalrevenuesandtaxesonpollutingindustries.TheEnvironmentalProtection

Agencywasdirectedtocreatealistofthemostdangeroussites;itwouldthen

compelthepollutertopayforthecleanuporwouldpayforthecleanupitself

throughtheSuperfundandsueforreimbursement.Precedingthissweeping

leg-islationwastheDeepwaterPortActof1974whichheldtheownersandoperators

ofvesselsstrictlyliablefordamagescaused.HowevertheDeepwaterPortLiability

Fundwascreatedtobeliablefordamagesandthecostofcleaningtheenvironment

whensuchclean-upwasnotcompensatedbytheprivatepolluter.In1973,France

InSection3,wewillanalyzetheincentivesystemcreatedby

thisregimeofgovernmentalliabilityforprospectiveinjurersand

itseffectontheaggregatelevelofenvironmentalharm.

3. Modelinggovernment’sandpolluters’incentives

Inthissection,wepresentaformalmodeltocomparethe

incen-tiveand welfareeffectsoftheenvironmentalliabilityprinciples

consideredabove.InSections3.1and3.2,wewillidentifysomeof

thebasicfeaturesofthisregimewithrespecttogovernment’sand

polluters’incentives.

Under eachenvironmentalprinciple,thegovernmenthasan

incentivetomonitorexantetheenvironmentallydangerous

activ-ities of private individuals and firms. Individual firms have an

incentivetoundertakecarein ordertominimizethelikelihood

ofanaccident.WedevelopaStackelberg-typegamewhere

gov-ernmentschoosetheirlevelsofpreventivemonitoringeffortinthe

firststageandfirmschoosetheirlevelofcareinthesecondstage

ofthegame.Parties(governmentandpolluters)areassumedtobe

riskneutral,rational,andutilitymaximizing.

Inthefollowingwecharacterizetheoptimalmonitoringlevel

of thegovernment and the optimalcare level of an individual

firmunderthealternativepolluter-paysandthegovernment-pays

regimes. We describe the effects of the polluter-pays and the

government-paysregimes,identifyingtheconditionsunderwhich

oneortheotherisamoreeffectiveinstrumentofenvironmental

protection.25

3.1. StartingfromStage2:thecarechoiceofprospectivepolluters

We assume that the principal’s (government) best strategy

incorporates the agent’s (prospective polluter) best reactionto

thegovernment’saction.Using backwardinduction,westartby

identifyingtheagent’s choice.Theagentcarriesoutan activity,

withafixedvalueV,26thatmaycauseenvironmentalharm.The

agentcaninvestincaretoreducetheprobabilityof

environmen-talharm.Denotewithxtheagent’slevelofcare,wherex∈[0,∞(.

Withalevelofcarex,environmentaldamageoccurswith

proba-bilityp(x),wherep(x)∈(0,1).Weassumeunilateralcare,suchthat

theprobabilityoftheenvironmentaldamagecanonlybe

effec-tivelycontrolledbythepolluter’slevelofcare.Thegovernment

canaffectthepolluter’slevelofcarethroughmonitoringbut

can-notdirectlyreducetheenvironmentalriskbytakingprecautions

onitsown.Likewise,thevictimsbeartheharmwithoutbeingable

toreducetheprobabilityofitsoccurrencewiththeirown

precau-tions.Weassumethattheagent’scaredecreasestheprobabilityof

environmentaldamage,px<0,atadecreasingrate,pxx>0.When

allocatedenvironmentaldamagefundstocontrollingnoisepollution.InJapan,the

1967BasicLawforEnvironmentalPollutionControlisthebedrockforallthe

legisla-tionthatfollowedtoprotectboththeenvironmentandpollutionvictims.Inkeeping

withtheEuropeantrendstheJapanesegovernmentenactedlawstoprotectairand

water,regulatetheproductionofchemicalsubstances,andconserveandprotect

thenaturalsurroundings.TheJapanesegovernmentcreatedtwotypesof

compen-sationstructuresundertheLawfortheCompensationofPollution-RelatedHealth

Injuries.Thefirstfollowsthepolluter-paysprincipleandmandatesthatvictimsbe

compensatedbytheprivateinjurer.Andasecondcategoryofvictimsarethose

whoseinjuriescannotbetracedtospecificpollutersandarecompensatedbythe

Pollution-RelatedHealthDamageCompensationAssociation,financedbypollution

levies(Gresser,Fujikura,&Morishima,1981).Thecompensationsystemadoptedin

Japanusestaxescollectedfromemissionstopaycompensationtovictims,hence

representingaPigouvian-taxvariationofthepolluter-paysprinciple,ratherthanan

applicationofthegovernment-paysregime.

25Forarecentanalysisofthetradeoffbetweendirectandindirectincentivesin

thecontextofstateliability,seeDari-Mattiacci,Garoupa,andGomez-Pomar(2010).

26Theassumptionofafixedlevelofactivityincreasesanalyticaltractabilityand

resultsdonotdependonthisassumption.Resultswithavariableactivitylevelare

(5)

environmentaldamageoccurs,anexogenouslossdenotedbyLis

created,whereL>0.Inthesimpleeconomyconsideredhere,there

aretwotypesofagents(potentialpolluters),i=R,P.Richagents,R,

arecharacterizedbythefactthattheyhavealevelofwealthAR

suf-ficienttocompensatefortheenvironmentalharmLcausedbytheir

activity.Pooragents,P,havealowerlevelofwealth,denotedbyAP,

whereAP<L.Itfollowsthatinthisframework,thedamagespaidby

atype-RagentequalthelossL,sinceAR≥L,whilearepresentative

type-PagentwillpaydamagesequalatmosttohiswealthlevelAP,

sinceAP<D.Weshallrefertoiastheproportionoftype-iagents

inthepopulation,i=R,P.27

Eachprospectivepolluterchoosesthelevelofcaretominimize

theexpectedcostofliabilityandprecautioncosts.28Additionally,

thegovernmentcanengageinmonitoringofthefirms’activities

throughexantesafetycontrolsandsanctionsthatimposeacost

onfirmsthatdeviatefromthesociallyoptimallevelofcare.The

governmentisassumedtoimposeaperunitcostondeviatingfirms,

equaltom(e).

Theobjectivefunctionforaprospectivepolluteriis:

min{xi}p(xi)Di+xi+m(e)(x∗∗−xi) (1)

Proposition1. Theprivatelyoptimallevelofcarechosenbytype-P

agentsislowerthanthelevelofcarechosenbytype-Ragents:x∗P≤x∗R.

Type-Ragentsexertthesociallyoptimallevelofeffort.

Proof:SeeAppendixA.

Thisresultshouldnotbesurprising.Thelimitedwealthoftype-P

agentsreducestheirexpectedliability,hencediminishingthe

(pri-vate)marginalbenefitofcare.Type-Pagentswill,therefore,havea

lowerincentivetoinvestincare(Dari-Mattiacci&DeGeest,2005;

Shavell,1986,1987).Onthecontrary,fullyliableagentswillexert

thesociallyoptimallevelofcare.

3.2. Stage1:themonitoringdecisionofthegovernment

Havingidentifiedthebestreactionofprospectivepolluters,we

canidentifythegovernment’sbestmonitoringstrategythrough

backwardinduction.Wedosobyconsideringthegovernment’s

decision under the polluter-pays regime and the

government-pays regime. When investing to contain environmental harm

through monitoring, the government faces a monitoring cost,

whichdependsontheeffortlevel,e∈[0,∞(.Thiseffortlevelshould

be thought as the incremental monitoring effort of local

gov-ernmentsandenvironmentalagenciesinresponsetotheriskof

environmentalharmandthethreatofdirectliability.29

Thegovernmenthasinformationonthefinancialwealth,Ai,i=R,

P,oftheagentsandcanundertakedifferentmonitoringlevelsfor

thetwotypesofagents.Themonitoringexpenditureequalsthe

totalmonitoringeffortexertedonrichandpooragents,whereei

denotestheeffortperindividualtypeofagent,i=R,Pand␥idenotes

thefractionofthepopulationoftypei,i=R,P.

3.2.1. Benevolentgovernment

Theobjectivefunctionofabenevolentgovernmentisto

mini-mizetheexpectedenvironmentalloss,themonitoringcostandthe

carecostsofeachtypeofagent.

min(e

i)i=R,Pp(xi)iL+



i=R;P

i(c(ei)+xi) (2)

27 Withoutlossofgenerality,thesizeofthepopulationisnormalizedtooneand

R+P=1.

28 Thisisequivalenttotheproblemofmaximizingtheagent’sobjectivefunction

equaltothevalueofactivitynetoftheexpectedliabilityandprecautioncosts,due

totheassumptionoffixedactivitylevel.

29 Thisiscompatiblewithafixedmonitoringleveloneachtypeofagent.

Proposition2. Abenevolentgovernmentundertakesahigherlevel

ofmonitoringfortype-Pagentsthanfortype-Ragents:eSO

P >eSOR .The

levelofcarechosenbytype-Pagents,however,islowerthanthelevel

ofcarechosenbytype-Ragents:xSO

P <xSOR .

Proof:SeeAppendixA.

3.2.2. Introducingimperfectgovernments:therelevanceoflegal

regimes

When the incentives of government officials misalign with

thoseofthecommunity,thegovernmentmayexperienceagency

problems.Inchoosingtheircourseofaction,governmentofficials

maynot perfectlyinternalizethesocial losscaused bya

pollu-tionaccident, equal toL.Giventheimperfectinternalizationof

theaccidentloss,thegovernment’smonitoringeffortwillbe

sub-optimal.Theintroductionofgovernmentalliabilityremediescan

correctthedilutionofincentivescausedbyagencyproblems.Under

agovernment-paysregime,government’s monitoringlevelswill

reflecttheresiduallossborne bygovernments unabletocollect

damagesfrominsolventordisappearingpolluters, L−AP.Under

a government-paysregime, thewelfarefunctionof the

govern-mentisequaltothesumofaweightedaverageofthesocialloss

(weightedby˛)andthegovernmentfinancialloss(weightedbyˇ)

andthemonitoringandcarecosts.Analytically,thewelfare

func-tionofthegovernmenttakesthefollowingform:

min(e

i)i=R,Pp(xi)i[˛L+ˇ(L−min{L,Ai})]+



i=R,P

i(c(ei)+xi) (3)

Agency problems in governmental action are present when

˛≤1.Thewelfarefunctioncollapsestotheoneofabenevolent

governmentwhen˛=1andˇ=0.Wecannowstudythe

monitor-ingincentivescreatedbytheapplicationofthegovernment-pays

regimeonthetwotypesofagentsconsideredabove.

AsdiscussedinSection2,inagovernment-paysregime,allcases

ofenvironmentaltortsandenvironmentalaccidentscanbeeither

filedthrough publicinterestlitigationdirectlyagainststateand

localgovernmentsorbroughtagainstthesegovernmentalbodies

throughjoint-and-severalliabilityactionsintorts.30Ineithercase,

thedeterminedamountofdamageswillbepaidbythestatetothe

victims.Thestatehasanopportunitytoactinsubrogationagainst

theactualpolluterstorecoverdamagespaidtothevictimsandthe

costofenvironmentalrestoration.

Intheseregimesofgovernmentalliability,primaryliabilityfor

environmentaldamage caused byprivate firmsand individuals

fallsonthestateand localgovernments. We assumethat local

governmentsandenvironmentalagenciesareconstrainedby

fis-calrevenuesandrespondtothethreatofprimaryliability,which

wouldcausefinancialdisruptionwithpoliticalandelectoral

con-sequences.

Underthegovernment-paysprinciple,weassumethatthe

gov-ernment’srightofsubrogationtransfersthelosstotheresponsible

partyonlytosolventparties,butleavesthelossonthe

govern-mentincaseofinsolvency.Underthegovernment-paysprinciple,

weassumeˇ≥1,i.e.thegovernmentfullyinternalizestheportion

ofthedamagecompensationpaidouttoenvironmentalvictims

andfacescostforadministeringsuchfunds,sincethegovernment

bearsnotonlytheportionofthelossunrecoverablefrom

insol-ventparties butalsolegalandadministrativecosts.Weassume

thatunderthepolluter-paysprincipal,thegovernmentdoesnot

fullyinternalizethevictims’loss(ˇ<1),whenthevictimremains

uncompensatedduetoinsolvency.

30InthecaseofenvironmentalprotectioninIndia,thisinvolvesfilingawrit

(6)

Proposition3. Theintroductionofgovernmentalliabilityleadstoan

increaseofthemonitoringoftype-Pagents.Themonitoringexherted

ontype-Ragentsisnotaffectedbythechoiceoflegalregime.

Proof:SeeAppendixA.

Proposition4. Themonitoringexhertedontype-Pagentsunderthe

government-paysregimemayexceedthelevelchosenbyabenevolent

government,i.e.e∗P>eSO

P ,forsufficientlyhigh˛andˇ.

Corollary. In agovernment-pays regime, type-P[type-R]agents

undertakeahigher[lower]levelofcarethanwhatwouldbechosen

whenmonitoringiscarriedoutbyabenevolentgovernment:xSO

R >x∗R

andxSO

P <xP∗forsufficientlyhigh˛andˇ.

Proof:SeeAppendixA.

The government-pays regime may trigger an overshooting

of monitoring incentives with respect to type-P agents. This

overshootingeffectresultsfromthefactthatthegovernment

inter-nalizesthebenefitofitsmonitoringbutdoesnotfullyinternalize

aportion(equalto1− ˛)ofsociallossLandthehigher

precau-tioncoststhatagentsface.7).Weobserveexcessivemonitoringof

type-Pagentsinanumberofsituations.Forexample,thisoccurs

wheneverthegovernmentweighsconsistentlymoreitslossthan

thesocialloss(i.e.ˇ>1ifAP=0andˇ> ¯ˇ >1ifAP>0),orwhen

thegovernmentfullyinternalizesthesocialloss,butfacesalsoa

lossatthestageofsubrogation(ˇ>0for anyAP≥0).Arational

governmentwillengageinstrictermonitoringoftype-Pagentsin

ordertoreduceitsexposureinthefaceofinsolventtortfeasors.This

maytriggerhigher(andpossibly,excessivelyhigh)levelsofcareby

type-Pagents.

Comparingthe effects of monitoringon thelevel of care in

Propositions 2 and 4 yields an intriguing result. As stated in

Proposition2,whenmonitoringiscarriedoutbyabenevolent

gov-ernment,type-Pagentswillchoosealowerlevelofcarethanthe

levelofcarechosenbytype-Ragents:xSO

P <xSOR .Thisresultruns

contrarytotheobservationinProposition4inthe

government-paysregime,wherex∗R<x∗P.Governmentalmonitoringoftype-P

agentsremainshighinallcases,butthemonitoringcarriedoutby

awelfare-maximizinggovernmentdoesnotleadtotheparadox

observedinProposition2,wheretype-Pagentstakehighercare

thantype-Ragentsinspiteoftheirlimitedliability.Abenevolent

governmentwillinducelowercarelevelsfortype-Pagentsthanfor

type-Ragentsbecausetheprecautionsoftype-Pagentsaresocially

morecostlythanthoseoftype-Ragents.Althoughdirectprecaution

costsarethesamefortype-Pandtype-Ragents,theinducementof

precautionsfortype-Pagentsnecessitatehighermonitoringcosts

giventhereduceddirectincentivestheyfacebecauseoftheir

lim-itedliability.

3.3. Summaryresults

InTable1,wesummarizetheresultsofthepreviousanalysis

evaluatingtheefficiencyofthelevelsofcareandgovernmental

monitoringfortype-Pandtype-Ragentsinthegovernment-pays

regime.Wedosobycomparingthelevelsofmonitoringandcare

inagovernment-paysregimetothosethatwouldbeinducedbya

benevolentgovernment,asdiscussedinSection3.2.1.

Intuitively,inbothregimestype-Pagentsaremonitoredmore

closelythantype-Ragents.Infact,inbothregimes,type-Pagents

face reduced direct incentives through liability and necessitate

highergovernmentalmonitoring.Theextentofmonitoringof

type-Pagents,however,differsbetweenthetworegimes,eSO

P <e∗P.

Thisbringstolightanimportanteffect.Itispossibletoseethatin

thegovernment-paysregime,governmentalmonitoringmaylead

toanovershootingincareincentives,inducingtype-Pagentsto

adopthigherlevelsofcarethantype-Ragents,x∗R<xP∗.This

over-shootingeffectisnotobservedunderabenevolentgovernment,

xSO

R >xSOP .Thereasonforthisovershootingeffectisthat

govern-mentschoosealevelofmonitoringthatminimizestheirfinancial

exposureinthefaceofpotentiallyinsolventagents,without

inter-nalizingthecostthattype-Pagentsfaceintermsofhighercare.

Abenevolentgovernment,ontheotherhand,undertakesalevel

ofmonitoringthatinternalizesboththecostsandbenefitsofthe

agents’care.

Thegovernment-paysregimecorrectsthemisalignmentof

gov-ernmentalincentivesbutmayleadtoabiasedgovernmentalaction,

withstrictermonitoringandenforcementagainsttype-Pagents.

Theseresultsareconsistentwiththeanedoctalevidencediscussed

in Section 2,where themediacriticized local governments for

applyingdoublestandardsinenvironmentalprotectiontowards

smalllocalfirmsratherthanlargerandwealthierindustries.

4. Comparingregimesinthepresenceofenforcement imperfections

Weextendthemodeldiscussedin Section3toconsiderthe

workingsofthetwo-liabilityregimesinthepresenceof

enforce-mentimperfections,suchasinsolvency,courtdelays,anderrors.

Enforcementimperfections create anundesirable dilution of

deterrenceunderallliabilityregimes.Asit willbediscussedin

thissection,polluter-paysandgovernment-paysregimesrespond

differently to the presence of enforcement imperfections. We

assumethatinagovernment-paysregime,thegovernment

recov-erscompensationpaymentsfromtheresponsiblepartiesthrough

subrogation. Whensuccessfulin a subrogationaction, the

gov-ernment can obtainfull recovery fromtype-R agents, but only

partialrecoveryfromtype-Pagents. Recoverythrough

subroga-tionisnotinstantaneous;trialsarelengthyandrepaymentoccurs

withadelayequaltot.Furthermore,duetothepossibilityofcourt

errors,judicial outcomesare affectedby somedegreeof

uncer-tainty,andgovernmentscanobtainasubrogationjudgmentagainst

theresponsiblepartyonlywithprobabilityps.

Wedenotewithıtheoveralleffectivenessofadjudicationin

asubrogationaction,capturingthecombinedimpactofjudicial

delaysandcourterrors.Theeffectivenessofadjudication,ı,can

bethoughttodecreasefromtheinterestrateranddelaysin

adju-dicationt,andtoincreasefromtheprobabilityofsuccessofthe

governmentinthesubrogationpS.Inanalyticalterms,ı=pS/(1+r)t.

Aperfectlyeffectiveadjudicationoccursonlyinthelimitingcase

withnodelaysinadjudication,t=0(repaymenttothegovernment

iscollectedimmediately),orwheretheresponsiblepartiesgainno

financialbenefitfromjudicialdelays,r=0,(zerointerestrate),and

wheretherearenojudicialerrors,pS=1(repaymentoccurswith

certainty).Thedilutioneffectfromineffectiveadjudicationcanbe

reducedoreliminatedbyincreasingthedamageawardinanaction

forsubrogationtooffsetthediscountingfromjudicialdelaysand

legaluncertainty.

In the presence of legal and enforcement imperfections,

the objective function of a representative type-i agent, i=R, P,

becomes31:

min{xi}p(xi)ıDi+xi+m(e)(x∗∗−xi) (1)

31ThedilutionappliesonlytothedamageDandnottothefinem(e).Thisimplies

thatthepolluter’sinsolvencymayshieldthepolluterfrom(large)environmental

liability,butnotfromthepaymentofafine(i.e.insolvencyisnotassevereasto

makethepolluterunabletopayafine).Likewise,weassumethatgovernmentsare

abletocollectfineswithoutdelays.Notehoweverthatourresultsdonotdependon

(7)

Table1

Monitoringandcareinagovernment-paysregime.

Government-paysregime Benevolentgovernment Acomparison

Type-P Type-R Monitoringeffort e∗R<e∗P eSO

R <eSOP eSOP <e∗P eSOR >e∗R

Levelofcare x∗

R<x∗P xSOR >xSOP xSOP <x∗P xRSO>x∗R

The objective function of a benevolent government is

unchanged,whiletheobjectivefunctionofagovernmentaffected

byagencyproblembecomes:

min(e

i)i=R,Pp(xi)i[˛L+ˇ(L−ımin{L,Ai})]+



i=R,P

i(c(ei)+xi) (3)

Legaland enforcement imperfections dilute theagent’s care

incentivesin thesecondstageofthegame.32 Noweventype-R

prospectivepollutersmayexertaneffortlevellowerthansocially

optimaldependingontheseverityofthelegalandenforcement

imperfectionsandthesizeofthepenaltym(e).

Proposition5. Thegovernmentexertshighermonitoringon

type-Pagentsthan type-R agents. Thegovernment-pays regimefurther

increasesthelevelofgovernmentalmonitoringontype-Pagents

com-paredtothepolluter-paysregime.

Proof:SeeAppendixA.

Inapolluter-paysregime,thegovernmentalwaysexertsa

posi-tiveeffortontype-Pagents.Monitoringoftype-Ragentsonlytakes

placeifthedilutionofthedirectincentivesissufficientlyhigh.Ina

government-paysregime,thegovernmentexertsapositive

moni-toringeffortonbothtypesofagents,butmonitoringishigherfor

type-Pagents.Thiscanbeexplainedbythefactthattype-Pagents

exposegovernmentstolargerfinancialliabilitieswhichheightens

governments’marginal returnonmonitoringefforts.Thisresult

holdseven intheidealworldof perfectadjudication,witht=0

(repaymenttothegovernmentiscollectedimmediately),ps=1(the

repaymenttothegovernmentismadewithcertainty),andr=0

(zerointerestrate).Ahigherlevelofmonitoringfortype-Pagents

alsooccurswhenrepaymentinsubrogationisincreasedbycourts

(asasortofpunitivedamagemultiplier)tooffsettheeffectsof

dis-countratesanduncertainty.Thewedgebetweene∗Rande∗Pincreases

asthewealthoftype-Pagents,AP,lowers.

Proposition6. Thegovernment-paysregimeleadstoan

overshoot-ingofcareincentives,suchthatthelevel ofcarechosenby type-P

agentsishigherthanthelevelofcarechosenbytype-Ragentswhen

themonitoringeffectdominatesforthelimitedliabilityeffect.

Proof:SeeAppendixA.

Inagovernment-paysregime,enforcementimperfections

cre-atetwocountervailingeffectsonagents’care.Ontheonehand,

thegovernmentexertshigherlevelsofmonitoringonbothtypes

ofagents,inducingapossibleincreaseintheirlevelofcare.Onthe

otherhand,thereplacementofdirectliabilitywithindirect

liabil-itythroughsubrogationcandilutecareincentives.Theneteffecton

eachtypeofagents’optimallevelofcare,eiistherefore

indetermi-nate.Fortype-Pagents,theimpactofmonitoringismorelikely

todominatethedilution fromimperfectadjudication,sincethe

advantageofimperfectadjudicationissmallerfortype-Pagents,

duetotheirlimitedliability.Thiscanbeseeninthelimitingcase

ofjudgment-proofdefendants(i.e.forvaluesofa→0),forwhich

thegovernment-paysregimeonlycreatespositiveeffectsthrough

monitoring,withnodilutioneffect.Theoppositemaybetruefor

32 TheprooffollowstriviallyfromEqs.(10)and(11)inAppendixAandisomitted

forbrevityreasons.

type-Ragents,sincegovernmentswilllikelyconcentratemostof

theirmonitoringeffortsontype-Pagents.

5. Thecomparativeadvantageofthegovernment-pays regimeasaninstrumentofenvironmentalprotection

In Section 4 above, we examinedincentives created by the

polluter-paysand thegovernment-pays regimesonprospective

polluters.Inthefollowing,wewillbuildontheseresultsto

exam-inethecomparativeadvantageandthewelfarepropertiesofthe

government-paysregimeasaninstrumentofenvironmental

con-trol. Inarecent paper,Faureand Raja(2010),havearguedthat

oneoftheprimaryreasonsforregulatoryfailurein

environmen-talprotectionindevelopingcountriesisthatpolicymakersdopay

sufficientattentiontothedesignofregulatorysolutionsthatare

appropriatetothelegal,economic,political,andsocialsituations

inwhichtheywillneedtooperate.Inthissectionweconsiderthe

pollutershowthatthegovernment-paysregimethroughthelensof

regulatorydesignsuggestedbyFaureetal.showingthatthis

regu-latorysolutionmaybecomeapreferablemethodofenvironmental

controlin situations characterizedbywidespreadpoverty, high

interestrates,andjudicialdelaysanduncertainty.Our

compara-tiveevaluationofalternativelegalregimesconsidersthewelfare

propertiesandthebiasescreatedbythegovernment-paysregime

relativetothealternativepolluter-paysregime,mappingthe

opti-malscopeofapplicationofeachregime.

Theeffects ofthegovernment-paysregimeontheaggregate

levelofenvironmentalharmcanbeevaluatedbyconsideringthe

expectedharmcausedbytype-Randtype-Pagents.Thetotalsocial

costofenvironmentalaccidentsequalsthesumoftheexpected

environmentallosscausedbytype-Randtype-Pagents,plusthe

precautionandmonitoringcosts,asfoundinEq.(2).Wedenote

withSPP thetotal social costof environmentalaccidentsunder

thepolluter-paysregimewhengovernmentandprospective

pol-lutersactoptimally.Similarly,wedenotewithSGPtotalsocialcost

ofenvironmentalaccidentsunderthegovernment-paysregime.

AccordingtotheanalysisdiscussedinSection4,theoptimalchoice

ofcareleveloftype-iagent,i=R,Pisafunctionof:

x∗i =f(ı,,)·i=R,P

whereı∈[0,1]measurestheeffectivenessofadjudication,defined

as ı=pS/(1+r)t, ∈[0,∞] the cost-effectiveness of monitoring

definedas=ce/pxxe,and=RAP/Lthewealthlevel,givenbythe

percentageoftype-Ragentsin societymultipliedbythewealth

leveloftype-Pagents.

Inordertounderstandtheoptimalscopeofapplicationofthe

government-pays principle forcontrolling environmentalharm,

wedefineaniso-social-costboundarybetweenthetworegimes

asfollows:

SPP=SGP (4)

The iso-social-cost boundary in (4) represents

combina-tions of parameters (ı, , ) for which the polluter-pays and

government-pays regimes prove equally efficient in containing

total environmental loss. Fig. 1 below depicts the

iso-social-cost boundary which helps us compare the polluter-pays and

(8)

Fig.1. Optimalscopeofapplicationofthegovernment-paysregime.

control.Theparametersı,and arerepresentedrespectively

onthevertical,horizontal-left,andhorizontal-rightaxesofFig.1.

Pointsthatfallbelowtheslopediso-social-costfunction

rep-resent combinations of our three parameters for which the

government-pays regime proves more efficient. Points above

the iso-social cost function instead represent combinations of

parameters that render the polluter-pays regime preferable as

aninstrumentofenvironmentalcontrol.Inallpointsbelowthe

iso-socialcostfunction,thebenefitsofshiftingtheincentivesto

governmentoutweightheproblemscreatedbythe

government-paysregime.

Theintuitionbehindthisgraphicalrepresentationexplainsthe

following.Areductionofthewealthlevelofprospectivepolluters,

,hasa positiveeffectonthetotalsocial costofenvironmental

accidentsunderbothliabilityregimes.However,thepolluter-pays

regimeismoresensitivethanthegovernment-paysregimetoa

decreasein(measuredbyandecreaseinRorAPoranincrease

inL).Theslopesalongtheeast-westandnorth-westdimensionsin

Fig.1implythat,forsufficientlylowlevelofwealth(i.e.largevalues

ofpoverty),thegovernment-paysregimemayalsobecome

prefer-ablewhengovernmentismoreeffectiveinmonitoringand/orwhen

adjudicationis imperfect and plagued withjudicial delays and

uncertainty.

Thepolluter-paysregimebecomesamoredesirablealternative

whentheeffectivenessofadjudication,ı,increasesorthe

effective-nessofmonitoring,,decreasesespeciallywhencombinedwith

lowpovertylevels.

Inagovernment-paysregime,forvalues=1thelosstothe

government is associated withthe delays and uncertainties in

thesubrogationaction.Thesecostsincreasewiththetime

neces-sarytorecoverfromtheresponsiblepartiesthroughsubrogation

(i.e.higher t) and withtheinterest rate, r,and decreaseswith

theprobabilityofsuccessinthesubrogationaction,pS.

Govern-mentsmaychoosesomepositivelevelofmonitoringtominimize

thesecosts.Thegovernmentwillexertthesamelevelof

monitor-ingonbothtypesofagents,becauseforvalues=1theagents’

wealthdifferencesdonotaffecttheirabilitytorepayin

subroga-tionandarenotrelevantforthegovernment’schoiceofmonitoring

effort.

Theseresultsshedlightonsomepossiblepolicyissuesforthe

adoptionofthegovernment-pays regime.Afirstpoint concerns

thebestinstitutionalallocationofoversightpowersforthe

moni-toringofprospectivepollutersunderthegovernment-paysregime.

Theprivateandsocialvalueoftherisk-creatingactivitiesis

gener-allyopaquetocourtsandgovernmentalagencies.Forthisreason,

thesevalues do not generallyplay a direct role in tort law. In

theabsenceofawell-functioningliabilitysystem,however,when

careincentivesaredrivenbygovernmentalmonitoring,the

eval-uationoftheprivateandsocialvalueoftherisk-creatingactivity

becomesrelevant.Thegovernment-paysregimedoesnotcreate

immediateincentivesonthegovernmenttotakeintoaccountthe

value of therisk-creating activitywhen choosing a monitoring

level.Aswehaveseen,thismayleadtoamyopicgovernmental

actionthatleadstoanexcessivemonitoringoftype-Pandtype-R

agents.Apossiblewaytoinducemonitoringagenciestoconsider

thevalueoftherisk-creatingactivitieswouldbetofacilitatea

coor-dinatedaction betweenbranchesofgovernmententrusted with

environmentalprotectionandtaxrevenuecollection.Monitoring

thatdistortscareandactivitylevelincentivesreducesthevalueand

thetax-revenuepotentialofthoseactivities—acostthatwouldbe

internalizedandsomewhatcorrectedthroughcoordinated

govern-mentalaction.

6. Conclusions

Inthispaperwehaveevaluatedthedifferencesbetweentwo

typesofenvironmentalregulation: thetraditionalpolluter-pays

principle,wherethepolluterisdirectlyliableforenvironmental

harm,andavariationofthepolluter-paysprinciple,adoptedbya

numberofdevelopingcountries,includingIndia,Malaysia,Taiwan,

Ecuador,Chile,CostaRica,Kenya,andSouthAfrica,amongothers,

wherethegovernmentinsteadisdirectlyresponsibleforpayment

andenvironmentalmonitoring.Wehavecomparedtheincentives

forboththepolluterandthegovernmentunderbothregimes,as

wellasthewelfareoutcomes.

Recentlyenactedlegislationandjudicialprecedentscreatean

obligationonthestatetocompensatethevictimsof

environmen-talharm. Thesereinterpretations of thepolluter-pays principle

holdstateandlocalgovernmentsjointly-and-severallyliablefor

environmentaldamagecausedbyprivateparties,allowingthese

publicbodies to act in subrogation against the individual

pol-luterswhenpossible.Thesesolutionsaimtoensureaneffective

andtimelycompensationofvictims,whichguaranteesreliefeven

whenpolluterscannotbeidentifiedorarefinanciallyinsolvent.In

addition,wehaveexaminedtheincentivescreatedbythisregime

of governmental liabilityonprospective polluters. We built on

thoseresultstoexaminethecomparativeadvantageandthe

wel-farepropertiesofthepolluter-paysandgovernment-paysregimes

as instruments of environmentalcontrol. We have shown that

government-paysregimesmaybepreferablein situations

char-acterizedbywidespreadpoverty,highinterestrates,andjudicial

delaysanduncertainty.Wefurtherconsideredthewelfare

prop-erties of thegovernment-pays regime, comparingits effects to

those that would be induced by the actions of a benevolent,

welfare-maximizing government. The government-pays regime

mayleadlocalgovernments toactmyopically,choosinga level

ofmonitoringthatminimizesthefinancialexposureofthelocal

government but doesnot fully internalize thecosts as wellas

the benefits of the agents’ care. The study of the advantages

andthelimitsofthesealternativeinstrumentsofenvironmental

liabilityprovidesa valuableviewpoint tounderstandthe

inter-action between legal remedies and institutional solutions for

environmentalprotectioninboth developingand industrialized

countries.

Acknowledgements

WewouldliketothankEmanuelaCarbonaraandMichaelFaure

fortheirextensivecommentsandcriticisms,andMaryRumseyand

(9)

AppendixA. Mathematicalappendix

ProofofProposition1. Thetype-RagentchoosesxRtominimize

(1)accordingtothefollowingFOC:

−pxL=1−m(e) ifxR<x∗∗

−pxL=1 ifxR≥x∗∗

(4’)

Itfollowsimmediatelythatx∗R=x∗∗

Thetype-PagentchoosesxPtominimize(1)accordingtothe

followingFOC:

−pxAP=1−m(e) ifxP<x∗∗

−pxAP=1 ifxP≥x∗∗

(5)

Itfollowsimmediatelythatx∗P≤x∗∗.

ProofofProposition2. Thegovernmentchooses(eR,eP)to

min-imize(2)accordingtothefollowingFOCs:

dxi

dei(pxL+

1)+cei=0 i=R,P (6)

From(6)i=R,eSO

R =0sincepx(xR∗)L+1=0fromProposition1.

From(6)i=P,eP∗>0sincepx(xP∗)L+1<0fromProposition1.

Taking the ratio of (4) and (5), since pxx>0, it follows that

x∗P(eSO

P )<x∗R(eSOR )

ProofofProposition3. Thegovernmentchooses(eR,eP)to

min-imize(3)accordingtothefollowingFOCs:

dxR deR[px(x ∗ R)˛L+1]+ceR=0 (7) dxP deP[px(x ∗ P)(˛L+ˇ(L−AP))+1]+ceP=0 (8)

wheredxR/deR=me/pxxL>0anddxP/deP=me/pxxAP>0.

From (7) since eR cannot be negative. From total

differ-ential of (8), e∗P is increasing in ˇ, where de∗P/dˇ=−px(L−

AP)/ (pxx+APpxxxRme) (dx/de)−APpxxRmee

Proof of Proposition 4. The benevolent government chooses

accordingtothefollowingFOC:

dxP

deP(px(x

SO

P )L+1)+ce=0

Compare(7)and(8)undertheassumptionthatsecond-order

effect dxP/deP are negligible. Asshown in Proof of Proposition

3,LHSof(8) isincreasingin ˇ.Hence,weneedtoimposethat

L<˛L+ˇ(L−AP).It follows that under thecondition (1−˛) L<

ˇ (L−AP),e∗P>eSOP .

Proof of Corollary. Assume the condition (1−˛)L<ˇ(L−AP)

holds.Takingtheratioof(5)evaluatedateSO

P ande∗P,sincepxx>0,it

followsthatx∗R(eSO

R )>xR∗(e∗R).Sameproofappliestotype-Pagent.

ProofofProposition5. Thetype-RagentchoosesxRtominimize

(1)accordingtothefollowingFOC:

−pxıL=1−m(e) ifxR<x∗∗

−pxıL=1 ifxR≥x∗∗

(10)

Itfollowsimmediatelythatx∗R≤x∗∗

Thetype-PagentchoosesxPtominimize(1)accordingtothe

followingFOC:

−pxıAP=1−m(e) ifxP<x∗∗

−pxıAP=1 ifxP≥x∗∗

(11)

Itfollowsimmediatelythatx∗P≤x∗∗.

Thegovernmentchooses(eR,eP)tominimize(3)accordingto

thefollowingFOCs:

dxR deR



px(x∗R)[˛L+ˇ(1−ı)L]+1



+ceR=0 (12) dxP deP



px(x∗P)(˛L+ˇ(L−ıAP))+1



+ceP =0 (13)

wheredxR/deR=me/pxxıL>0anddxP/deP=me/pxxıAP>0.

Fromtotaldifferentialof(8),e∗Pisincreasinginˇand

decreas-ingin˛.Fromthecomparisonof(12)and(13),e∗P>e∗R,underthe

assumptionthatsecond-ordereffectdxP/deParenegligible.

ProofofProposition6. Fromthecomparisonof(10)and(11)

undertheassumptionofhighlevelsofmonitoringontype-Pagent

withrespecttotype-Ragent,i.e.e∗P>e∗R.

References

Babu,P.G.,Eger,T.,Raja,A.,Schäfer,H.B.,&Somashekhar,T.(Eds.).(2010).Economic

analysisoflawinIndia.Theoryandapplication.India:OxfordUniversityPress.

Bakshi,P.M.(2005).TheconstitutionofIndia.NewDelhi,India:UniversalLaw

Pub-lishingCo.

Bergkamp,L.(2001).Liabilityandenvironmentprivateandpubliclawaspectsof

civilliabilityforenvironmentalharminaninternationalcontext.TheHague,The

Netherlands:KluwerLawInternational.

Bruch,C.,Coker,W.,&VanArsdale,C.(2001).Constitutionalenvironmentallaw:

Giv-ingforcetofundamentalprinciplesinAfrica.ColumbiaJournalofEnvironmental

Law,26(131),174.

Chen,D.(1994).TheemergenceofanenvironmentalconsciousnessinTaiwan.In

M.A.Rubenstein(Ed.),TheOtherTaiwan,257(pp.261–262).Armonk,NY:M.E.

Sharpe.

Cole,D.H.(1991).CleaningupKrakow:Poland’secologicalcrisisandthepolitical

economyofinternationalenvironmentalassistance.ColoradoJournalof

Interna-tionalEnvironmentalLawandPolicy,2(205),230.

CommissionoftheEuropeanCommunities.(1993).Communicationfromthe

Com-missiontotheCouncilandParliament:Greenpaperonremedyingenvironmental

damageCOM47final,May14.

Craig, P. P., & Deshpande, S. L. (1989).Rights, autonomy and process:

Pub-licinterestlitigationinIndia.OxfordJournalofLegalStudies,9(3),356–373.

http://www.jstor.org/stable/764422.AccessedJuly29.07.08

Dari-Mattiacci,G.,&DeGeest,G.(2005).Judgmentproofnessunderfourdifferent

precautiontechnologies.JournalofInstitutional&TheoreticalEconomics,161(1),

38–56.

Dari-Mattiacci,G.,Garoupa,N.,&Gomez-Pomar,F.(2010).Stateliability.European

ReviewofPrivateLaw,18(4),773–811.

Faure,M.(2009).Environmentalliability.InE.Elgar(Ed.),Tortlawandeconomics

(pp.247–286).Cheltenham.

Faure,M.,Goodwin,M.,&Weber,F.(2010).BuckingtheKuznetscurve:Designing

effectiveenvironmentalregulationindevelopingCountries.VirginiaJournalof

InternationalLaw,51(1),95–156.

Faure,M.,&Raja,A.V.(2010).Effectivenessofenvironmentalpublicinterest

litiga-tioninIndia:Determiningthekeyvariables.FordhamEnvironmentalLawReview,

21(2),239–294.

Finn, F. R. (1975). The polluter-pays principle and transitional period

mea-suresinadynamicsetting.TheSwedishJournalofEconomics,77(1),56–68.

http://www.jstor.org/stable/3439327.Accessed05.05.08

Gresser,J.,Fujikura,K.,&Morishima,A.(1981).EnvironmentalLawinJapan,285–319.

Guelton, S. (2002). Who can pay for depollution? An economic approach.

Laboratoire d’Observation de l’Économie et des Institutions Locales,

TRADE/WP.8/AC.1/SEM.7/2002/4/S.8.<www.unece.org/ie/intersol/documents/

s.8e.pdf>Accessed28.07.08.

Jain,M.P.(2005).Indianconstitutionallaw.NewDelhi,India:Wadhwa&Company

Nagpur.

Jaswal,P.S.(2008).Environmentlaw.Faridabad,India:AllahbadLawAgency.

Krier,J.E.,&Stewart,R.B.(1978).Environmentallawandpolicy:Readingsmaterials

andnotes.Indianapolis,IN:Bobbs-Merrill.

KrishnaKumari,A.(2007).EvolutionofenvironmentallegislationinIndia.Working

paper,ICFAIUniversity.<http://ssrn.com/abstract=956228>Accessed30.07.08.

Lin,A.C.(2005).Beyondtort:Compensatingvictimsofenvironmentaltoxicinjury.

SouthernCaliforniaLawReview,78(1439),1493.

Mustafa,M.(1991).Malaysia.InternationalEncyclopaediaofLaws:EnvironmentalLaw

5(232)(MarcBoesed.,1991-).

Nash,J.(2000).Toomuchmarket?Conflictbetweentradablepollutionallowances

andthepolluterpaysprinciple.HarvardEnvironmentalLawReview,24(465)

OrganizationforEconomicCo-operationandDevelopment.(1972).Onguiding

prin-ciplesconcerninginternationaleconomicaspectsofenvironmentalpoliciesC,72.,

p.128.

OrganizationforEconomicCo-operationandDevelopment.(1974).Thepolluter-pays

(10)

OrganizationforEconomicCo-operationandDevelopment.(1989).Recommendation

ofthecouncilconcerningtheapplicationofthepolluter-paysprincipletoaccidental

pollutionC,89.,p.88.

OrganizationforEconomicCo-operationandDevelopment.(1992).Thepolluter-pays

principle:OECDanalysesandrecommendations.Doc.OCDE/GD(92)81.

Ott,C.,&Schäfer,H.(1996).Wideningthescopeofenvironmentalliability.InE.Ide,

&R.vandenBergh(Eds.),Lawandeconomicsoftheenvironment.Oslo,Norway:

JuridiskForlag.

Ott,Claus,&Schäfer,H.(2004).Specialproblemsincivilliabilityintheeconomic

analysisofcivillaw.Cheltenham,U.K:EdwardElgarPublishingLtd.

Polinsky,A.M.(1980).Strictliabilityvs.negligenceinamarketsetting.TheAmerican

EconomicReview,70(2),363–367.

Prasad,P.M.(2004).Environmentalprotection:TheroleofliabilitysysteminIndia.

EconomicandPoliticalWeekly,39(January(3)),257–269.

Rabie,M.A.(1991).SouthAfrica.InternationalEncyclopaediaofLaws:Environmental

Law,7,387–388(MarcBoesed.,1991-).

Raja,A.V.,&Rathinam,F.(2005).Economicefficiencyofpublicinterestlitigations(PIL):

LessonsfromIndia.WorkingpaperNo.3870,MunichPersonalRePEcArchive.

<http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/3870/>AccessedJuly17.07.08.

Santos,R.(1996).EnvironmentallawofCostaRica.ComparativeEnvironmentalLaw,

1,18(NicholasA.Robinsoned.,1996-)

Schäfer,H.-B.(2000).Thebundlingofsimilarinterestsinlitigation.Theincentives

forclassactionandlegalactionstakenbyassociations.EuropeanJournalofLaw

andEconomics,9(3),183–213.

Shavell,S.(1986).Thejudgmentproofproblem.InternationalReviewofLawand

Economics,6,45–58.

Shavell,S.(1987).Economicanalysisofaccidentlaw.Cambridge,MA:Harvard

Uni-versityPress.

Sullivan,M.(1996).Chileanenvironmentallaw.ComparativeEnvironmentalLaw,1.

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

El eje 1 discrimina entre las representaciones proporcionadas por Il Giornale y La Stampa, mientras que los dos periódicos ideológicamente orientados, L’Unità (izquierda) y

With a coarse basic mesh resolution the effects of p-adaptivity are significant, leading to results close to the ones obtained with the maximum resolution allowed to the

Neurosteroidogenic efficacy of Translocator Protein (TSPO) ligands can be predicted by evaluating the time that the ligand spent into the target, namely the Residence Time, rather

The aim of this proposal is to prove that by having a minimal intervention on the urban shading devices over the parking lots and in the internal parks can bring

Within several complementary test campaigns (performed within international OECD projects), the results from PKL integral system tests have been used to define the boundary

However, because of the complexity of this disease, these persons are early institutionalized in nursing home with negative consequences for patients themselves and welfare

Specifically, consider- ing also the limited number of the sample of subjects involved, rather than the methods of automated data reading (think of the different software currently on