• Non ci sono risultati.

The impact of selling information on competition

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "The impact of selling information on competition"

Copied!
44
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

EUI WORKING PAPERS

WP 3 3 0 EUR © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(2)

European University Institute © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(3)

EUROPEAN UNIVERSITY INSTITUTE, FLORENCE ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT WP 3 3 0 EUR N ^ Ur° %

1

° 3 d O 'A ^ >

3

ê*

EUI Working Paper ECO No. 2000/6

The Impact of Selling Information on Competition

Karl H. Schlag © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(4)

All rights reserved.

No part of this paper may be reproduced in any form without permission of the author.

© 2000 Karl H. Schlag Printed in Italy in April 2000 European University Institute

Badia Fiesolana I - 50016 San Domenico (FI)

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(5)

The Impact of Selling Information on

Competition*

Karl H. Schlag

Economics Department

European University Institute

March 2000

Abstract

We consider a homogenous good oligopoly with identical consumers who learn about prices either by (sequentially) visiting firms or by con­ sulting a price agency who sells information about which firm charges the lowest price. In the sequential equilibrium with maximal trade and minimal search, prices are dispersed and consumers randomize between consulting a price agency and buying a t the first firm encountered. Low competition among price agencies induces maximal price dispersion. High com petition among firms leads to offers th at are either rip-offs or bargains where most consumers visit a price agency and firm profits are small. Keywords: price agency, intermediary, sequential search, price dispersion. JEL Classification: D43, D83, L ll, L13, L15.

‘We wish to thank Klaus Adam, Monika Schnitzer and Avner Shaked for helpful comments. The idea for this paper is based on a master’s thesis at the University of Bonn by Andreas Meis- ter. Financial support from the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft, Sonderforschungsbereich 303 at the University of Bonn is gratefully acknowledged.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(6)

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(7)

1

In tr o d u ctio n

As the number of products increases and markets globalize we find an increasing demand for information, in particular, about where products are sold at what price. This has been creating an increasing supply of information. The internet is a growing source of free information; many sites offer information on the location of the firm selling a given product cheapest (e.g., search routines among internet book stores are very popular). W ith the expansion of the internet, opportunity costs for finding the appropriate sites have been rising too. Sources that explicitly sell information include newspapers, shopping clubs and price agencies. A price agency is a firm which sells information about the cheapest seller of a given product. In recent years, a particular form of price agency has been rapidly spreading from Germany, Austria and Switzerland to the rest of Europe. The consumer is charged a percentage of his savings either relative to the lowest price known to him prior to his visit to the price agency or relative to the producers’ recommended price.1

Consumers can profit two-fold from buying information. Directly, they are guided to the locations of firms who charge lower prices. Indirectly, the information given to some consumers increases competition between the firms to the benefit of all consumers. The service of the price agency is a public good. In particular, when a known set of firms can only be distinguished according to the price they charge for a given good then all consumers wishing to purchase this good will not choose to visit a price agency. Market prices would otherwise reflect perfect information and thus eliminate any additional value of visiting a price agency. Our paper contains the first analysis (known to us) where the price of information is endogenous in such a competitive goods market. The related literature (including [Hiinchen and von Ungern-Sternberg, 1985]) is discussed in the conclusion.

We aim to explore the impact of costly information providers on price for­ mation, profits, dispersion of information and on consumer behavior. We focus on the public good effects of price agencies and assume that their only service is to provide information about prices. We consider a simpler payment scheme of the price agencies than the one described above and assume that a price agency informs its customer about the lowest market price for a fixed fee (or tariff).

1 (unverbindliche Prcisemfehhing in German)

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(8)

This price agency tariff is treated in three different settings: (i) exogenous, (ii) set by a monopoly or by colluding price agencies and (iii) determined through competition among price agencies. At the end of the paper we relax the assump­ tion that price agencies act honestly and discuss an alternative flexible tariff that provides the right incentives.

The underlying goods market is modelled in the simplest possible way. A homogeneous good is supplied by finitely many identical firms without cost or capacity constraints. Finitely many consumers each demand one unit of the good. A finite number of price agencies each charge a fiat fee (or tariff) for informing a consumer about which firm is charging the lowest price. In the first part of the paper we consider the strategic interaction between consumers and firms while keeping the tariff of price agencies fixed at an exogenously given commonly known level. The sequence of moves is as follows. First firms simulta­ neously set prices observable by price agencies but unobservable by consumers. Then each consumer independently and sequentially gathers information about prices, either directly by visiting one of the firms or indirectly by consulting a price agency. Each time a consumer visits a firm he can decide to buy the good at this firm, to visit some other firm, to visit a price agency or to terminate search and to not buy the good at all. It is assumed costly for a consumer to gather information; the first visit to any firm costs s > 0.2

We choose to solve our model using standard game theory, ruling out non credible threats by focussing on sequential equilibria. In particular, deviations from equilibrium play can only be learned from observations. Thus we depart from much of the search literature (e.g., [Diamond, 1971], [Hanchen and von Ungern-Sternberg, 1985]) that assumes the actual distribution of prices to be known. In addition, we limit our attention to efficient (more precisely, welfare maximizing) equilibria where each consumer buys the good with the minimal number of visits to a firm. In these equilibria, consumers either go directly to a price agency or buy the good at the first firm they visit. Equilibrium conditions ensure that consumers do not prefer to continue their search (or to go to a price agency) after they have visited the first firm.

Typical for such sequential search models (see [McMillan and Rothschild, 1994]), there is no trade if the price agencies’ tariff is too large. W ithout potential customers coming via a price agency, firms have an incentive to raise their price

technically this means sequential search, without replacement and with free recall.

2 © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(9)

as they take advantage of the additional search costs involved should a consumer choose to visit another firm. Notice that this argument is based on the fact that consumers do not learn about a price increase until they actually visit the firm. Thus, if no consumer visits a price agency, firms charge the monopoly price. Consequently, consumers choose not to buy the good and not to visit any firm as they cannot cover search costs of the first visit. A simple corollary is that some consumers will visit the price agency with positive probability whenever trade occurs in equilibrium.

When the services of price agencies are less expensive and some consumers visit a price agency, a firm which raises its price trades off earning more from uninformed consumers and being less likely to be the cheapest in the market, thus lowering the expected number of sales to consumers who visited a price agency. For a sufficiently small price agency tariff efficient equilibria exist and are completely characterized. In these equilibria, firms randomize among prices belonging to a closed interval. Expected market prices lie above the price agen­ cies’ tariff as consumers are indifferent between buying directly at the first firm and going to a price agency. When only few (two or three) firms are competing in the market, comparative statics reveal that higher search costs cause expected prices to decrease, which can make consumers better off. Although an increase in search costs directly reduces consumer utility, it also generates a substitution effect through making price agencies more attractive, with higher demand for price agencies’ services pushing down expected prices. When there are many firms, then most consumers go to a price agency and aggregate firm profits are very small. Firms then mostly either charge a very low (bargain) or a relatively high (rip-off) price (as in [Salop and Stiglitz, 1977]).

Next we include price agencies as players and assume th at they choose their (publicly observable) tariff before firms set prices. Colluding price agencies (such as a price agency monopoly) that maximize their joint profits act as if they do not care about profits and only choose their tariff to maximize price dispersion in the market. When individual search costs are small, then unlike the exogenous tariff setting analyzed above, consumers are always better off under lower search costs. When there are many firms then price agencies obtain almost all surplus.

Finally we briefly consider the effects of competition among price agencies. Should this lead to low tariffs then most consumers will visit the price agency and market prices will be low.

We proceed as follows. In Section 2 we present and analyze the basic

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(10)

model without price agencies. In Section 3 we add price agencies and assume tariffs to be exogenous in Subsection 3.1. In Subsections 3.2 and 3.3 we then analyze collusion and competition. Section 4 provides the necessary adaptations to ensure that price agencies act truthfully. In Section 5 we discuss the related literature and conclude. The appendix contains the explicit calculations for the special case where there are either two or three firms in the market.

2

In d iv id u a l Search

First we analyze market behavior without price agencies which also results when price agencies’ tariffs are too high. Consider the following oligopoly market with search frictions, n identical, risk neutral firms produce a homogeneous good at marginal cost 0 (there are neither fix costs nor supply constraints). A finite number of identical, risk neutral consumers each has demand for one unit of the good and a reservation price of 1. To simplify notation, we normalize total demand to 1 which makes all equations appear as if there is only one consumer. Consumers only learn the price offered by a given firm after visiting this firm. We assume that a consumer incurs a cost s € (0,1) each time she visits a firm for the first time, s is meant to reflect frictions when gathering information from an unfamiliar source. Later visits of the same firm are thus assumed costless.

We consider the following sequence of moves. At the outset, firms simul­ taneously choose their price for the good. These prices are not observed by the consumers. Then each consumer either chooses a firm to visit or decides not to buy the good. Once visiting a firm, a consumer can either purchase the good at this firm at the price offered, visit another, possibly previously visited firm, or decide to quit the search and to not buy the good from any firm. The game ends either when the good is purchased or when the consumer decides to terminate his search and to not buy the good at all.

The strategy of a firm i can be identified with a cumulative distribution of prices Fi. The strategy of a consumer can be very complicated, although two simple pure strategies are immediate: “do not search and hence do not purchase” and “purchase at any price at firm i" . Throughout this paper we will analyze symmetric Nash equilibria in which each firm chooses the same c.d.f. F and each consumer uses the same purchasing strategy. Our game has many symmetric Nash equilibria, e.g., each firm charges the price 0 and each consumer visits a

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(11)

random firm and purchases the good there if this firm charges 0 and otherwise does not purchase the good. Notice that consumers’ threat in this equilibrium not to buy when a firm charges price s/2 is not credible. Given search costs s, a consumer would be better off buying at s/2 than not purchasing the good at all or purchasing the good at a different firm. In the following we restrict attention to Nash equilibria that are not based on such incredible threats. Formally we will restrict attention to sequential equilibria. Typical to models with sequential search ([Diamond, 1971], [McMillan and Rothschild, 1994]), we obtain market failure in equilibrium.

P ro p o sitio n 1 There is a unique sequential equilibrium: firms charge the mon­

opoly price 1 and consumers immediately decide not to purchase the good.

The proof of the inexistence of pure strategy equilibria can be stated ver­ bally. Consumers are willing to pay any price below 1 when they are visiting a firm (since search costs s are sunk). Thus, all firms charge 1; the firm charging the minimum market price strictly below 1 can otherwise raise its price slightly (by less than s) without loosing its clients. Consumers anticipate these high prices and decide not to visit any firm (and thus not to purchase the good) as they cannot cover their search cost s > 0 of visiting the first firm. The more general proof for mixed strategies is analogous and therefore omitted.

3

Search in a M arket w ith P r ic e A g en cie s

In models of sequential search there is too little competition among firms. Firms exploit consumers visiting their firm which induces consumers not to start to search in the first place. Things change when we add price agencies. A price agency is assumed to know all prices in the market and sells this information to consumers at a publicly known price (or tariff) b > 0. Consumers are not able (or allowed) to resell their information to other consumers. When a consumer acquires the services of the price agency, all information necessary for the trans­ action are included. So we assume that the consumer does not incur any further cost when going to the firm specified by the price agency. On the other hand, the consumer’s visit to the price agency also involves individual costs which we assume for simplicity to be equal to s.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(12)

3.1

E xogen ou s Tariffs

Assume at first that all price agencies charge the same exogenous price b > 0 for their services. Notice that the existence of price agencies does not preclude market failure. It is immediate from the analysis in Section 2 that regardless of the size of b there is always a sequential equilibrium in which all firms charge the monopoly price 1 and all consumers decide at the outset to not purchase the good. In order for there to be trade in a sequential equilibrium, some consumers must visit the price agency with positive probability. A visit to a price agency is only profitable when there is uncertainty about the prices in the market. Since consumers know the equilibrium strategy of each firm this means that some firms choose a mixed pricing strategy. However, not all consumers will choose to visit the price agency. Otherwise, Bertrand competition is induced among the firms as only firms offering the lowest price will get customers. Firms will consequently offer price 0 and consumers will purchase directly at firms without going to the price agency first.

In the rest of the paper we restrict attention to symmetric sequential equi­ libria that are efficient in the sense that each consumer buys the good and the expected number of times the cost s is incurred is minimized. In these equilib­ ria, each consumer randomizes between going directly to a firm to purchase the good and going directly to a price agency to then purchase the good at a firm charging the lowest price.

In the following we will derive necessary properties of these equilibria. Let 7 6 (0,1) be the probability that a consumer goes directly to a price agency. Equilibrium prices will be contained in [0,1]. A firm raising her price from p to p' yields a trade-off between lowering the probability of receiving customers that first went to the price agency (provided F (p) < F (p')) and raising profits per sale. Hence, firms will randomize over a closed interval of prices [a,0] , i.e.,

F is strictly increasing on (a,/?) with [q, 0} C [0,1]. Let p = f pdF (p) be the expected price offered in equilibrium by a firm.

Next we calculate F as a function of 0- In order to give incentives to firms to choose the same pricing strategy, each consumer who decides to go directly to a firm must be equally likely to visit each firm. Hence, with probability £ (1 — 7) a consumer visits firm i and purchases the good there. Firm i also sells to all consumers that first went to the price agency if it chose the lowest price in the

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(13)

market. Indifference of firm i over prices p € [a,/?] implies i ( l - 7 ) + 7( l - F ( p ) )n—1

Since F (a) = 0 we obtain from (1) that 1 “ 7 1 — 7 + rry • P = - ( ! - 7 ) •/? • n

0

(i) so F{p) = F (p,7,/3) = if 0 < p < 1-77+n7^ ^ T ^ P < P < 0 (2) 1 if

where the corresponding density is given by

0 1

f i.P) = n — 1

0 < p < l

0 — p \

ri7 / ( 0 ~ p ) p

for a < p < 0. In particular, the minimal price a always lies strictly above 0. Given p = J p f (p) dp, we obtain p = 0 n — 1

0

/ l - 7 ^ I " ' l i m / V n 7 ) 1" 1 lim / V « 7 )1 * - > J-. T ^ 0 0 ~ P 0 ~ P \ " P ~ P dp P dp

(3)

using change of variables p = p//3 so p = 0p and dp = 0dp. Hence, h (7) := p /0 is independent of 0.

Each consumer buys the good and is indifferent between going directly to a firm and going first to a price agency. Hence,

s + b + pBn = s + p < 1

(4)

where pBk denotes the expected minimum price in the market when k firms randomize independently according to F. Moreover, a consumer who decides to go directly to a firm will not purchase the good if the price is above s + p since he always has the option to visit a second firm. Hence, 0 < s + p.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(14)

In the following we will derive additional properties of F when p = s + p as we shall show below that P = s + p holds in these equilibria. Notice that this means that any consumer who goes directly to a firm where the good is offered at the maximal price p is indifferent between buying the good at this firm and visiting another firm. Since p = s + p = s + p h (7) we obtain

The profit of a firm equals what it earns by charging the highest price p = s + p. It must also earn an equal share of what consumers pay directly at firms and what they pay for the good after visiting the price agency. Hence,

(s + p) (1 - 7) - = (1 - 7) - p + 7- p Bn ,

n n n

which holds if and only if

P B n - I s . Thus,

b = p — 1 \ a = 1 - 1 1 s. 1 — h 7

(5)

This leads us to the first main result.

P ro p o sitio n 2 An efficient symmetric sequential equilibrium exists if and only

if there exists 7 6 (0,1) that satisfies

s s ( 1 l \

P - s + p = --- - < 1 and b = p - pB„ = P ---- = --- ---s . (6)

1 — h 7 \1 — h 7/

In such an equilibrium, each firm chooses prices according to F satisfying (2). Each consumer goes directly to the price agency with probability 7 and goes

equally likely to one of the n firms with probability 1 — 7. A consumer buys the

good at any firm she visits if this price is less or equal to s + p.

The expected price nc paid by a consumer, the expected profit of a firm 7Xf and the expected profit of the price agency irp in a given efficient symmetric

sequential equilibrium are given by

nc nf 7Tp p = P - s = 1 - h " 1 — 'y - n (' - l } P = M T CI f ' © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(15)

P ro o f. All we are left to show is 0 = s + p is necessary and that 7 6 (0,1) satisfying (6) actually induces a symmetric efficient sequential equilibrium. No­ tice that a firm has no incentive to offer a price below a since a firm setting a already almost surely attracts all consumers who visit a price agency.

First we show that a consumer will never choose to go to the price agency after visiting k firms. Let x be the smallest observed price. Assume th at x = 0. Then the expenditure including search cost of going to the price agency equals

s + b+p B(n-k)- Since s + 6+ps(n-*:) > s + b+pBn = s + p > 0 a consumer offered the good at price 0 strictly prefers buying over going to the price agency. Now consider the case where x < 0. Then the disutility of going to the price agency equals

s

+ b + J

p

(n — k) f

(p) [1 —

F

(p)]"-*-1

dp

+ [1 —

F

(a:)]"-*

x

.

Using the fact that the derivative of the above expression with respect to x equals

(1 ~ F ( x ) r k

we obtain that the consumer strictly prefers buying at a firm who charges x over going to the price agency.

Finally, we show that each consumer buys at the first firm visited. Consider a consumer’s behavior after searching n — 1 firms with x being the lowest price offered by these firms. Expenditure including search cost of going to the n-th firm equals

s + [ P f (p) dp + (1 - F (x)) x ,

Jo

expenditure when not going to the n-th firm is x. We will show that the indi­ vidual never strictly prefers to visit the n-th firm, i.e., that

x < s + [ p f (p) dp + (1 — F (x)) x (7)

Jo

given 0 < s + p . Notice that (7) is true when x = 0. Moreover, the derivative of the right hand side with respect to x for x < 0 equals 1 — F (x) < lan d hence (7) holds for all x € [a,/?].

Now consider the choice of whether to visit the (n — l)-th firm. Since the n-th firm will never be visited it is as if there is not an n-th firm. By induction on the number of firms it then follows that each consumer buys at the first firm visited as long as 0 < s + p. In particular, this implies th at a firm will choose

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(16)

0 = s + p since sales at price 0 axe only made'to consumers who do not consult

the price agency and consumers will buy if p < s + p. This completes the proof.

Next we discuss when such equilibria exist together with some of their properties. It is easily verified that 6 (0) = 1, 6 (1) = 0 and that h is continuous and decreasing in 7 as

h' ( 7) = ( n - 1)7(1 -1 7) -h + 1 1 - 7

— 7 + 717 < 0

Given 0 < s < 1 let 7 = 7 (s) € (0,1) be the unique solution to h (7) = 1 — s. Then it follows from (6) that the probability that a consumer visits a price agency in one of our equilibria is at least 7. Now consider some 7 6 [7,1). Then the price distribution F is well defined which implies that p — pBn > 0. So if

then (6) is satisfied. Hence, any 7 € [7,1) (and only these) can be supported by an efficient sequential equilibrium if the tariff 6 is chosen appropriately. In particular, 7 = 7 and 6= 1— s/7 > 0 can be supported in which case the largest price offered equals the monopoly price 1 (i.e., 0 = 1), expected price p is maximal and consumers are indifferent between not buying and buying the good (either at a random firm or via the price agency). When 7 > 7 then all prices are bounded away from 1 and consumers strictly prefer to purchase the good. For 7 close to 1, the tariff 6 supporting this equilibrium as well as the expected price is close to 0 (while the maximal price 0 is close to s) as p > pgn,

P — PBn is continuous in 7 and p gets small as 7 gets close to 1. In particular,

C o ro llary 3 An efficient equilibrium exists when 0 < 6 < 1 — s /7.

It remains unclear whether efficient equilibria only exist if 6 < 1 — s/7 and whether equilibrium demand for price agencies is decreasing in the tariff (although both statements are easily verified for n € {2,3}, see appendix). Of course, efficient equilibria (as well as any other sequential equilibria with trade) fail to exist if s is sufficiently small for given 6 since a consumer strictly prefers visiting each firm over going to the price agency whenever (n — 1) s < b. Similarly, equilibria with trade fail to exist when s is sufficiently large for given 6

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(17)

since consumers will not participate in search whenever b > 1 — s as this implies that p+ s > 1. When there are only three firms then the set of (s, b) constellations where efficient equilibria exist can be calculated explicitly (calculations given in the appendix, regions illustrated in Figure 1).

When price agencies are sufficiently attractive (i.e., their tariff b is suf­ ficiently small) for given s then efficient equilibria exist. Demand 7 for their services will be arbitrarily close to 1 and the expected market price will be arbi­ trarily close to 0. Almost all surplus will go to the consumers. When there are either two or three firms, then comparative statics for intermediate values of b are also available as the demand for price agencies is decreasing in their price. Lowering b decreases the maximal, the minimal and the expected price of the good. This makes consumers better off and firms worse off (changes in profits of the price agency will be analyzed in the next section).

Efficient equilibria do not exist for extreme values of the individual search cost s given b. Again, comparative statics can be obtained for intermediate values only when n € {2,3} . Increasing s leads to two opposite effects. Since

p is increasing in s for given 7 we find that a higher individual search cost has a tendency to raise prices. On the other hand, there is a substitution effect between individual search and going to the price agency. Increasing s is like decreasing b. For given b, as s increases, the demand for services of the price agencies increases. This causes a decrease in normalized prices h = p//3. In the appendix we show that the latter effect dominates the former as we find that expected prices are decreasing in the search costs s. Of course, expected prices remain above b so that eventually, when s is too large then an efficient equilibrium fails to exist as b = p — pBn can no longer be satisfied. Whether or not consumers are in fact better off when search costs s increase depends on the change of s + p. The substitution effect is strongest when search costs are small (i.e., when equilibrium demand is small). For n — 2 we find that consumers are better off if and only if the equilibrium demand is below 0.635, for n = 3 this is the case when 7 is below 0.786. Figures 2 and 3 show the graph of p as a function of s where b = 0.05 and n = 2 or n = 3. In particular, we find that there is only a relatively small range of search costs s where an increase in s makes the consumers better off (s € (0.17,0.274) for n = 2, s € (0.0 66,0.14) for n = 3).

The calculations of the equilibrium strategies when there axe either two or three firms (see appendix) also reveal the explicit pricing strategy of a firm.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(18)

While the price density is decreasing for n = 2, it is u-shaped for n = 3; there is a higher concentration of prices at the extreme ends of the price interval [a, /?] with the density at /? being unbounded (the later remains true for n > 3).

Equilibrium characteristics can also be derived when the market is very competitive. In particular, our next proposition reveals that efficient equilibria exist when n is sufficiently large for given b and s with b < 1 — s. Price agencies become very attractive and each consumer consults one with an arbitrarily high probability. Firms either compete for consumers who visit the price agency and charge a price close to 0 (bargain) or they exploit the uninformed and charge a high price (rip-off) slightly above the price agencies’ tariff (actually a price close to b -f s). Asymptotically, bargains and rip-offs are offered with probabilities

s / (b + s) and b/ (b + s) and the expected market price equals b. All surplus is

divided between price agencies and consumers.

P ro p o s itio n 4 For b < 1 — s and £ 6 (0, b + s) there exists no such that n > no

implies there exists 7n G (1 — e, 1) with

K [in) < 1 b = 1 - — Is 7n / max {|Fn (e) - s / (b + s )| ,\Fn (b + s - e) ~ K (7„) s / ( b + s )|} < £

P ro o f. Following Corollary 3 the proof of the existence of an efficient equi­ librium for sufficiently large n and given b is complete once we show that lim info.,,» 7n = 1 where hn (qn) = 1 — s. Assume that liminf7n = 1 — 6 < 1. Setting 7 = 7n and 0 n = s / { l - h (7J ) = 1,

lim sup [1 — Fn (p)] = lim sup = 1

for any given p < 1. Thus, hn (7n) > 1 — s holds once n is sufficiently large. This however contradicts the fact that 1 = s + hn (7n) holds for all n. Hence, lim inf 7n = 1.

Now consider the equilibria induced by tariff b and 7 = 7n. Since j n > 7n, we obtain limn_oo7n = 1. Hence, (3 = b + s/-yn tends to b + s as n —> 00. (5) implies that psn tends to 0 and hence lim ,,^^ p (n) = l i m ^ ^ b + pBn = b.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(19)

Let

v := 1 — lim infn—* oo

For any fixed p 6 (0, 6 + s ), we obtain lim inf,,-,,» Fn (p) = ia Hence, lim inf„_oo p (n) = (1 — i/)(b + s). Comparing this to the fact that limn_ 00 p(n) = b we obtain i' = s/(6 + s). Repeating the same argument for lim sup then completes the proof. ■

3.2

M o n o p o listic P rice A gencies and C ollusion

While the price agencies’ tariff was assumed exogenous above, we now include price agencies as players. For simplicity, assume zero cost for price agencies to obtain information about prices charged. The results below are readily gener­ alized to include fix and constant marginal costs. At first we consider a single monopolistic price agency who publicly determines its tariff b before prices are set and consumers search. This price agency aims to maximize its expected profits 7Tp = 7 • b.

In this enlarged game, each possible choice b of the price agency induces a subgame. In each of these subgames there are multiple sequential equilibria including one that induces market failure (see the beginning of Section 3.1). In the following, we focus on efficient sequential equilibria in which trade is efficient in each subgame in which this is possible; when b is chosen such that there exists 7 € [7,1] with

then firms and consumers follow an efficient sequential equilibrium of this sub­ game as characterized in Proposition 2. Since b is chosen to maximize expected profits, an alternative interpretation of the analysis of this section is that we are searching for the efficient sequential equilibrium that maximizes the joint profits attainable by colluding price agencies.

In our next result we measure price dispersion by the normalized differ­ ence between average price charged by firms and the minimal price charged in the market; prices p are normalized by dividing by 0. So expected price dis­ persion in an efficient equilibrium equals (p — PBn) /0- Our next results shows that maximum profits are obtained precisely when expected price dispersion is maximal. © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(20)

P ro p o sitio n 5 Consider the equilibria characterized in Proposition 2. Then

i. The profit np of a price agency is maximal if and only if the expected price dispersion {p — pBn) / P Is maximal.

ii. There exist s°, 7* € (0,1) such that:

(a) I f s < s° then the profit maximum is attained when demand equals

7*; in this case all consumers strictly prefer to purchase the good and

a, P, p, 7Tf, b and 7Tp are proportional to s.

(b) I f s > s° then profit maximizing demand is greater than 7*. If in addition n € {2,3} then consumers are indifferent between buying and not buying and expected prices are decreasing in s.

P ro o f. The proof of part 1 is complete once we show arg max < -—777—r - l|/i (7) < 1 - s

7€(0,1) [1 - h( ~f )

= arg max {h (7) - g (7) |h (7) < 1 - s} 7€(0,1)

where g — Pbu/ P ■ Following (5), g = g (7) = (1 — 7) (1 — h) /7 and hence,

h — g = 1 — (1 — h) /7 is maximized if and only if (1 — /z) /7 minimized if and only if 7/ (1 — h) is maximized. Thus the claim is proven.

Notice that h (7) < 1 — s if and only if P (7) = s / (1 — h (7)) < 1. Let 7* be the largest maximizer of the heterogeneity h — g, i.e.,

7* = max j arg max {h (7) — g (7) : 0 < 7 < 1} j .

Then 7* (0,1). Let s° = 1 — h (7*). Then s < s° implies h (7*) < 1 s and

hence,

7* £ arg max {76 (7) \h (7) < 1 — s} .

The fact that a , 3, p, ttf, b and 7Tp £ire all proportional to s follows from

(6) and the fact that 7* does not depend on s.

If s > s° then h (7*) > 1 — s so h (7) < 1 — s implies 7 > 7*.

For n € (2,3} , b is decreasing in 7 and price heterogeneity is concave in 7. Consequently, s > s° implies th at demand equals 7 and 6 = 1 — s/7 in the profit maximizing efficient equilibrium. In this case, p = 1 • h (7) = 1 — s. ■

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(21)

Table 8 gives the explicit values of the equilibrium parameters from Propo­ sition 5 when n € {2,3} and s < s° (calculations contained in the appendix). Notice how the comparative statics in search cost s have changed in comparison to our analysis in Section 3.1 for a fixed tariff b. When s is small, the price agency chooses a small tariff which makes consumers strictly prefer to buy the good. Increasing s, the price agency offsets increased demand for its services due to increase in individual search cost s by increasing its tariff b. Demand 7 in fact remains unchanged and hence expected prices increase as firms take advantage of higher search costs. When s is above s°, the price agency charges the highest tariff under which consumers are still willing to participate in the search for the good. Increases in s are now compensated by decreases in 6 as the price agency has to make itself more attractive to compensate for higher individual search costs. Expected price decreases to keep total consumer utility unchanged.

Next we consider the profit maximizing sequential equilibrium found in Proposition 5 when there are many firms. As we already saw in the case where tariffs were fixed (Proposition 4), price agencies become very attractive when there are many firms. Thus, it is not astonishing that we find below that the monopolistic price agency sets its tariff close to the maximal level 1 — s and still attracts most consumers. The rest of the results for fixed tariffs carry over. Most prices are either bargains close to 0 or rip-offs which are now close to the monopoly level 1. Approximately a fraction 1 — s of the firms offer a rip-off resulting in an expected market price close to the maximal level 1 — s. Almost all consumers go to the price agency, they are nearly indifferent to not participating in the search. In particular, this means that the cutoff level s° from Proposition 5 tends to 0 as n tends to infinity.

P ro p o sitio n 6 For given s > 0, consider a sequence n = 1,2,.. of efficient

sequential equilibria indexed by the number of firms in the market where efficient trade occurs in subgames whenever possible. Then the equilibrium parameters satisfy

lim q„ = 0, lim = lim Q. = 1, lim p„ = lim bn = 1 — s

n — oo n —mx> n —*00 n —*oo n —» oo

andlim^Fn (p,^n, 0 n) = s for any 0< p < 1.

P ro o f. Write equilibrium parameters as a function of the equilibrium value of demand 7. Let 7’ be the profit maximizing level and let 7n solve hn (7n) = 1 — s.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(22)

Following the proof of Proposition 4, limn^ oc,7n = 1. Since

P n ( i n ) - 7; - s > / ? „ (7n ) • 7„ - S = 7n ~ S

we o b ta in l i m * ^

0n

(7 ; ) = lim n_ 0O7 ; = 1 w hich im plies l i m ^ ^ a , , (7 ; ) = 0 a n d limn-.oo bn (7 *) = 1 — s. U sing th e fact th a t pn (7 n ) = 8n (7*) — s we also o b ta in limn-.ooPn (7 ; ) = 1 - s.

Finally, let

Then lim infn—00 Fn (p, 7*, /? (7*)) = 1/ for 0 < p < 1 which implies lim infn_ QO

pn (7*) = 1 — u. Since limn^ooPn (7*) = 1 — s we obtain v = s. Completing this argument using lim sup instead completes the proof. ■

3.3

C o m p etin g P rice A gen cies

Up to now we assumed that price agencies colluded, or alternatively, that there is a single price agency who acts as a monopolist. Consider now at least two price agencies competing against each other. Instead of explicitly specifying demand and calculating equilibria we discuss the impact of competition with the help of comparative statics in the tariff b. Consider competition among price agencies that leads to all price agencies charging the same tariff where more competition leads to a lower value of the market tariff b. The discussion in Section 3.1 on page 11 reveals that demand for price agencies will be arbitrarily close to 1 and expected market prices arbitrarily close to 0 if competition among the price agencies reduces tariffs close to 0. When either two or three firms are supplying the good then any increase in competition leads to a higher demand for services of the price agencies and lower expected market prices, making consumers better off. However, increased competition need not result in lower price dispersion in the goods market as we observed above th at price dispersion increases initially when tariffs lie above the joint profit maximizing level.

1/ = 1 — lim inf © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(23)

4

M oral H azard and V ariable Tariff S tru ctu res

In our model, as in [Hanchen and von Ungern-Sternberg, 1985], we assume that price agencies actually inquire about the prices promised and then reveal the lowest price truthfully. However, as consumers cannot verify the information provided by the price agency, there is moral hazard. A price agency that incurs a positive cost with each price inquiry would choose to save costs of gathering information and would only check the price of one firm. Consequently, our equilibrium would brake down. One way out of this problem is to include public monitoring of the price agencies. Here we briefly discuss an alternative where we provide the right incentives to a price agency by considering a variable tariff.

It is plausible that a price agency as a firm with many employees has a technology that makes it profitable to sample prices simultaneously instead of in sequence. Consider a tariff system in which the payment to the price agency is decreasing in the price revealed to the consumer. Then, given a sufficiently large number of consumers, the price agency will choose to learn about all prices and to reveal the lowest price to its customers. Variable tariff systems can be found among price agencies acting in Germany where a customer without a price quote researched on his own pays a percentage of the savings relative to the manufacturer’s recommended price.3

To see how such a variable tariff affects our model, assume that the tariff of the price agency equals a percentage of the savings relative to the largest possible market price, i.e. it charges r (/? — pgn) where r € [0,1] is the parameter chosen by the price agency. The indifference condition of consumers analogous to (4) becomes s + r (/? - pan) + PBn = s + p < 1 and hence

= P - P B n _ 1 + h - 1 0 - P B n 7 - ( 1 ---y) ( 1 - h ) '

All results then extend directly to this alternative tariff structure, the only changes being that b has to be replaced by r in the statements. The values of r needed to complete table (8) are r2 = 0.155 and r.3 = 0.297.

3On the other hand, some price agencies charge a tariff that is increasing in the price they find. © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(24)

5

C o n clu d in g R em arks

Information intermediaries such as price agencies facilitate trade and spread information among consumers. They profit from price dispersion and the degree of information in the market, parameters they influence when they fix the price for their services. To obtain a more detailed understanding of their impact, we set up a simple model where price agencies provide information about prices in a homogeneous good oligopoly. We consider sequential search so that consumers are always free to visit one more firm if they are not pleased with the prices previous encountered. Consumers remember which firms they have visited in the past and may go back to any of these at no cost (formally, sampling is without replacement and with free recall). The fact th at consumers remember which firms they have visited complicates the analysis substantially so we rest ambitions to find all sequential equilibria and focus on the efficient ones.4

We find price dispersion where the expected market price inducing trade is always greater than the price agency tariff. Maximal price dispersion obtains when competition among price agencies is weak or when there are many firms. Colluding price agencies deliberately set their tariffs to induce maximal price dispersion as this maximizes their profits. When there are many firms, price agencies become very attractive to consumers and most consumers visit a price agency. Firms consequently face fierce competition for business attracted via a price agency. This leads to extreme price dispersion as firms either offer bargains or rip-offs.

The equilibrium price dispersion uncovered in the seminal paper of Salop and Stiglitz [1977] is driven by heterogeneous consumers. Consumers with low search costs get the bargains while those with high search costs are left with a random draw among the bargains and the rip-offs. Only pure strategy equilibria are considered. Whether or not there is price dispersion depends on the relative search costs. In our model, consumers are identical, differences in their informa­ tion is endogenous. Given many firms we find an analogous result, the informed (which are the customers of the price agencies) get the bargains whereas the others get a random draw. Similar to Burdett and Judd [1983] and Shiloney [1977], we find that ex ante consumer heterogeneity is not necessary to obtain price dispersion. Price dispersion obtains in our model whenever there is trade

4 It is a simple excersize to verify that the equilibrium we characterize are the only sequential equilibrium in which trade occurs when consumers sample with replacement.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(25)

in a sequential equilibrium (see the beginning of Section 2), existence requires that firms choose a mixed pricing strategy. The price distributions generalize the findings of Gale [1988] who considers two firms and an exogenous proportion of informed consumers. In particular, each firm randomizes among an infinite number of different prices. Since we consider only a finite number of firms, our efficient equilibria thus cannot be reinterpreted in a setting in which firms do not randomize and consumers only know the distribution of prices in the market.

In many models (e.g., [Salop and Stiglitz, 1977], [Burdett and Judd, 1983], [Hanchen and von Ungern-Sternberg, 1985]), consumers have a fixed sample size and thus are not allowed to continue their search if they only observed high prices. Thus, some firms charge the monopoly price whenever there is price dispersion. In our model of sequential search, consumers are never forced to buy the good. Consequently, in an efficient equilibrium, the maximal price charged by a firm never differs from expected price by more than the search cost s. In particular, when the price agency tariff is small, then the maximal market price is just above s.

When there are only few firms (n = 2 or 3) then we can derive more spe­ cific results. Demand for price agency services is decreasing in the tariff b, in particular efficient equilibria are unique. Both the expected and the maximal market price are decreasing in the tariff of the price agencies. However, the opposite happens when individual search costs become small. We find a result similar to Samuelson and Zhang [1992] that both expected and maximal price increase when the individual search cost s decreases. When s decreases, substi­ tution effects cause the services of the price agency to become relatively more expensive. This leads to a decrease in the demand for price agencies, consumers are less informed and competition among firms declines. Of course, when search costs s and the tariff b decline by the same percentage then it is immediate that prices decrease too (see (6)).

The only other model (we know) analyzing strategic considerations of price intermediaries when present in goods markets is due to Hanchen and von Ungern- Sternberg [1985]. While the basic questions analyzed in their paper are very similar to ours, their underlying model remains very different. In their “cir­ cular road” market, goods are extremely differentiated (where differentiation is not geographical); no two firms provide the same good for the same con­ sumer. Their intermediary not only provides information about the prices but also about the different characteristics of the goods being offered. Lack of com­

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(26)

petition among firms enables all firms to charge the same price in equilibrium while all consumers visit the price intermediary. In particular, in equilibrium, the information intermediary only provides information on which product is most preferred to a consumer. We set out to investigate some aspects surrounding price intermediation of the form provided by the price agencies found in Europe. These intermediaries provide information only about location and price (includ­ ing transportation cost to the consumer) of a given good. Here the setting of [Hanchen and von Ungern-Sternberg, 1985] seems less applicable. On the side, an interesting extension of either price intermediation model is to assume that only an unknown subset of the firms offer the desired good.

In the most popular tariff employed in Germany, price agencies charge a proportion (typically 30-33%) of the savings relative to a price the consumer has researched on his own. Notice th at our calculations cannot be used to rationalize the use of such tariffs as we focussed on equilibria where consumers who visit a price agency have no information about prices charged in the market. Moreover, as noted in Footnote 4, only these equilibria emerge under the common simpli­ fication that consumers forget which firms they have visited (sampling with replacement and without recall). Thus, it remains an intriguing topic for future research to analyze circumstances where these tariffs are used in equilibrium.

R eferen ces

[1] K. Burdett and K.L. Judd (1983), Equilibrium price dispersion, Economet­

rica 51, 955-970.

[2] P. Diamond (1971), A model of price adjustment, J. Econ. Theory 3, 156- 168.

[3] D. Gale (1988), Price setting and competition in a simple duopoly model,

Quart. J. Econ. 103, 729-739.

[4] T. Hanchen and T. von Ungern-Sternberg (1985), Information costs, inter­ mediation and equilibrium price, Economica 52, 407-419.

[5] J. McMillan and M. Rothschild (1994), Handbook of Game Theory, Voi. 2, R.J. Aumann, S. Hart (eds), Elsevier Science B.V., 906-927.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(27)

[6] S. Salop and J.E. Stiglitz (1977), Bargains and ripoffs: A model of monop­ olistic competition, Rev. Econ. Stud. 44, 493-510.

[7j L. Samuelson and J. Zhang (1992), Search costs and prices, Economics Let­

ters 38, 55-60.

[8] Y. Shilony (1977), Mixed pricing in oligopoly, J. Econ. Theory 14, 373-388.

A

T w o or T h ree firms

In the following we calculate the efficient sequential equilibrium characterized in Proposition 5 when there are either two or three firms in the market. When there are only two firms (i.e., n = 2) then solving the integral in (3) we obtain

*!»(?) f i ( p ) P2 02 h ) PB2 ( l ) 1 _ 1 ^ - 7^

(02~P

A 2 1 - 7 2 7p2 for ~ ^ 0 2 < P < 02 1 + 7 & M 7 ) = 27 17 ______ _________ s 2 7 _ ( i _ 7 ) l n i±a = & - - = 27 27 — (1 — 7) ln i=? T = 0292 (7) = 0\ 1 - 7 02 ( 1 - 7 In 1 + 7 1- 7

Here we find the equilibrium tariff h2 (7) to be decreasing in the proportion of consumers going to the price agency (Figure 4 shows b2 (7) / s as a function of 7). It is easily verified that 762 (7) is convex in 7 and attains its maximum 0.1159s when 72 « 0.635 (Figure 5 shows 762 (7) / s together with the price dispersion ( p ~ P B2) / P as functions of 7). Consequently, s° = 1 — h2 (72) ~ 0.569 and we obtain for s < s° the profit maximizing level 75 with 7Tc = p2 ~ 0.758s, 7Tf « 0.321s, b2 = 0.183s and irP « 0.116s. For s > s°, the profit

maximizing demand 72 solves h ( j 2) = 1 — s and hence 7 2 > 72- The density and c.d.f. of the price distribution for s = 0.1 corresponding to 7 2 is shown in Figure 6 ([a,/3] ~ [0.393s, 1.757s]). © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(28)

For the alternative linear tariff system presented in Section 5 the inverse demand r as a function of 7 for n = 2 is shown in Figure 7, in particular, r (7 ‘) = 0.155.

Similar calculations for the case of three firms (i.e., n = 3) yields

F (p ) = / (p) = P =

03 =

Ò

3

=

, _ f o r < P < h V 37p 1 + 27 03 / I ~ 7 1 2 /?3 'Z 1 ~ 7 2 37 PÌ2\[0 3 ~ V

2 ^

7T / 1 — 47 — - arcsin „ ■ ■ ■ — 2 V 1 + 27 2^ - \ / l - 7 [f - arcsin ( j ^ ) ] - 4 ( 1 - 7 ) v /Jy + y j l - ' r n - 2v /l - 7 arcsin 4 7 \/3 7

- 7v/l

- 77T + 27v /1 - 7arcsin ( y ^ )

Again, we find that 63 is decreasing in 7 and that 6 3 7 is concave. The profit of the price agency 6 3 7 attains is maximum 0.29s at 7 « 0.681. Thus we obtain for

s < s° = 1 — /1.3 ( 7 3 ) « 0.528 that the profit maximizing level 7 3 « 0.681 which

yields p3 » 0.89s, 7T/ « 0.2s, 62 ~ 0.426s and 7Tp « 0.29s. The corresponding density and c.d.f. for s = 0.1 are shown in Figure 8 ([a, (5\ = [0.256s, 1.894s]).

Finally, we provide the main calculations used to show how p changes in s for given b. Given

“ M

(r^À -

7

)

-differentiating b = w(~) (s)) s with respect to s we obtain

0

7'(s)

w’ (7 ) • 7' (s) • s + w (7) —w --- 7 7 Ts • w‘ (7) > 0 and hence, h! (7) w 1 — h w‘ (7) d s P 1 ^ (7) /i (1 - /i);7' (s)s = 1 - h © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(29)

For n = 2 this implies w' (7) d 7 , n l + 7 27 1 — 7 - In 1 + 7 1 - 7 = _ J L i n i ± 7 + 272 1 - 7 7(1+7) + _ 2 (2 7- ( 1- 7) l n | ^ ) V 1 9 sP ■ 2-y I-7 / 27 7 j 1 + 7 ( _ 1 i_ 1±2 1 1 ) ( 27______ l \ ^ \ 2 ^ * 1 - 7 ^ 7 ( 1 + 7 ) / y 2 7 —( 1 —7) I n 7 J (l _ ln l± r) I 2— ^7 ln^7__, + l1 27 l n i - 7 J “ ( 2 7 - 0 - 7 ) , „ 4 ) v +(27- ( l -7) l n | ^ ) / 2J < 0

where numerical calculations reveal that p > —1 holds if and only if 7 > a r g m a x { ( p - p Sll)//3} « 0.635.

For n = 3 we obtain

h'( 7) ^x/7 ____1 __

872^3(1- 7) 27 ( l + 2 7 ) '

Given tc := 6/ s similar though more length calculations show that Jlp < 0 where numerical calculations reveal that Jjp > - 1 holds if and only if 7 > 0.786.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(30)

Table 8: Equilibrium parameters when there are either two or three firms present. Tl b 7* p 7Tj 7Tp 2 0.569 0.183s 0.635 0.758s 0.321s 0.116s (8) 3 0.528 0.426s 0.681 0.89s 0.2s 0.29s © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(31)

b 4

1 .

/ b=2s

0.8 0.6

' . b=1-s

0.4 0.2

/

0 q 0 2 0.4 0.6 0.8 i *s

Figure 1: Shaded area: Parameter range where an efficient sequential equilibr­ ium exists. © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(32)

1j 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 P 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 S

Figure 2: Expected price p as a funtion of search cost s when n = 2 and b = 0.05.

A 1 ■ 0.8 0.6 | i 0.4 0.2 P 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 { * s

Figure 3: Expected price p as a funtion of search cost s when n = 3 and b = 0.05.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(33)

0.4 :

b

s

0.2 0.1 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 *Y

Figure 4: Aggregate indirect demand of price agencies per unit search cost when

n = 2.

Figure 5: Aggregate price agency profits per individual search cost and price dispersion when n = 2. © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(34)

A 35 . 30 • 25 j I 20 15

j

10

i

5 ; 0 .

price density f

0.05 0.1 0.15 ' 0.2** P

Figure 6: Equilibrium price density when s = 0.1 and n = 2.

0.25 0.2’ 0 .1 5 0.1 j 0.05 \

\

0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0 .8 1 Y

Figure 7: Inverse demand of price agencies under the alternative tariff system.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(35)

4 25 20 | l 15 ; p r i c e d e n s i t y f 10 • \

\

5 . 0 0 0.05 0.1 0.15

Figure 8: Equilibrium price density when s =

0.2 p 0.1 and n = 3. © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(36)

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(37)

EUI

WORKING

PAPERS

EUI Working Papers are published and distributed by the European University Institute, Florence

Copies can be obtained free of charge - depending on the availability of stocks - from:

The Publications Officer European University Institute

Badia Fiesolana

1-50016 San Domenico di Fiesole (FI) Italy © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(38)

Publications of the European University Institute

To The Publications Officer European University Institute Badia Fiesolana

1-5(X) 16 San Domenico di Fiesole (FI) - Italy Fax: +39-055-4685 636

e-mail: pubIish@datacomm.iue.it http://www.iue.it

From N am e... Address...

□ Please send me a complete list of EU1 Working Papers □ Please send me a complete list of EUI book publications □ Please send me the EUI brochure Academic Year 2000/2001 Please send me the following EUI Working Paper(s):

Dept, n°, author ... Title: ... Dept, n°, author ... Title: ... Dept, n°, author ... Title: ... Dept, n°, author ... Title: ... D a te... Signature

X

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

Les recherches menées dans ce domaine, à part leur attrait pour les positivistes du XIX e siècle, rendirent possible la publication des premières éditions critiques d’actes anciens

Results of this study and our past ones [24–25] indicate that the factors important for pleasantness perception during active touch, such as the average roughness (or

Accordingly, the source-filter theory of voice production has recently been proved to allow a far greater understanding of the information encoded in banded penguins

Supplementary Materials: The following are available online at http://www.mdpi.com/2072-6694/11/1/101/s1 , Figure S1: RhoU promoter analysis in MEF cells, Figure S2: Downregulation

ChardonnaY, Pinot neroo Cabernet, Pinot grigio e Teroldego sono ri- sultati i più ricchi di aminoa- cidi; viceversa, Marzemino, Múller-Thurgau, Nosiola e Schiava erano i più

Extracellular DNA, whether released in biofilm by bacteria, in RETs by root cap cells or in NETs by neutrophils or other cell types, has key structural, and functional roles that

CNV chart related to a single cell from SK-N-BE (2)-C showing, from left to right, partial gain of chromosome 1, partial loss of chromosomes 3, partial gain of chromosomes 7 and 11,

At the same time, an exhaustive comparative study of the fossil Hipparionini assemblages from the As Saha- bi site (Libya) and from Tizi’n Tadderht site (Moroc- co), will allow us