• Non ci sono risultati.

When Ideas Fail to Influence Policy Outcomes: Orderly Liberalization and the International Monetary Fund

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "When Ideas Fail to Influence Policy Outcomes: Orderly Liberalization and the International Monetary Fund"

Copied!
43
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

This is an author version of the contribution published on:

Review of International Political Economy,

2009, 16 (5), pp. 854-82. doi: 10.1080/09692290902725655

The definitive version is available at:

http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/09692290902725655#.UxYoYKXnX

G4

(2)

When Ideas Fail to Influence Policy Outcomes:

Orderly Liberalization and the International Monetary Fund

Manuela Moschella

This paper investigates a case of failure of economic ideas at bringing about institutional change. The idea in question is the policy idea of orderly liberalization that dominated the thinking of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) in the early 1990s. Positing the desirability of capital

liberalization and the ineffectiveness of controls, the policy idea of orderly liberalization also prescribed to strengthen the powers of the IMF over capital flows to minimize the risks entailed

(3)

in their free movement. The institutional change is the proposal to amend the Fund’s

constitutional charter, its Articles of Agreement. The amendment, which would have allowed the IMF to promote the liberalization of cross-border capital flows, was launched in 1995 and disappeared from the IMF’s books in the late 1998.

Why did the idea of orderly liberalization help to forge consensus around the amendment in 1995? Why did the consensus unravel in 1998? Or, more broadly, under what conditions are economic ideas able to influence policy outcomes within the Fund? In answering these questions, the paper engages with the literature on policy change in international political economy (IPE), seeking to specify the mechanisms of influence of economic ideas and lack thereof. While this literature has gone far towards specifying the actors and the mechanisms through which ideas successfully bring about institutional change (Berman 1998; Blyth 2002; Parsons 2003; Seabrooke 2007a), we still do not have a full picture of the conditions that allow ideas to be influential. Hence, investigating a case of ‘non-decision,’ as Susan Strange (1988, 22) would have put it, may help specify what factors nullify the power of economic ideas and, vice versa, magnify it. Furthermore, explicitly studying a case of failure may help face the criticism that we know about the power of ideas because scholars have solely explored cases of ideas that

‘worked’ (Legro 1997, 34).

Although the analysis of the factors that lead to the failure of ideas has received only limited attention yet, the extant literature does contain two sets of implicit hypotheses – the external sponsorship and bureaucratic culture hypotheses. The first draws from the argument that economic ideas are consequential when powerful advocates sponsor them (Goldstein 1993), the corollary hypothesis being that they fail when the sponsors withdraw their support. Applied to the case under investigation, the hypothesis is that the amendment got through to the extent that

(4)

it was backed from the outside by the powerful U.S. Treasury-Wall Street complex (Bhagwati 1998; Wade and Veneroso 1998) and was ultimately dropped when the political sponsorship vanished. The second set of hypotheses builds on the literature on epistemic communities, thereby emphasizing factors such as the role of experts in the decision-making process and organizational culture (Barnett and Finnemore 2004; Momani 2005). The argument is that the idea of orderly liberalization gained political influence from the inside because of the common professional background of IMF staff members (Chwieroth 2007c; Leiteritz 2005) and because some of its most outspoken advocates held key posts in the Fund’s bureaucracy (Abdelal 2007, Ch. 6). The implicit conclusion here is that the idea of orderly liberalization lost its influence as a result of turnover of staff members who had been instrumental in promoting the idea.

The external sponsorship and bureaucratic culture hypotheses are two important perspectives informing the analysis of policy change within IOs. However, they leave some important questions unresolved. The puzzle that the external sponsorship hypothesis is unable to explain is why member countries chose to delegate so much authority to an international

organization. In particular, the external sponsorship hypothesis has difficulty in explaining why weaker states eagerly decided to amend the IMF’s Articles thereby expanding the IMF’s powers, if this policy simply reflected the economic interests of the powerful countries. The puzzle that the bureaucratic culture hypothesis cannot explain is why the amendment eventually failed. Under the bureaucratic culture view, we would expect a cultural change within the organization to account for policy change. Nevertheless, this paper finds little support for this hypothesis especially in light of the absence of a significant turnover of IMF staff when the amendment was finally abandoned.

(5)

This paper argues that the limited explanatory power of extant hypotheses derives from their one-dimensional focus on one set of variables over the other – be it the economic interests of powerful members or the technical expertise of IMF staff. Rather, explaining the variation in the influence of economic ideas over time requires combining both external and internal factors. Specifically, the argument is that a full understanding of the variation in the influence of ideas over time requires an evolutionary approach that conceives of the influence of ideas as a fluid process that takes place within a dynamic historical context where ideas and interests are not ‘independent’ but ‘interdependent’ variables (Adler 1991; Blyth 2002, 18; Steinmo 2003, 229). The paper therefore examines how the idea of orderly liberalization, which was developed inside the IMF within an economic context characterized by a dramatic increase in the size of cross-border capital flows, influenced the policy reforms for the world’s financial sector in 1995; and how changes in the historical/economic context influenced the successive process of policy change in 1997. In particular, the empirical analysis traces the emergence of orderly

liberalization within the Fund against the early 1990s changes in the global economy. With an increasing number of developing countries accessing and benefiting from global financial integration, the idea of orderly liberalization became persuasive among the Fund’s membership and the private sector. Not even the 1994 Mexican financial crisis undermined the emerging consensus. Rather, the fact that capital flows to developing countries quickly returned to record levels and that the consequences of the crisis were contained led policy makers to institutionalize the idea of orderly liberalization by agreeing on the amendment to the Fund’s Articles. When the global economy changed in 1997, however, following the Asian financial crisis, the

(6)

beneficial and rewarding for member countries’ economies leading policy makers to back step on the amendment.

Despite the focus on the interaction between ideas and the environment in which they are floated, this article offers more than a story about experiential learning. Indeed, the influence of the idea of orderly liberalization was not dissipated in light of accumulated knowledge and policy failure that led to falsification of theory within the IMF expert community. For instance, although the Mexican crisis revealed the risks of global financial integration, it was not

interpreted as a policy failure that marked a re-assessment of previously held ideas. Rather, the idea of orderly liberalization survived the crisis almost unscathed. Furthermore, the theoretical re-positioning of the IMF on capital account liberalization, with the IMF nowadays emphasizing the importance of preconditions and sequencing before opening to international markets,

followed and not anticipated the policy choices pursued after the Asian crisis. That is to say, the amendment fell through before IMF economists developed a more skeptical reading of the relationship between liberalization and economic growth in light of new empirical evidence. The process of policy change is therefore more than the result of a process of knowledge

accumulation governed by IMF experts. It is the result of the interaction between technical as well as political actors.

What this paper shows is therefore how important it is that IMF economists gain policy makers’ acceptance about what works and what does not in economic policy. In other words, this paper draws attention to legitimacy feedbacks as a mechanism through which ideas are

influential over time. Indeed, what ultimately mattered for the ratification of the amendment was not that it was based on the economic interests of powerful members or on the accumulated knowledge of the IMF expert community. Rather, what mattered was that the policy idea

(7)

resonated with the larger political environment made up of member countries and the private sector that constitute the Fund’s social constituencies for legitimation at the elites level (Seabrooke 2007b). The feedback coming from these actors, expressed in the form of consent and opposition, was pivotal in shaping the trajectory of the amendment. Until members and private sector actors legitimated the idea of orderly liberalization by publicly supporting its assumptions, the amendment was high on the Fund’s agenda. When those actors, however, questioned the tenets of the idea of orderly liberalization, it was no longer possible for its advocates to keep the amendment on course.

The comparison between the Mexican and the Asian crisis well illustrates the importance of the feedback coming from member countries and the private sector in shaping IMF policies. Indeed, although the Mexican crisis was a crisis characterized by a sharp reversal of international capital flows, it did not unleash a backlash against the idea of orderly liberalization neither within nor outside the Fund. The evidence drawn from the crisis probably falsified the theory in favor of global capital integration as some economists pointed out (Krugman 1995), but it did not discard its social legitimacy. After the Asian crisis, however, the idea of orderly liberalization went profoundly challenged outside the Fund. While IMF economists continued interpreting the crisis as a traditional currency crisis, the IMF faced a variety of criticisms for its management of what came to be identified as a capital crisis. In an attempt to respond to the criticisms coming from member countries and the private sector, the Executive Board started reconsidering the IMF’s position on capital account liberalization. In other words, in contrast to the Mexican crisis, the Asian crisis did not simply falsify the theory of orderly liberalization. It also triggered a crisis of legitimacy that undermined the consensus around the idea of orderly liberalization.

(8)

The paper is organized as follows. The analysis begins by sketching the proposal to amend the Articles and by discussing the variety of factors that are involved in an attempt of explanation, detailing the theoretical framework adopted here. Then, the paper traces the

emergence (Section II), acceptance (Section III), and rejection (Section IV) of the idea of orderly liberalization across the Fund’s social constituencies for legitimation and examines how the feedback coming from those constituencies shaped the influence of the idea of orderly liberalization over time. The paper concludes reflecting on the theoretical and empirical

implications of the findings, suggesting possible avenues of future research on both the IMF and policy change.

I. MAJOR CHANGES IN THE FUND’S INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN

According to its original Articles, which were drafted at Bretton Woods in 1944, the IMF has the responsibility to promote the liberalization of current account transactions (i.e. goods and

services) but not capital account (i.e. debt, portfolio equity, and direct and real estate

investment). As a result, member countries have the right to introduce controls on capital flows at their will. The 1995 proposal to amend the Articles to give the IMF authority over

international capital flows thereby entailed a substantial modification of the institutional design drafted in the post-world war era. Indeed, member countries would have to remove capital controls and to seek Fund’s approval for temporary recourse to capital controls.

In recent years, a number of scholars have analysed the capital account amendment to provide some insights into the inner workings of international organizations. Although these scholarly works mainly focus on the role that neoliberal ideas had in shaping the choice to amend

(9)

the Articles, their explanations differ in the identification of the mechanisms through which ideas were institutionalized. In what follows, I review some of the available explanations in turn.

External Sponsorship and Bureaucratic Culture Hypotheses

A first group of scholars has drawn attention to the economic interests of powerful members, thereby hypothesizing that the crucial mechanism for ideas to be consequential is the identity of the sponsorship. From this perspective, the amendment reflected the interests of the U.S.-Wall Street Treasury complex, which was trying to institutionalize the principle of capital mobility in the charter of the IMF (Bhagwati 1998; Wade and Veneroso 1998). Another group of scholars has emphasized the Fund’s organizational features. For instance, it has been noted that the amendment reflected the ideas embedded in the Fund’s organizational culture (Leiteritz 2005) or those held by a group of IMF top officials that took on the mission to promote capital account liberalization even in the absence of a clear mandate from its principals (Abdelal 2007). Using quantitative methods to demonstrate the power of new ideas in prompting change inside the Fund, Jeffrey Chwieroth (2007c) has convincingly argued that the massive recruitment of staff trained in ‘neoliberal’ departments during the 1980s provided the basis for the IMF staff to advance the proposal to amend the Articles. Drawing this argument to its logical conclusion, the underlying hypothesis is that the mechanisms through which ideas translated into the decision to amend the Articles are the degree of intellectual homogeneity of its staff and their access to the decision-making process.

While both hypotheses disclose important insights, they nonetheless do not provide a satisfactory explanation of the negotiations on the amendment. For instance, it is true that the proposal to amend the Articles was supported by virtually all industrialized countries in general

(10)

and the United States in particular. However, contrary to the expectations of the external sponsorship view, the historical record does not lend significant support to the hypothesis that the U.S. actively pushed for the amendment within the IMF Board. Rawi Abdelal (2007, Ch 6), for instance, has provided significant empirical evidence to dispute the argument that the

initiative to amend the IMF’s Articles was a U.S.-led one. Furthermore, the external sponsorship view has difficulty in explaining why weaker states eagerly accepted a policy (i.e. the

amendment) that reflected the economic interests of the most powerful member countries. In other words, the external sponsorship school does not identify the mechanisms through which developing countries converged around the proposal to amend the Articles. This is not to deny the influence of the U.S. on the Fund’s policymaking process but to warn against identifying it as the main mechanism through which economic ideas become consequential in terms of the Fund’s policies.

The bureaucratic culture hypothesis, in turn, lacks convincing explanatory power when it comes to the failure of the amendment. Indeed, no high turnover took place inside the Fund to substantiate the claim that the influence of economic ideas is intrinsically linked with the professional background of IMF staff. Furthermore, there is no substantial evidence that IMF experts quickly learned from the evidence provided by the Asian crisis thereby leading the IMF to abandon the amendment. As the empirical sections are going to show, the Fund’s early interpretation of the crisis did not reject the assumptions on the benefits of liberalization and on the ineffectiveness of capital controls.

This article argues that the sponsorship and the bureaucratic culture hypotheses are vulnerable to a common criticism. They both underestimate the role of Fund’s membership in shaping and constraining the content of the IMF’s policies. They have largely ignored the fact

(11)

that the IMF is an intergovernmental organization, that is, an organization made by states to solve states’ economic problems and that draws its legitimacy from states. Without membership sanction and validation of its activities, the IMF could hardly be the influential organization that it has become over the decades. The Fund’s advice on fiscal or structural adjustment, for

instance, could hardly have been influential on member countries’ economic policy choices had members not recognized the Fund’s rightness and responsibility in promoting ‘sound’ policies. In what follows, I thereby suggest an evolutionary approach that brings to the surface the thus far neglected element of social legitimation.

An Evolutionary Approach: Interests and Ideas in Explaining the IMF’s Policies

In the attempt to specify how ideas have political consequences, the theoretical approach developed here builds on two assumptions. The first builds on the view that ideas are ‘contested and contingent’ (Katzenstein 1996, 3). The second assumption draws on the argument that the influence of an economic idea is inherently relational. The first assumption highlights that ideas do not appear in a vacuum but are embedded in a political-economic environment in which they are debated and checked against existing empirical evidence. As a result, ideas are neither fixed nor fully formed but subject to evolution. The influence of ideas thereby varies over time. The second assumption suggests that the influence of ideas does not only vary over time but also across actors. Not only are ideas assessed against available evidence but also against existing interests. As Peter Hall (1989, 369-70) put it, ‘the persuasiveness of economic ideas depends, in part at least, on the way those ideas relate to the economic and political problems of the day.’ For instance, the paper shows how the idea of orderly liberalization emerged in the context of both the changing global economy and the political demands of policy makers. Specifically, the idea

(12)

of orderly liberalization gained a widening international audience as the global economy changed and revealed new political needs for both industrial and developing countries. As the empirical analysis will show later, the idea of orderly liberalization, which laid down the arguments in favor of global financial integration, related to the concerns of industrial countries that wanted to consolidate and expand globalization across the globe. The same idea, however, also resonated with the needs of developing and emerging market countries, which interpreted international capital flows as a means to achieve higher levels of income and stability. In other words, the idea of orderly liberalization was institutionalized in the 1995 proposal to amend the Articles in part because of the experience of policy makers. Indeed, when the economy changed in the aftermath of the 1997 Asian crisis, policy elites’ experience with the seemingly disastrous international capital flows led them to re-assess previous ideas and policy choices, including the amendment that was abandoned.

The relationship between ideas and the environment as highlighted in this paper is not meant to suggest that the external environment instructed policy makers about what policies to adopt in order to manage the global economy. In particular, the idea-environment relationship is not meant to suggest that the process of policy change is simply the result of experiential

learning according to which change takes place in light of better information, new evidence or policy failures (Cyert and March 1963; Levy 1994, 283). Experiential learning is thereby conceived of an epiphenomenal process in which all actors draw the same inferences from experience and act accordingly on them.

The explanation of change supported in this paper builds on an alternative explanation to the experiential learning one. Specifically, under an evolutionary approach, actors do not

(13)

by the continuous transformation of the global economy and by their understanding about how the economy works. History, indeed, is not seen here as given fact but as an event that needs to be interpreted (Best 2005, 5; Widmaier 2007). As Friedrich Kratochvil (2006, 21) put it, ‘history is not simply there’ but ‘it is always viewed from a particular vantage point.’ In other words, experience is rarely available in explicit and uncontested form. Seen from this perspective, the experiential learning suffers from some major pitfalls. In particular, it seems unable to tell us how experience is assessed (what does constitute relevant evidence?) and how policy failure is identified (what does constitute failure?). For instance, it would have been plausible to interpret the Mexican crisis as an example of policy failure – i.e. the failure of the ideas favouring market opening. Nevertheless, in the aftermath of the Mexican crisis, policymakers sitting at the IMF tables decided not to stop the process of global financial integration but to intensify it by giving the Fund the powers to promote liberalization. Similarly, despite the successful experience of the Chilean capital controls, until the late 1990s ideas in favour of controls did not retain intellectual respectability.

Since reality needs interpretation, ideas play a crucial role by providing the cognitive map through which actors interpret experience, select among empirical evidence and dismiss

discrepant ideas – as it happened to the ideas in favour of capital controls. The idea of orderly liberalization well exemplifies the tasks an idea performs. Indeed, that idea provided, at least for a while, the common cognitive map through which different actors (such as IMF staff and member countries) interpreted the same phenomenon (i.e the revival of global financial integration). After 1997, however, the idea of orderly liberalization ceased to provide the common map for experts and policymakers around the world. This ideational shift thereby discloses an important question that needs to be addressed. Specifically, it calls for identifying

(14)

the mechanisms through which an idea becomes the idea around which policies are organized at a given moment.

It is at this point that legitimacy acquires crucial importance. Indeed, ideas are powerful to the extent that the actors affected by them recognize their legitimacy by providing support. It is therefore necessary to define the concept of legitimacy and the identity of the actors whose support is necessary for legitimacy to be in place.

The concept of legitimacy used here differs from the traditional concept of legitimacy used in political science to identify the ‘Westminster model’ of democracy. Specifically, I am not going to use the notion of legitimacy to provide insights into the democratic credentials of the IMF addressing questions of representation, political involvement and participation to the decision making process.i If the traditional notion of legitimacy may be defined as institutional legitimacy, the concept of legitimacy used here may better defined as relational legitimacy. That is to say, legitimacy is not a property of the IMF political system that can be gained through institutional reforms, such as decision-making and governance reforms. Rather, legitimacy is an inter-subjective belief in the validity of an idea (Weber 1978) and it is thereby ‘dependent on a collective audience’ (Suchman 1995, 594). It follows that legitimacy is actively given by public support that derives from how the actors affected by IMF policies evaluate them. The output of the evaluation of IMF policies, then, is not simply the result of a calculation of interests – whereas actors support IMF policies because the latter accrue actors’ interests. The relationship between the IMF and the actors that grant it legitimacy is more profound. Not only is support based on the evaluation of whether the policy benefits an actor but on the judgment of whether the policy is the right and appropriate thing to do. Indeed, actors rarely follow in policies that do

(15)

not believe themselves. In short, the collective views that actors hold about the IMF itself are central to the activities of the Fund (Broome 2008).

These observations lead us to investigate the identity of the actors that grant legitimacy to the IMF. For the purpose of this article, the relevant actors that form the Fund’s social constituencies for legitimation include state representatives and private actors such as international investors. In other words, although the Fund’s constituencies may well include non-elite actors such as citizens affected by IMF policies (Seabrooke 2007b; Thirkell-White 2004), the focus of this study is narrowed down on elites. Drawing on Chris Reus-Smit (2007), indeed, the boundaries of an actor’s constituency can be drawn ‘only … with reference to the political realm he or she seeks to act.’ Given the attempt to expand the Fund’s political realm to capital liberalization, both member countries and private sector actors fall within those boundaries in that the Fund’s promotion of capital liberalization would have affected them. On the one hand, extending Fund jurisdiction to capital movements entailed a new obligation for member states. As already pointed out, whereas under the present Articles, members have the right to introduce controls at their will, an amended Article VIII would have imposed an obligation on each member to remove controls. On the other hand, the amendment impinged on the realm of the private sector. Had the amendment won support, member countries would have to obtain the approval of the Fund for the temporary use of capital controls. With the approval of the Fund, an amended Article VIII Section 2(b) would have granted each member a right not to enforce private contracts by postponing their enforcement when these contacts are contrary to the control regulation of that member. In other words, at least in theory, the extension of the IMF’s powers to the promotion of capital liberalization would have affected the exercise of creditor rights although only temporarily.

(16)

Hence, the variation in the influence of the idea of orderly liberalization is correlated with the size of the gap between the Fund’s claims to include the promotion of capital liberalization in its political realm and the acceptance of those claims by the actors of its social constituencies for legitimation (Seabrooke 2007b, 258). Whereas during the first half of the 1990s, there was a congruence between the IMF’s claims and the political needs of member countries and the private sector, at the end of 1997 congruence gave way to a crisis of legitimacy in which new political demands were no longer satisfied by the IMF-sponsored ideas.

What this paper argues and illustrates, however, is that the ideas sponsored by an expert community are influential beyond their ability to relate to the interests of the time. Specifically, the ideas are influential in that they raise new expectations that provide the foundations for old ideas to be dismissed and for its sponsor to be trapped into its own rhetoric when expectations are disappointed. In particular, the idea of orderly liberalization raised expectations across the Fund’s constituencies about the positive effects of the free movement of international capital flows on domestic economic growth and about the role of the IMF in promoting a liberalization that was not disruptive of domestic prosperity. These expectations, however, were severely disappointed in the aftermath of the Asian crisis, prompting a backlash against the IMF and the process of liberalization. Indeed, having long preached the benefits of liberalization and the crucial role of the IMF in promoting it, IMF staff had built a rhetorical trap around themselves. When the benefits turned into losses, the IMF could not fend off the criticisms. In an attempt to respond to the criticisms from its social constituencies for legitimation, thereby in an attempt to preserve the legitimacy of the organization, the Executive Board gave up on the amendment to the Articles. In other words, the idea of orderly liberalization provided the foundations for the contestation of the its sponsor: the IMF.

(17)

In what follows, the paper thus charts the extent to which the impulse coming from the social constituencies for legitimation validated IMF ideas and prompted policy change. Specifically, the empirical sections show how the idea of orderly liberalization became

consensus within the IMF, how it was institutionalized after the Mexican crisis and how it was rejected by the outbreak of the Asian crisis.

II. THE EMERGING CONSENSUS ON 19TH STREET: ORDERLY

LIBERALIZATION

During the first half of the 1990s, both economic and political events in developing countries defied all expectations. Nations that most thought would not regain access to world financial markets for a generation abruptly became favorites of private investors, who plied them with capital inflows on a scale not seen since before World War I (Krugman 1995, 28)

In this observation, Paul Krugman nicely captures the most distinctive feature of the international economic system in the early 1990s: a revival of global financial integration after the ‘lost decade’ of the 1980s. Across the industrialized world, financial deregulation and the removal of capital controls on capital transactions resulted in greater competition and increased capital mobility.ii Sluggish rates of growth and low interest rates, then, significantly influenced the direction of capital flows, which returned to developing countries.iii Across the developing world, a renewed confidence of international investors translated into a dramatic increase of private capital flows. As a result, while in 1983-1989 the total net capital flows to developing countries as a group was less than $9 billion, in 1990-1994 capital flows rocketed to around $105 billion, with a peak of $155 billion in 1993 – a nearly fourfold increase over the previous five-year period (IMF 1995, 33-34).

(18)

As the international organization that presides over and conducts research on the

international financial system, the IMF could hardly not take stock of the dramatic changes that were taking place in the global economy. Indeed, by the beginning of the 1990s, there was a growing recognition among IMF economists that capital movements have become central to member countries’ economic prospects. Numerous IMF studies thereby contributed to elaborate a distinct position about what capital liberalization is, what its effects are, and what solutions can be devised to manage the risks entailed in the liberalization process. This position, which is here defined as the idea of orderly liberalization borrowing from the language of IMF officials, was built on three assumptions: the welfare-enhancing effect of liberalization for economic growth, the ineffectiveness of capital controls and the role of the IMF in promoting liberalization across its member countries. As the following analysis of IMF archival and public documents reveal, those assumptions, which grew on the foundations of member countries’ 1990s experience with capital flows, were widely shared within the IMF.iv

First, the consensual view within the IMF was that capital liberalization is desirable course of economic policy because of its positive effects on the economic performance of its member countries. Free capital movements facilitate a more efficient global allocation of savings, and help channel resources into their most productive uses, thus, so the argument went, they increase economic growth and welfare. Seen from 19th Street, there were few doubts that the benefits of liberalization were substantial. ‘The globalization of financial markets is a very positive development,’ the Managing Director Michel Camdessus (1995a) forcefully and repeatedly commented, depicting capital flows as ‘one of the driving forces of global growth in recent years’ (see also Camdessus 1995b; Fischer 1995a). The experience of developing

(19)

effects of global financial integration. The rate of growth of the high-inflows countries in Latin American and Asia, for instance, fueled the presumption of the link between global financial integration and economic growth (Camdessus 1996; IMF 1994, 6-8, 22-27, 57-61).v

Second, the consensus within the IMF in the early 1990s revolved around the assumption that capital controls were becoming ineffective in stemming capital flight, retaining domestic savings, and assisting stabilization efforts (Mathienson and Rojas-Suàrez 1993; Quirk et al. 1995). From the Fund’s perspective, capital controls were also viewed as damaging in that ‘they may discourage longer-term portfolio and direct investment flows’ and spillover to other countries.vi In the words of the staff, ‘controls imposed by one country typically affect others adversely …. and can, therefore, be destructive of international prosperity.’vii In essence, the mainstream view inside the Fund conceived of capital liberalization as the ‘first best’ solution. ‘The rapid integration of capital markets has shifted the balance of costs and benefits away from the controls.’viii

In the context of the prevalent thinking about the benefits of liberalization as compared to the costs of capital controls, IMF economists took strong signals from evidence that

liberalization was welfare-enhancing for its member countries but discounted alternative views to account for member countries’ positive economic performance. For instance, despite the fact the Chile provided a successful example in the use of capital controls for managing short-term inflows, until late in the 1990s the voice coming from the IMF dismissed the relevance of such an evidence. ix From the Fund’s perspective, Chilean ‘capital controls seem[ed] to have been far less important in successfully dealing with capital inflows than the adjustment of underlying fundamental macroeconomic policies.’x In line with this interpretation, the IMF thereby

(20)

documents reveal, ‘the Fund … tended […] to welcome members’ actions taken to liberalize capital account transactions,’ discouraging the use of capital controls in both industrial and developing countries.xi

Finally, the consensus around the idea of orderly liberalization revolved around the assumption that the IMF would have to play a primary role in managing the promotion of world’s capital market integration. In the Fund’s view, distinctive features of the organization – its universal membership, mandate and expertise – made the IMF the most appropriate

instrument to manage the challenge of globalized finance.xii Furthermore, the fact that the Fund may be called upon to finance balance of payments problems associated with the capital account provided another compelling reason for the IMF to play ‘a more critical role in this area than it has done so far.’xiii In this connection, IMF staff members advanced a specific policy solution: reforming the international financial architecture by amending the IMF’s Articles of Agreement to give the organization mandate and jurisdiction over capital transaction (Guitiàn 1992).xiv Although this policy change implied a profound transformation, from the Fund’s perspective, the amendment was interpreted as the ‘appropriate’ policy response to the challenge posed by financial globalization (Fischer 1997).

In sum, in the early 1990s, the assumptions on the welfare-enhancing effect of liberalization, on the ineffectiveness of capital controls and on the role of the IMF in managing international capital flows were largely shared inside the organization. Interestingly, however, those assumptions were also widely shared outside the Fund as reflected in member countries’ demands to advance the cause of international financial integration. Indeed, by the mid-1990s, authorities in both industrial and developing countries were opening their markets or were advocating it. Among the G7 countries, the U.S administration played a

(21)

paramount role in encouraging markets integration as part of its foreign economic strategy. As Jeffrey Garten, Undersecretary of Commerce, aptly put it in March 1995, ‘our exports and jobs are dependent on gaining a larger market share in the big emerging markets. No U.S. firm will be a world-class company without substantial involvement in the big emerging markets’ (as quoted in Krugman 1995, 29). U.S. aside, the G7 countries by and large preached the benefits of open capital markets (G7 1994). The view favoring liberalization was also widespread among emerging market elites (Chwieroth 2007a). Enthralled by economic success visibly embodied in the flows of international capital, several emerging market elites forged national economic policies that aimed at integrating their countries into global financial markets (Feinberg 1992). In this atmosphere, industrial countries’ demand ‘to remove obstacles to foreign direct investment’ (G7 1994) was echoed by developing countries’ concerns ‘to enhance to the fullest extent possible the recipient countries’ capacity to utilize the inflows in a manner that furthers their potential for higher investment and growth.’ By acknowledging the positive effects of greater financial integration, developing countries were also calling on the IMF to help them in ‘macroeconomic management’ (G24 1993).

Responding to these demands, when IMF bureaucrats publicly proposed to amend the Articles no significant opposition emerged.xv Although IMF staff and the U.S administration put their weight behind the proposal, there is no evidence that they were pushing it on unwilling throats. Rather, at the 1994 Madrid conference, the proposal gained strength with the implicit and explicit support of the IMF membership at large. In the immediate aftermath of the conference, indeed, the Interim Committee (1994) endorsed a Declaration in which member countries’ representatives encouraged the IMF ‘to continue its work on capital issues’. The Executive Board, in turn, discussed the possibility to overhaul Fund’s jurisdiction in the area of

(22)

capital account convertibility and several Directors advocated a new role for the Fund in ‘monitoring capital account restrictions and encouraging capital account liberalization’.xvi With the support of both industrial and developing countries, the issue of reforming the IMF was officially into the international political agenda.

III. THE ACCEPTANCE OF ORDERLY LIBERALIZATION:

THE MEXICAN TEST

At the end of 1994, the outbreak of the Mexican crisis tested the consensus view on orderly liberalization and on the proposal to amend the Articles. On the one hand, the crisis hit hard a country that had recently gained access to global capital markets and that had been repeatedly pointed at as an example of the positive effects of market opening.xvii On the other hand, the hallmark of the crisis was a sharp reversal of private capital flows in both Mexico and several emerging market countries. Only in December 1994, there was a net outflow in the form of foreign holdings of Mexican government securities of about $790 million (IMF 1995, 60). In the words of Guillermo Ortiz the Mexican Finance Minister, ‘financial markets for Mexico virtually disappeared, and there was a true stampede, in which all Mexican public and private debt instruments were literally thrown out’(as quoted in Calvo and Mendoza 1996, 173). Capital flight spread to the other emerging markets too. The bulk of market pressures were concentrated in Latin America, where the restructuring of investors portfolios mostly penalized Argentina and Brazil. Nevertheless, the ‘tequila effects’ were felt worldwide with Thailand, the Philippines, and Hong Kong experiencing financial pressures too.

The Mexican crisis thereby provided a significant test for the ideas elaborated inside the Fund in earlier years. By showcasing the risks inherent in the integration of world’s capital

(23)

markets, the Mexican crisis spoke directly to the idea of orderly liberalization raising doubts on the notion of liberalization as a desirable policy choice. It seemed but, in fact, it did not. Rather, the idea of orderly liberalization provided the lens through which interpreting the crisis and selecting the empirical evidence related to it.

Within the IMF, the crisis did not negate the presumption of the benefits deriving from global financial integration. In the aftermath of the crisis, Camdessus (1995b) summarized the consensus of the time reaffirming the faith in ‘financial flows’ as ‘an essential and reliable basis of economic progress.’ Rather than ‘to fall back on restrictions’ Camdessus forcefully argued, ‘it is policy inadequacies that have to be addressed’. Pointing to ‘policy inadequacies’ as the main culprit of the crisis, the IMF provided an interpretation of the 1994-95 events consistent with the logic of currency crises, which points to the collision between domestic goals and an unsustainable exchange rate to explain sudden and massive reversals of capital flows (Fischer 1995b; IMF 1995, 74). Conceived in these terms, the peso crisis was not interpreted as an instance of market failure but as an instance of the market rational response to perceived inconsistencies in economic policies (IMF 1995, 70)

Seen from this perspective, the crisis also testified to the ineffectiveness of capital controls. The Fund’s position on the Brazilian and Argentinean response to the crisis is telling here. Indeed, the IMF criticized Brazil’s use of capital controls in response to the crisis. As a staff document put it, ‘although [controls] can provide useful breathing room for the formulation of more fundamental measures, they create distortions and tended to lose effectiveness over time.’ By contrast, Argentina, which avoided recourse to capital controls on capital outflows but tightened its fiscal policy, was pointed at as an example for member countries.xviii Finally, the Mexican crisis reinforced the consensus on the role of the IMF as the manager and promoter of

(24)

global financial integration. Indeed, from the Fund’s perspective, the crisis showcased that ‘the responsibilities of the IMF, [were] now greater than ever before’ (Camdessus 1995b).

The consensual view on the benefits of liberalization, on the ineffectiveness of controls and on the role of the IMF remained robust outside the IMF too. In spite of the crisis, member countries did not reject the process of global financial integration nor did market participants stop investing in emerging market countries. In the communiqué released after the June 1995 Halifax summit, for instance, the representatives of the most industrialized economies repeated their faith in the benefits of global integration. They stressed that ‘new investment and increased trade are vital to achieving our growth and employment objectives’ pledging ‘to work for the reduction of remaining internal and external barriers.’ In this spirit, they also called on fellow countries ‘to remove capital market restrictions’ and to strengthen the IMF to facilitate the ‘integration of domestic capital markets’ so to assure that the international community remains able to manage ‘the risks inherent in the growth of private capital flows’ (G7 1995). Even among developing countries the IMF was still regarded as an important actor in helping countries reap the benefits of global integration (G24 1995) while few voices called for capital controls. For instance, the position of the IMF Indian representative K. P. Geethakrishnan that provocatively noted that ‘maybe some restrictions would … be in order’ was an isolated voice. xix

The resilience of elites’ support for the idea of orderly liberalization was further justified by market reaction to the crisis. After the crisis, indeed, markets euphoria for emerging markets was intact. True, there was a pause in the investment flows to developing countries in the first half of 1995. Nevertheless, the speed of recovery was rapid. The comparison with the 1982 crisis made the recovery the most remarkable. As the U.S. Treasury Secretary Robert Rubin (2003, 34) noted in his memoirs, ‘after the 1982 crisis, Mexico took seven years to regain access to capital

(25)

markets. In 1995, it took seven months.’ Not only Mexico but also the other Latin American countries quickly recovered from the crisis, with capital flows returning back on screen. By the end of 1995, net capital flows to developing countries exceeded their previous highs, recorded in 1993 (IMF 1996).

The positive reaction to the crisis eventually led Executive Directors to agree on the reforms that IMF staff had suggested acting on the idea of orderly liberalization. That is to say, the Mexican crisis had signaled the existence of a large support in favor of capital market integration under the aegis of the IMF. Within the Board, the perception was that an extension of the Fund’s mission to capital transactions was welcome across the Fund’s social constituencies for legitimation. For instance, several Directors recall no opposition from developing countries as a reason that led the Board to continue along the path of an amendment.xx As one Executive Director put it,

Within the Board the perception was that many member countries were confronted with the challenge of globalization and that the IMF could help them confront the challenge (Esdar 2006).

Not even the fact that Chile and Colombia, two countries that had continued to use controls, were among the least affected in the Western Hemisphere by the Mexican crisis, helped to undermine the emerging agreement around the amendment. Indeed, in the IMF Executive Board, few Directors took the view that capital controls could be used to confront major capital outflows.xxi The majority of Directors ‘supported the view that restrictions on capital controls had proven largely ineffective.’xxii Furthermore, with private capital flows quickly returning to developing countries sustaining economic growth, even the most critical representatives of developing countries were silenced. For instance, the Colombian Alberto Calderon, who deemed

(26)

that an amendment ‘does not seem appropriate’ conceded that ‘countries should strive towards capital account convertibility.’ Similarly Zhang, the Chinese Executive Director, who was quite skeptical on the opportunity to amend the Articles, nonetheless recognized that liberalization had proven ‘rewarding’ for his country.xxiii In other words, the opposition to an extension of the role of the IMF over capital flows was undermined by the overall observation that capital account liberalization was proving beneficial for domestic economies. In this perceived favorable environment, by the mid 1997, state representatives invited the IMF Board ‘to complete its work on a proposed amendment of the Fund’s Articles that would make the liberalization of capital movements one of the purposes of the Fund, and extend, as needed, the Fund’s jurisdiction’ (Interim Committee 1997).

In conclusion, although the Mexican crisis certainly demonstrated the risks of integrated global capital markets, the consensus on orderly liberalization remained intact thereby coloring the interpretation of the crisis itself. Both within and outside the IMF, the prevalent view was still that the free movement of private capital flows was welfare-enhancing and that capital controls were ineffective. The crisis may have theoretically falsified the idea of orderly liberalization but it had not yet discarded consensus around it.

IV. THE FAILURE OF ORDERLY LIBERALIZATION:

THE ASIAN LEGITIMACY CRISIS

In 1997, another crisis tested the consensus on orderly liberalization and on the proposal to amend the Articles. As the Mexican crisis had already done, the Asian crisis revealed the risks of increasing global financial integration.xxiv Countries that right up to the crisis had received the largest share of capital inflows among developing countries experienced capital reversals of

(27)

unprecedented scale. ‘South Korea, Indonesia, Thailand, Malaysia and the Philippines received $93 billion of private capital inflows in 1996. In 1997 they saw an outflow of $12 billion’.xxv In other words, there was a reversal of about $105 billion of net capital flows, amounting to more than 10 percent of the region’s GDP.

In reflection of the substantive beliefs of the organization, the IMF’s early interpretation of the crisis replicated what had been argued in the case of the Mexican crisis, thereby

emphasizing the consequences of policy inadequacies. Capital movements certainly played a major part in the crisis, ‘but it was not open capital accounts per se that led to problems,’ as Jack Boorman Director of the Policy Development and Review Department forcefully remarked (IMF 1998a). In the December World Economic Outlook (IMF 1997, 2), for instance, the IMF staff pointed to two factors as the ‘most important’ to explain the build-up of the crisis: ‘shortcomings and inconsistencies in domestic macroeconomic and exchange rate policies.’ In other words, as the Radelet and Sachs (1998, 1) maintain, the IMF sponsored an interpretation of the crisis that ‘assigned primary responsibility to the shortcomings of East Asian capitalism’. Specifically, the voice coming from the IMF repeatedly pointed to the inadequate supervision of corporate and financial systems as reflected in the substantial foreign borrowing by the private sector and a weak and over-exposed banking system (Fischer 1998b; IMF 1997; IMF 1998b). This is not to say that the IMF did not see market excesses at play in the region. As IMF staff conceded, for instance, ‘changes in market sentiment … cannot be fully explained …. by economic

fundamentals alone’ (IMF 1997, 2). Nevertheless, in the repartition of blame between domestic and international factors, the latter received comparatively less attention in explaining the origins of the crisis (IMF 1997, 41).

(28)

As a result of this interpretation, the three foundations of the idea of orderly liberalization were still intact. First, IMF officials made the point that ‘the Asian crisis had not negated the contribution that substantial inflows of capital had made to economic progress in the Asian countries before the crisis erupted.’xxvi Second, from the IMF’s perspective, the crisis did not call into question the view that capital controls were inefficient policy instruments to cope with volatile capital flows. For instance, the voice coming from the Fund consistently stressed the lack of significant evidence to corroborate the hypothesis that controls, such as those imposed in Malaysia or in place in India and China, were effective in stemming capital flight (IMF 1997, 17). Finally, from the Fund’s perspective, the crisis underscored the importance of IMF’s involvement with the management of capital flows. For instance, the fact that some of the crisis hit countries had a weak domestic financial system was pointed at as evidence of the importance of Fund surveillance in helping member countries to adopt sound banking regulation (Fischer 1999).

In sum, similarly to what happened after the Mexican crisis, after the Asian crisis, the idea of orderly liberalization emerged unscathed within the IMF providing the lens to interpret the crisis itself. In contrast to what happened after the Mexican crisis, however, there was no longer a complacent audience for the IMF’s ideas across the Fund’s social constituencies for legitimation. This time around, member countries and market investors did not longer support the IMF interpretation. Rather, the IMF became a target of criticism and a hostage of its own rhetoric. In particular, member countries and the private sector grew increasingly skeptical of the benefits of liberalization and sympathetic to calls for capital controls. The role of the IMF as a manager of global financial flows was also hotly contested. In short, the idea of orderly liberalization provided the foundations upon which contestation emerged.

(29)

According to a first line of criticism, the crisis called into question the presumed positive and direct relationship between financial liberalization and economic growth that have long been consensus within the IMF. In particular, it became increasingly clear that the origins of the crisis were connected with financial liberalization (Bhagwati 1998; Goldstein 1998) and that the benefits of liberalization had to be accurately weighted against its costs (Williamson 2004). A second line of criticism called into question the IMF’s view on the ineffectiveness of capital controls in managing financial crises. The argument was that capital controls may well be able to cope with large capital flows. Analyzing the crisis from the perspective of developing countries, the G24 (1998) emphasized the need ‘for countries to proceed cautiously with the liberalization of their capital accounts,’ considering the possibility of controls on short-term flows. Single investors and private sector representatives advanced similar arguments. George Soros (1998, 192-193), for instance, a financier who made his fortune thanks to open financial markets, suggested ‘some form of capital controls may … be preferable to instability even if it would not constitute good policy in an ideal world’. Interestingly, even the Institute of International Finance (IIF), the world global association of financial institutions, noted that ‘rushing to liberalize is as ill advised as rushing to impose controls’(IIF 1999, ii).

Finally, a third line of criticism was directed at the IMF in reflection of the Fund’s thus far sponsored ideas. Indeed, in the years preceding the crisis, IMF economists had in certain sense contributed to forging the public image of the Fund as the sponsor’s institution of market opening (The Economist 1999). Just one year before the crisis, Camdessus (1997a; 1997b) noted that ‘we at the IMF consider the flows to emerging market economies a very positive development,’ adding that ‘countries have to open their capital accounts.’ Still, as Fischer (1998c) recalled, in the years before 1997 the IMF had advocated capital liberalization as ‘very

(30)

naturally something in which the Fund should be concerned, and .. something that … we have pushed in the context of programs.’ Given the deliberate association between the IMF and capital account liberalization that IMF staff had rhetorically built in the years preceding the crisis, it is hardly surprising that when the Asian crisis brought about a reconsideration of the benefits of liberalization, the IMF found itself entrapped in its own rhetoric.

In its extreme form, most famously made by Mahatir Mohammed the Malaysian Prime Minister, the argument against the IMF was that the organization was an accomplice of those international investors who were disrupting emerging market economies.xxvii In less vehement terms, the charge that the IMF was strangling domestic economic recovery became popular in both industrial and developing countries. For instance, according to Thailand Deputy Prime Minister Supachai Panitchpakdi, the IMF was causing more harm than good by forcing the government to slash spending while Henry Kissinger, former U.S. National Security Advisor and Secretary of State, went public wondering whether ‘the [IMF] cure is worse than the disease.’xxviii

Reflecting the criticisms coming from the outside, the tone of the negotiations on the amendment changed substantially. With member countries and private sector actors increasingly disappointed by the seemingly disastrous liberalization approach, several Executive Directors became particularly wary about the proposal to amend the Articles. For instance, the Moroccan Director noted that ‘the events of the past six months had raised considerable concerns for many members,’ while several Directors suggested postponing the amendment calling on the IMF to better concentrate on advising countries about the preconditions that must be in place before opening to international markets.xxix In general, as the readings of the Executive Board meetings reveal, Executive Directors started re-assessing the appropriateness of amending the Articles in light of the crisis of legitimacy investing the IMF. Responding to the criticisms coming from

(31)

outside the Fund became a primary concern within the Board. For instance, the Canadian Director Thomas Bernes forcefully remarked that the Fund had to acknowledge the criticisms leveled at it, ‘otherwise,’ the German Director Bernd Esdar added, ‘the Fund might be blamed for ignoring its critics.’xxx One of the most visible attempts made by the Fund to respond to the external criticisms was the seminar held in March 1998 that was held ‘to elicit views from a wide range of private and official opinions outside the IMF’ (IMF 1998a). During the discussions, several questions were raised on the assumptions underlying the idea of orderly liberalization. As Fischer noted in his summation of the discussions, there were ‘’severe doubts’ either on whether capital account liberalization per se was a good idea, or whether … legalized jurisdiction [was] too painful, complicated, and unnecessary.’

In sum, after the Asian crisis, the IMF was identified with the disastrous consequences of capital market liberalization. Policymakers in both industrial and developing countries began to abandon the beliefs that the free movement of capital flows contributes to economic growth and that the IMF can be of help in managing the risks associated with the liberalization process. In this changed economic environment, IMF top officials continued advocating the proposal to amend the Articles in reflection of the IMF’s thus far sponsored beliefs.xxxi However, state representatives slowed down Fund’s involvement with capital account liberalization. In

particular, the Interim Committee invited the Executive Board to ‘review the experience with the use of controls on capital movements, and the circumstances under which such measures may be appropriate’ (Interim Committee 1998). Not only did the language of liberalization recede in favour of language worded in terms of controls, but the issue of amendment disappeared.

(32)

V.

CONCLUSIONS

In recent years, international political economy literature on international organizations has increasingly focused on IO’s ideas to explain organizational outcomes (Barnett and Finnemore 2004; Broome and Seabrooke 2007; Chwieroth 2007b; Momani 2005). This paper contributes to this scholarship in particular and to the ideational scholarship in general by shedding light on the mechanisms through which the idea of orderly liberalization shaped the trajectory of the proposal to amend the Fund’s constitutional charter.

Building on an evolutionary approach, the paper has argued that focusing on how ideas influence IMF policies must be accompanied by greater attention to the actors that are the target of IMF ideas. In particular, the paper has shown that the influence of the idea of orderly liberalization was strictly dependent on the support provided by the actors that operate in the Fund’s authorizing environment. This finding has important implication for our understanding of the influence of ideas because it brings to the conclusion that the influence of ideas is highly contingent. Since actors can both accept and reject ideas, studying the influence of ideas requires historical as well as spatial contextualization. For instance, the acceptance of the idea of orderly liberalization varied during the 1990s and was differently regarded by member countries and private sector actors. Still, as evolutionary theory would point out, institutional changes shaped the strategic environment in which actors interpreted reality (Rothstein and Steinmo 2002). That is, the policies adopted in the aftermath of the Mexican crisis raised expectations on the effects of capital account liberalization for economic growth and on the efficacy of the IMF in guaranteeing the stability of the international financial system. Unmet expectations, however, engender disappointment and lead to dissolution of relationships. Hence, when the Asian

(33)

financial crisis triggered a period of sluggish economic growth and demonstrated the limits of the role of the IMF in an era of globalized finance, the expectations raised by the idea of orderly liberalization as instantiated in the post-Mexico policies engendered profound disappointment among the actors that form the Fund’s social constituencies for legitimation, bringing to abandon old policies such as the amendment.

In the empirical analysis, I also sought to assess the relative explanatory power of competing hypotheses about how ideas are influential on policy choices. Not surprisingly, the preferences of the U.S. and other industrialized countries are an important factor determining whether an idea will influence policy outcomes. However, the historical record suggests that U.S. support has substantial less of an impact than it is conventionally assumed. The idea of orderly liberalization gained currency and, later, was unseated within the Fund even in the absence of an active U.S’ advocacy. The findings also offers only limited support for explanations that emphasize organizational culture as the key mechanism through ideas shape the IMF’s policies. Specifically, the amendment failed in advance of substantial turnover of IMF staff and before IMF economists’ learning from the Asian financial crisis.

More broadly, the relatively weak support for these alternative explanations is the result of their attempts to identify a single factor (economic interests or technical expertise) as the only mechanism through which ideas get established into IMF’s policies. As this paper argues and illustrates, there are instances in which ideas gain leverage over Fund’s policies without any of these mechanisms being present. This is not to suggest that focusing on powerful interests or on bureaucratic culture is always incorrect but that other mechanisms, such as the inputs coming from the Fund’s political realm, may well shape organizational outcomes too. In other words, the

(34)

scholarship on the factors shaping IOs’ behavior has thus far neglected the role played by an organizations’ social constituencies for legitimation.

In conclusion, a final point is worth considering about the relationship between the IMF and its member countries. The IMF is conventionally seen as a ‘globalizer’ (Woods 2006), that is, an organization that shapes the policies of its member countries by constituting social reality, fixing meanings in the social world, and articulating and diffusing new norms around its

membership (Barnett and Finnemore 2004). The empirical findings here suggest that the IMF is also itself subject to globalizing pressures. Its staff and Executive Directors are receptive to the policy debate going on outside the Fund, and open to policy change to retain the organization’s legitimacy. Hence, in future analysis on IOs and their policies, we should ask not only who drives changes in ideas over time but also who accepts them (Seabrooke 2007c, 382), thereby assessing the relative weight of the inputs coming from the Fund’s political environment.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

My thanks go to three anonymous RIPE reviewers for their insightful criticisms and suggestions. My thanks also go to Christopher Gilbert, Erik Jones, Sandy MacKenzie and Ralf Leiteritz for helpful comments on an earlier draft. I would also like to thank the University of California’s Washington Center and the staff of the IMF Archives for the invaluable support provided to me in the early stages of writing.

(35)

i On the issues of representation, political involvement and participation to the IMF decision making see, for instance, Woods, N., and D. Lombardi (2006), Bini Smaghi, L. (2004).

ii The United States moved to international financial liberalization in 1974, the United Kingdom in 1979 and Japan in 1980.

Australia and New Zealand removed their capital controls in 1983 and in 1984. Complete decontrols were adopted in the Netherlands (1986), Denmark (1988), France (1989), Belgium, Ireland, Italy, and Luxembourg (1990). Several members of the EFTA – Sweden (1989), Austria, Finland, and Norway (1990) – followed the path. Finally, liberalization took place in Portugal and Spain in 1993; in Greece in 1994 and Iceland in 1995

iii The US Federal Reserve left federal funds rate at 3 percent since September 1992. It started raising the rate by 25 basis points in February 1994. By September, the federal funds rate rose be 175 basis points, following projections of domestic economic recovery.

iv The views about capital account liberalization that circulated within the IMF are gleaned from many different sources. These include staff memoranda and background studies for Executive Board meetings available in the IMF Archives and IMF public documents, which are usually available on the IMF website. In particular, the IMF’s position on capital liberalization is identified building on the analysis of IMF Working Papers, Staff Papers, Occasional Papers, and the speeches of IMF staff members.

v Economic growth refers here to a rise in real GDP.

vi IMF Archives. SM/94/202. ‘Issues and Developments in the International Exchange and Payments Systems’. August 1, 1994.

vii IMF Archives. SM/97/32. ‘Capital Account Convertibility and the Role of the Fund-Review of Experience and Consideration of a Possible Amendment of the Articles’. February 5, 1997, 6.

viii IMF Archives. SM/94/202, 25.

ix On this point see also the Independent Evaluation Office Report (2005), 28

x IMF Archives. SM/95/164. ‘Capital Account Convertibility: Review of Experience and Implications for Fund Policies’. July 7, 1995, 7; and IMF Archives. SM/95/164, Sup. 1. ‘Capital Account Convertibility - Review of Experience and Implications for Fund Policies - Background Paper.’ July 10, 1995, 20.

xi IMF Archives. SM/95/164, 8,9; and IMF Archives. SM/97/32 Supplement 1. ‘Review of Experience with Capital Account Liberalization and Strengthened Procedures Adopted by the Fund.’ February 6, 1997.

xii IMF Archives. MD/Sp/98/5. ‘Capital Account Liberalization and the Role of the Fund’. Remarks by Michel Camdessus.

Managing Director of the International Monetary Fund. IMF Seminar on Capital Account Liberalization. Washington, D.C., March 9, 1998.

xiii IMF Archives. SM/95/164, 12. xiv IMF Archives. SM/94/202, 53.

xv See, for instance, the proceedings of the 1994 Madrid conference in Boughton, J. M., and S. K. Lateef, eds. (1995).

xvi IMF Archives. BUFF/94/106. ‘Concluding Remarks by the Acting Chairman for the Seminar on Issues and

Developments in the International Exchange and Payments System’. Executive Board Seminar 94/10. November 16, 1994. xvii In the words of two economists, ‘before December 1994, Mexico was hailed as the prime example of success of market-oriented reforms. It was widely believed that … the country was poised for ascending to a sustainable high-growth, low-inflation equilibrium. …. the strength of the country’s fundamentals was rarely questioned’ Calvo, G. A., and E. G. Mendoza. (1996), 170-175.

xviii IMF Archives. SM/97/32 Supplement 1, 34.

xix IMF Archives. EBM/95/73. Minutes of Executive Board Meeting. ‘Capital Account Convertibility - Review of Experience, and Implications for Fund Policy.’ July 28, 1995, Statement by K. P. Geethakrishnan, Indian Executive Director, 57-58

xx Wijnholds, J. O. d. B. (2006) Author’s interview, Executive Director, Netherlands [1994-2003], International Monetary Fund, Washington D.C., May 26; and Mozhin, A. (2006) Author's interview, Executive Director, Russia [1996-present], International Monetary Fund, Washington D.C., March 30.

xxi IMF Archives. EBM/95/73. Minutes of Executive Board Meeting.

xxii Ibid. Summing Up of the Acting Chairman, Stanley Fischer, 68.

xxiii IMF Archives. EBM/95/73. Minutes of Executive Board Meeting. Statement by Alberto Calderon, Executive Director, Colombia, 48 and Statement by Zhang, Executive Director, Democratic Republic of China, 46

xxiv The literature on the Asian crisis is extensive and references are simply indicative here. For detailed analyses of the Asian crisis from an economics perspective: Radelet, S., and J. D. Sachs. (1998); Goldstein, M. (1998). For accounts of the crisis from a political economy perspective: Haggard, S. (2000); Noble, G. W., and J. Ravenhill, eds. (2000).

xxv The Economist. ‘The perils of global capital’. The Economist, April 9, 1998.

(36)

xxix IMF Archives. EBM/98/38. Executive Board Meeting. ‘Liberalization of Capital Movements Under an Amendment of Articles’. April 2, 1998. Statement by Mohammend Dairi, Alternate Executive Director, Morocco and Statement by Thomas Bernes, Executive Director, Canada, 8 and 9. See also the position of Gregory Taylor, Executive Director, Australia, 27. xxx IMF Archives. EBM/98/103. Executive Board Meeting. ‘Strengthening the Architecture of International Monetary System; Strengthening Financial Systems; and Orderly Capital Account Liberalization - Draft Reports of Managing Director to Interim Committee’. September 23, 1998, 12 and 13.

xxxi IMF Archives. EBM/98/38. Executive Board Meeting, 9. On IMF management persistent advocacy for the

amendment see also Fischer, S. (1998a).

REFERENCES

Abdelal, R. (2007) Capital Rules. The Construction of Global Finance, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Adler, E. (1991) ‘Cognitive Evolution: A Dynamic Approach for the Study of International Relations and Their Progress’, in E. Adler and B. Crawford (eds) Progress in Postwar International Relations, New York: Columbia University Press.

Barnett, M. N., and M. Finnemore. (2004) Rules for the World: International Organizations in Global Politics, Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press.

Berman, S. (1998) The Social Democratic Model: Ideas and Politics in the Making of Interwar Europe, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Best, J. (2005) The Limits of Transparency. Ambiguity and History of International Finance, Ithaca: Cornell University Press

Bhagwati, J. (1998) ‘The Capital Myth: the Difference Between Trade in Widgets and Dollars’, Foreign Affairs 77 (3): 7-12.

Bini Smaghi, L. (2004) ‘A Single EU Seat in the IMF?’ Journal of Common Market Studies 42 (2): 229-248.

Blyth, M. (2002) Great Transformations. Economic Ideas and Institutional Change in the Twentieth Century, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Boughton, J. M., and S. K. Lateef, eds. (1995) Fifty Years After Bretton Woods, Madrid, Spain, September 29-30, 1994: International Monetary Fund.

Broome, A., and L. Seabrooke. (2007) ‘Seeing like the IMF: Institutional change in small open economies’, Review of International Political Economy 14 (4): 576-601.

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

In patient of progressive limitation in mouth opening the coex- istence of an intra-articular pathology can lead, even experienced clinician, to neglect Jacob disease,

Sono giardini da vivere e godere, al sole e all’ombra, dove spazi erbosi in morbi- de modellazioni sono circondati o si alternano a macchie di alberi e arbu- sti,

The frequency separation between the reference laser and the + laser beam is measured with a Fabry-Perot spectrum analyzer and the ring laser perimeter length is corrected in order

The motivation for this research stems from the discovery that two tomato cystine-knot miniproteins (TCMPs), one expressed in the flower (TCMP-1) and the other in the mature

Tutti i pazienti sono stati sottoposti ad angiografia coronarica quantitativa (QCA) con una nuova coronarografia di follow-up a 9-12 mesi dalla precedura indice: ciò ha

Given 4 PoAs, a fricative - affricate distinction and 4 possibilities for each sibilant (no sibilant, a voice- less sibilant, a voiced sibilant or both voiced and voiceless

The project aims to design and develop a system which bridges Homebound people (HBs) educational needs with information, resources, initiatives and tools that fit with them; it