• Non ci sono risultati.

Reserve switches and exchange-rate variability : the presumed inherent instability of the multiple reserve-currency system

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "Reserve switches and exchange-rate variability : the presumed inherent instability of the multiple reserve-currency system"

Copied!
56
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

EUI

W ORKING

PAPERS

E U I W O R K I N G P A P E R No. 8 9 / 4 1 6

Reserve Switches and Exchange-Rate Variability:

The Presumed Inherent Instability of

the Multiple Reserve-Currency System

JOERG MAYER © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(2)

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute

(3)

EUROPEAN UNIVERSITY INSTITUTE, FLORENCE

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

E U I W O R K I N G P A P E R No. 8 9 / 4 1 6

Reserve Switches and Exchange-Rate Variability:

The Presumed Inherent Instability of

the Multiple Reserve-Currency System

JOERG MAYER

BADIA FIESOLANA, SAN DOMENICO (FI)

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(4)

without permission of the author.

© Joerg Mayer

Printed in Italy in November 1989 European University Institute

Badia Fiesolana - 50016 San Domenico (FI) -

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute

(5)

1

Reserve Switches and Exchange-Rate Variability: The Presumed

Inherent Instability of the Multiple Reserve-Currency System

I . Introduction

Economists have been worried for many years about the presumed 'inherent' instability of an international monetary system that is based on reserve holdings denominated in more than one currency. From the early 1960s to 1971, the discussion focused on too rapid

or slow global reserve creation with consequent inflationary or

deflationary pressures on the reserve-currency countries as

diversification proceeded or receded [see e.g. Triffin (1960) or

Williamson (1973)]. Accordingly, a scheme for harmonization of

reserve composition was discussed. Since the adoption of

widespread floating in 1973, the main concern regarding switches

in official reserves has been the aggravating of exchange rate

instability.

The concern about aggravated exchange-rate instability is

based on historical analogies to the bimetalic standard of the

19th century and to the gold-exchange standards of the between-

the-wars and postwar periods [see for example Group of Thirty

(1980, p. 6)]. Both standards were unstable and eventually broke

down. However, Kenen (1981, p. 408) notes that the 'inherent'

instability of these standards was caused by "... the authorities' attempts to peg the prices of the reserve assets despite changes

in their relative scarcities." This invited self-aggravating

speculation which increased the danger of depleting the

authorities' holdings of the reserve asset.

Since under the present system authorities manage but do not

try to peg the prices of reserve assets, there is no such

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(6)

incentive for self-aggravating speculation. However, looking at periods of diversification out of dollar holdings and again partly

back into them and at periods of dollar depreciation and

appreciation, some correspondence of these periods can be noted. Hence, the question is whether central bank reserve switches have

aggravated rather than offset the exchange rate instability in

these periods. The objective of this paper is to assess this

question empirically. In Section 2, portfolio switches of central banks and a reference for the development of exchange rate are calculated. The resulting figures are used to assess the stability impact of the portfolio management of central banks by applying

the 'leaning-against-the-wind' criterion, Section 3, and the

'profit criterion', Section 4. Section 5 summarizes the main

conclusions.

2. Portfolio Switches and the Development of Exchange Rates

Ideally, the impact of portfolio switches on the development of exchange rates would be empirically assessed by a regression

analysis. Such an analysis would use all factors that the

generally accepted exchange-rate model indicates as causing

exchange-rate movements as indipendent variables aand add official portfolio switches as a further independent variable. The sign of

the variable representing portfolio switches would indicate

whether the portfolio management of central banks predominantly

reinforced or dampened exchange-rate movements. However, since none of the existing exchange-rate models is generally accepted an alternative - 'second-best' - approach has to be taken.

The empirical analysis partly follows Bergsten and

Williamson's (1982) study, the only - although unpublished -

source available in the literature on this issue. The analysis is

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research

(7)

3

based on the data made available by the International Monetary

Fund1 on the quarterly holdings of the five principal reserve

currencies (US dollar, pound Sterling, Deutschemark, Swiss franc, and Japanese yen) of two groups of countries, industrialized and developing, from 1975:1 to 1987:4.2

Following Bergsten and Williamson (1982, p. 26), a portfolio

switch was measured as the percentage increase in the holding of a currency in a given quarter, less the percentage increase in the

size of total foreign-exchange holdings (in terms of the

respective currency) of the respective country group, i.e.

Portfolio switch = (Pt - P. ^) - (PT - PTt_1 ) /

where P = percentage share of a currency in foregin-exchange holdings of the respective country group

PT = total foreign-exchange holdings of a country group denominated in the respective currency using the SDR exchange rate at the end of (t—1) to convert

holdings denominated in SDRs to holdings

denominated in the respective currency.

Note that portfolio switches measured in this way are independent of the currency chosen as numeraire.

However, the measure used ignores changes in reserve

composition caused by distributional effects within a country

group. If, for example, a country which holds the bulk of its

1. The author is indebted to Donald Mathieson for the provision of the data.

2. Note that ECU-holdings in the period from 1979:1 on were

decomposed into dollars and gold whose swaps create the ZCU

claims. © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(8)

reserves in currency 1 runs a surplus with another country the

major part of whose reserves is denominated in currency 2,

holdings in currency 1 will increase at the expense of currency 2 without any country changing its portfolio composition. As data

disaggregated by country are confidential, the impact of those

distributional effects on changes in the aggregate portfolio

cannot be singled out. The data on the holdings of a currency,

their percentage changes, and the calculated portfolio switches

for both industrialized and developing countries are shown in the first six columns of tables 1 to 5.

Since the objective of the analysis is to investigate whether reserve shifts have been stabilizing or not with respect to the

development of exchange rates, it is necessary to compare the

results obtained for portfolio switches with the behavior of

exchange rates. Exchange-rate changes are represented by

deviations from trend as expressed by the scaled residuals of a regression on the exchange rate as the dependent variable and a constant and a trend variable as the independent variables over

the period 1975:1 to 1988:4.3 A positive (negative) sign

signifies that the currency is appreciated (depreciated) in

comparison to its calculated trend value.

As it is not clear what the appropriate set of exchange rates

employed for the calculation of exchange-rate changes is, four

sets have been analysed. Since the dollar is still the major

reserve currency and portfolio switches therefore tend to be out of or back into dollars, the dollar rate for currencies other than

3. PC-GIVE was used for these calculations. The program

calculates the maximum-likelihood estimator by maximizing the likelihood function concentrated with respect to the constant and the trend factor.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research

(9)

5

the dollar was used as the first set. The other three sets work with a measure of some kind of multilateral exchange rate: the

IMF's effective exchange rate indeces (MERM); value-added

deflators (VADs) representing the quotient of the current and

constant price estimates of value added in the manufacturing

sector adjusted for changes in indirect taxes, i.e. composite

indicators of the cost (per unit of real value added) of all

factors of production - IFS line 99BY - , as a measure of the real exchange rate; and, finally, SDR-exchange rates. While the first three data sets are based on period average values, SDR rates are based on end-of-period figures since IFS does not report period

average SDR exchange rates.

Columns 7 to 10 (7 to 9 for the dollar) in tables 1 to 5 show

the calculated deviations from trend of the four exchange-rate

series. It is apparent that all four measures of the exchange rates move broadly in parallel after detrending. Therefore, in the following, exchange-rate changes will be represented only by the series of SDR rates.

3. The 'Leaninq-against-the-Wind' Criterion

As mentioned above, those who hold that a multiple reserve-

currency system is inherently unstable argue that a rational

central bank would move into appreciating and out of depreciating

currencies - thus reinforcing exchange-rate instability. It has

been argued on similar grounds that central banks with a

commitment to exchange-rate stability should not only refrain from

this kind of reserve switching, but also defend exchange rate

against destabilizing speculation of private economic agents.

Accordingly, official intervention policy should 'lean against the

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(10)

wind', i.e. buying depreciating and selling appreciating currency [see e.g. Tosini (1977) and Jurgenson Report (1983)].

However, whether leaning against the wind is considered

stabilizing depends on the definition of the term 'stabilizing'.

Friedman (1953, pp. 176-177, 188) holds that intervention is

destabilizing if it counters the underlying forces in the absence

of speculation or interferes with fundamental adjustments.

Accordingly, leaning against the wind is destabilizing because it

causes the exchange rate to deviate from its underlying value.

More recently, authors [e.g. Jurgensen (1983, p. 32)] have argued that instability should be equated with the variance of exchange- rate changes. In this sense, leaning against the wind is obviously

stabilizing. The desirability of this strategy is, however, not

entirely clear because it "... might have had adverse implications had it delayed necessary exchange rate adjustments or contributed to sustained periods of one-way exchange rate movements which might have created 'one-way' bets." [Jurgensen (1983, p. 25)] But the very purpose of intervention can be regarded as to finance

balance-of-payments deficits and thus avoid adjustment. Hence, the

central bank may want to foster domestic economic stability by

temporarily avoiding "excessive" adjustment costs through the slowing down of the speed of adjustment in the economy.

Similarly, reserve switches might be interpreted as 'leaning

against the wind' if reserves tend to be switched out of

appreciating and into depreciating currencies and therefore

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research

(11)

counteract or offset the exchange-rate change. Alternatively, reserve switches might be interpreted as 'bending before the wind'

if they tend to counter 'leaning-against-the-wind' intervention

and reinforce the exchange-rate change. Consequently, to determine whether reserve switches have involved reinforcing or offsetting exchange-rate changes, the deviations from trend of end-of-quarter SDR exchange rates have been multiplied into the figures for

portfolio switches. A positive number indicates reserve switches

into a currency in question when it was appreciating, or out when

it was depreciating, i.e. reserve switches were reinforcing

exchange-rate changes.^ Negative numbers indicate reserve

switches as leaning against the wind. The results of this

operation are shown in the columns headed "Leaning against the Wind" in tables 1 to 5.

As a general feature, the tables suggest that developing

countries were reinforcing exchange-rate changes as they often

bent before the wind during periods when a specific reserve

currency was appreciating or depreciating with respect to trend.

This lends support to earlier findings reporting that central

banks of developing countries tend to optimally manage their

foreign-exchange portfolio [see e.g. Ben-Bassat (1984)]. On the

other hand, the figures suggest that industrialized countries were generally more committed to exchange rate stability as they were 45

4

4. Note, however, the conceptual difference between reserve

switches and intervention. Intervention is characterized by the sale or purchase of domestic currency in exchange for a foreign

currency (the intervention currency), while reserve switches

involve a sale or purchase of one foreign currency in exchange for another where both are reserve currencies.

5. For example, the figures for the OS dollar for 1987:4 suggest

that portfolio switches by developing countries were reinforcing

dollar-rate changes three times more than portfolio switches by industrialized countries. © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(12)

predominantly leaning against the wind from 1981 on and were bending before the wind between 1975 and 1980 during shorter periods or to a lesser extent compared to developing countries.

Concerning the dollar, developing countries were bending

before the wind over several periods on two occasions, the very weak dollar in 1978 and the very strong dollar between 1984:3 and 1985:1. It is interesting to note that all reserve switches in or out of the dollar until 1985, which involved substantial exchange-

rate destabilization (1975:4, 1978:1, 1978:3 - 1978:4, 1980:2,

1984:3 - 1985:1), find correspondence in a similar development in

the figures for the Deutschemark. This indicates the high

substitutability of dollar and Deutschemark as reserve currencies. However, the figure for 1987:4 corresponds to the development in the figures for the yen. Since 1987:4 is the last quarter of the sample period, one can only speculate as to whether this indicates an increasing importance of the yen as a reserve currency in the very recent past compared to the persistence of the share reached by the Deutschemark before.

The dollar management of industrialized countries can be

divided into two subperiods, with the beginning of 1981 as the

dividing line. The first subperiod is characterized by a high

number of bending-before-the-wind switches. These reserve switches are especially high between 1978-1980, a period characterized by a

very weak dollar. Interpreting the reputation of a currency to

guarantee real-value stability of holdings denominated in that

currency as its 'brand-name capital' [see Klein (1974)], the

reserve switches between 1978 and 1980 suggest the adoption of a new attitude of industrialized countries towards dollar holdings at the time. As there was no convertibility constraint on dollar

holdings and the performance of the dollar during the 1970s

undermined its reputation as a high-quality currency, confidence

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research

(13)

9

of industrialized countries in the capacity or willingness of the

United States to guarantee a low-inflationary and stable

international monetary system was ebbing. Consequently, the

reserve switches might be interpreted as a signal of

industrialized countries to the United States that they would not tolerate further exploitation of the brand-name capital of the dollar. Accordingly, the United States either had to accept the

erosion of the dollar as a reserve currency or adopt policy

measures with the objective of guaranteeing real value stability

on outstanding dollar holdings. US authorities indeed adopted a

more restrictive monetary policy in November 1978 and October

1979. In addition, they promised to intervene on foreign-exchange markets to influence the dollar exchange rate in the short run.

The second subperiod is characterized by leaning-against-the-

wind reserve switches in almost all quarters. Note that these

switches were strongest between 1984:1 and 1985:3 - the end of

this period coincides with the Plaza Agreement - a period during which developing countries were heavily bending before the wind. The above-mentioned parallelism between reserve switches involving

the dollar and switches involving the Deutschemark - the yen

replacing the Deutschemark in 1987:4 - can also be noted for the group of industrialized countries.

Concerning the pound Sterling, the tables suggest than

developing countries employed a policy of optimal portfolio

management. All extended periods of bending before the wind

coincide with local maxima or minima in the devlopment of the

exchange rate of Sterling (1976, 1978:4 - 1982:3, 1984:3 -

1985:2). The low values of reserve switches into or out of

Sterling by industrialized countries may indicate the limited

importance of Sterling as a reserve currency for these countries.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(14)

Optimal portfolio management by developing countries is also suggested by the tables for the Deutschemark. The long period of bending before the wind between 1981:2 - 1985:1 coincides with the depreciation of the Deutschemark with respect to the dollar. For the group of industrialized countries, the tables suggest the same

division into two subperiods as for the dollar, although the

pattern is less distinct. It is interesting to note that the

accumulation of DM-reserves by EMS-countries, in particular since

1983, seem to have been following a leaning-against-the-wind

strategy, i.e. exchange-rate changes have not thereby been

reinforced.

The figures for the Swiss franc show few substantial reserve switches for both groups of countries. However, a long period of bending before the wind by developing countries between 1981:4 and 1984:3 coincides with a local maximum and a local minimum of the

exchange rate of the Swiss franc against the SDR. This points

again to the optimal portfolio strategy of these countries.

Concerning the Japanese yen, the striking feature of the

tables is that industrialized countries followed a leaning-

against-the-wind strategy throughout the entire sample period,

only interrupted a few times for one or at most two quarters.

In order to assess whether reserve switches predominantly

involved reinforcing or offsetting exchange-rate changes

throughout the entire sample period, an index was constructed, as proposed by Bergsten and Williamson (1982, pp. 29-30). For this, the figures in the columns headed "Leaning against the Wind" have been summed for each currency and for the two country groups separately. These sums tend to be dominated by those quarters in

which there were both considerable switches and significant

exchange-rate changes as the scale of the switch and the degree of

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research

(15)

rate changes enter multiplicatively. Then, the absolute values of the figures in the column headed "Leaning against the Wind" have been summed, and used to divide the sum calculated before. The resulting index runs from +1 to -1, the extreme cases indicating that reserve switches were completely reinforcing or offsetting

exchange-rate changes, respectively. The resulting indeces are

shown in table 6.

Table 6: Index of Leaning against the Wind

Industrialized Countries Developing Countries

Dollar Sterling Deutschemark Swiss franc Japanese yen -0.166 0.258 -0.007 0.093 -0.131 0.420 0.026 0.315 -0.0002 0.333

Source: Tables 1 to 5 and calculations as described in the text. A

negative number indicates that reserve switching

predominantly offset exchange-rate changes

The table suggests that reserve switching by industrialized

countries was indeed such as to generally lean against the wind,

i.e. to offset rather than to reinforce exchange-rate changes

while the opposite seems to be the case for developing countries.

In the light of the above interpretation of reserve switching

regarding dollar and Deutschemark during 1978 and 1979, the index

underestimates the stabilizing character of reserve switches by

industrialized countries for these two currencies. Thus, the

difference in the portfolio management of the two country groups becomes even more striking.

Bergsten and Williamson (1982, pp. 31-32) use the described

method to calculate a second index of whether reserve shifts were

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(16)

stabilizing, now on the basis of medium-term equilibrium exchange

rates. They define the equilibrium rate as the trend value

calculated before in order to determine thè exchange-rate series which were used for the calculation of portfolio switches. While the results on their first index led them to conclude that central

banks in general lean against the wind, their second index

suggests that central banks tend to destabilize exchange rates,

i.e. that they tend to push the exchange rate away from its medium term equilibrium level.

But, using an equilibrium exchange rate - however defined -

for the calculations is not persuasive. This approach requires

knowledge of the equilibrium path of the exchange rate, whereas

the exact identification of that equilibrium path is virtually

impossible. The most important technical difficulty of defining

the nominal equilibrium exchange rate is the choice of a base

period. It cannot be expected that a trend value calculated over some specific period (1974:2 to 1981:1 in Bergsten and Williamson

(1982)) will necessarily closely correspond to medium-term

equilibrium rates. Even if this difficulty could be solved,

medium-term equilibrium exchange rates are not a compelling policy target. Foreign-exchange interventions or reserve switches affect

the nominal exchange rate and, with sticky prices, the real

exchange rate in the short run only, a horizon that is shorter

than the medium-term perspective underlying Bergsten and

Williamson's calculation of the equilibrium exchange rate.

Moreover, Swoboda (1988, p. 98) points out that the real exchange

rate is an endogenous variable under both fixed and flexible

exchange rates and therefore should not be used as a policy

target. In general, as the correct calculation of equilibrium exchange rates is not clear and the real exchange rate is not an independent policy instrument, calculating a leaning-against-the- wind index on the basis of an arbitrarily determined equilibrium

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research

(17)

13

rate tells little about the actual stabilizing merits of reserve

switches.

4. The 'Profit Criterion'

A natural question to ask is whether the profits and losses

that may arise from reserve switches can be used as a formal

criterion to evaluate the stabilizing or destabilizing nature of these switches. Such a use follows from the profit criterion, a controversially discussed yardstick in economic literature on the

stabilizing or destabilizing impact of official intervention in

the exchange markets. The profit criterion goes back to Milton

Friedman's (1953) well-known essay on fixed versus flexible

exchange rates. Friedman affirmed that destabilizing speculation

implies losses to speculators, and suggested that one criterion of the effectiveness of official intervention in stabilizing exchange rates could be the profits made on that intervention.

Two theoretical problems of the profit criterion are

noteworthy here.*’ On the one hand, Mayer and Taguchi (1983, pp. 10-11) show that even unprofitable speculation can be stabilizing. One example is excessive intervention in the right direction with

the exchange rate randomly fluctuating around its equilibrium

path. In this case, intervention would push the actual exchange

rate beyond the equilibrium path - an overvalued (undervalued)

currency would become slightly undervalued (overvalued).

Consequently, despite the fact that intervention succeeds in 6

6. See Jacobson (1983) for a survey on the theoretical debate or,

the relationship between profitability of speculation and

exchange-rate stability in economic literature.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(18)

reducing exchange-rate variability, all sales are made at a lower rate than purchases - the central bank incurs losses. On the other

hand, the authorities may deliberately lose money by their

interventions. This may be the case in two circumstances. One is intervention to finance a temporary payments deficit in order to avoid costly adjustments that would have to be reversed when the effects of the underlying temporary disturbances have passed. The other is when sudden disturbances are believed to be permanent but intervention permits a more gradual, and thereby more balanced and less disruptive adjustment.

In general, using the profit criterion one has to bear in mind

that more weight is given to destabilizing than to stabilizing

behavior. Due to this negative bias, the usefulness of the profit

criterion for evaluating the impact of intervention, or reserve

switches, on exchange-rate stability is reduced, and results

should therefore be interpreted with caution. Nonetheless,

together with the leaning-against-the-wind criterion the profit

criterion remains the most useful criterion for this purpose

because it is a relatively easily quantificatable measure.7

The most serious technical problem of the profit criterion is how to handle net cumulative currency holdings at the end of the

period. Taylor (1982) and Corrado and Taylor (1986) value the

cumulative net intervention figure at the end-of-period exchange

rate. Several authors [Argy (1982), Jacobson (1983) and Pilbeam

(1988)] have argued that by examining the entire sample period,

results will be biased according to whether the period was

7. Mayer and Taguchi (1983) propose a 'hybrid criterion' as an

alternative. However, in order to use it both an equilibrium

exchange rate and exchange rate zones around this hypothetical

equilibrium level have to be determined.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research

(19)

15

dominated by net purchases or sales of dollars. Therefore, they propose restricting the calculations to periods in which purchases and sales of foreign exchange are approximately equal to avoid the problem of measuring cumulated net currency holdings.

In the remainder of this section, the profit criterion will be

applied to reserve switches. This calculation deviates from

Bergsten and Williamson's (1982, pp. 34-35) study since the latter do not provide a meaningful measure of profits. They define profits as the sum of the products of portfolio switches and the percentage appreciation relative to trend in the exchange rate from the quarter in question to the average rate 5 months later.

Accordingly, they examine whether portfolios were shifted into

(out of) currencies before an appreciation (depreciation) occured. However, this method arbitrarily determines an investment horizon

of six months which neglects any flexibility in investment

decisions. Moreover, interest income earned on the currency

holdings is ignored. Finally, summing the profits over the entire sample period introduces a bias dependent on whether switches were

predominantly into or out of the reserve currency in question

during the sample period.

The calculations for the profit criterion involve several

steps:

1) The holdings of a currency of both industrialized and

developing countries have been calculated by multiplying:

- total foreign-exchange holdings of the respective country

group (expressed in end-of-period SDRs) by

- the share of the currency in the total portfolio of the

country group,

- the end-of-period SDR/OS Dollar exchange rate, and

- the period average US Dollar exchange rate of the respective currency. © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(20)

This yielded eight series: the period average holdings of industrialized and developing countries of Deutschemark, Swiss franc, pound Sterling, and Japanese yen, each in terms of the

currency held.

2) Increases and decreases of holdings of the four currencies have

been calculated by subtracting holdings in period t-1 from

holdings in period t. This yielded eight series of net holdings in a period on average. The differences have been summed to calculate eight series of net cumulative holdings of a currency in a period on average.

3) In order to minimize the problems inherent in evaluating the

end of period cumulative currency holdings, periods have been selected over which net cumulative currency holdings have been close to zero. The net increase (decrease) of currency holdings remaining in the series of net cumulative holdings at the end

of a selected period was subtracted from (added to) the

difference of holdings - calculated in 2) - in the final

quarter of the selected period. This yielded the series of zero

net cumulative currency holdings.

4) Average balances of holdings denominated in the four currencies have been calculated for each quarter of the selected periods of zero net cumulative holdings, as basis for the calculation

of exchange-rate and interest-rate profits of portfolio

switches. For this, the net holdings figure for the quarter in

question was added to the previous quarter's net figure and

divided by two (for the first quarter of a selected period, the

net holdings figure was divided by two).

5) Exchange-rate profits in terms of US dollars have been

calculated by multiplying the average balances of currency

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research

(21)

17

holdings for each quarter of the selected periods of zero net cumulative currency holdings by the average dollar exchange

rate of the respective currency. Positive entries represent

purchases of the currency against US dollars, i.e.

expenditures, and negative entries represent sales of the

currency for US dollars, i.e. receipts. Purchases and sales

have been summed to calculate the exchange-rate gain or loss for the respective period of net zero cumulative holdings.

6) Interest-rate earnings have been calculated as follows: the

absolute figures of average holdings of a currency have been multiplied by US interest rates for each quarter of zero net cumulative currency holdings. The sum of these series indicate

the interest income for each period of zero net cumulative

holdings, had all holdings been in US dollars. Next, the

figures of a period with a positive entry in the series of average holdings of a currency have been multiplied by the

interest rate of the country issuing the currency held. US

interest-rate earnings have been replaced by these figures of

interest income for the respective periods in order to

calculate the series of interest income considering the switch from dollar holdings into one of the other four currencies. The interest rate gain or loss of portfolio switches was calculated by subtracting the series of interest income on the basis of-US interest rates from the series of interest income on the basis of US interest rates for the periods of dollar holdings and of interest rates for the respective other currency for periods of

holdings therein.

7) The net profit from portfolio switches was calculated as the exchange rate profit/loss plus the interest rate gain/loss.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(22)

The above calculation is based on the following assumptions:

- All portfolio switches are made out of dollar holdings and back into dollar holdings;

- switches are spread out evenly thoughout the quarter; - profits and losses on intra-quarter trading can be ignored; - all interest rate gains/losses are converted into dollar at the

period average exchange rate;

- compound interest income can be ignored (assuming a compound

interest rate of 10 percent on an annual basis, the quarterly

interest rate would be the fourth potence of 1 plus the fourth root of 0.1 (1.024) - or 1.0995 - while an interest rate of 1.10 was assumed in the calculation);

- net cumulative portfolio switches at the end of the period can be closed out at the average exchange rate of the final quarter of the period.

As it is not clear what the appropriate set of interest rates

employed for the calculation of the profitability of portfolio

switches is, two sets have been used. Mayer and Taguchi (1983, p. 16) argue that, for such a calculation to be useful, the interest

differential should reflect the underlying trend in the

equilibrium exchange rate between two currencies. Considering the forward rate as an unbiased estimate of the future spot rate, the forward discount or premium on foreign currency reflects the trend in the exchange rate expected by the market. On the other hand, the forward discount or premium equals the Euro-currency interest

differential when covered interest arbitrage holds. However,

central banks do not necessarily invest in the Euromarket but, for example, conduct swap operations at non-market rates. This means

that actual interest income may differ from the results obtained by taking Euro-interest rates - the theoretically appropriate set. Therefore, treasury bill rates have been used to see whether the

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research

(23)

19

g

choice of interest rates rseulted in any significant difference.

Accordingly, three-months LIBOR on deposits (IFS line 60EA for

Sterling, Deutschemark, Swiss franc and yen, and IFS line 60LDD for OS dollar) was used as the first interest-rate set. As an alternative, for the four currencies of the sample included in the

SDR basket, the treasury bill rate applied by the IMF for

calculating the SDR interest rate was used, i.e. IFS line 60CS for US dollar and pound Sterling and IFS line SOBS for Deutschemark and Japanese yen, while for the Swiss franc the interest rate on three months deposits with large private banks - IFS line 60L - was used.

The results of the calculations are given in tables 7 to 10.

The tables suggest that both developing and industrialized

countries incurred losses by switching their foreign-exchange

holdings out of the dollar into Deutschemark, pound Sterling,

Swiss franc, and Japanese yen. Only two of the eight calculations for industrialized countries and only two of the six calculations

for developing countries report a profit. There seems to be no

general pattern of profitable reserve switches with respect to

either country groups, currencies, or periods. However, due to the

above mentioned negative bias of the profit criterion, this does

not necessarily mean that reserve switches were destabilizing.

8. This method is also used in Jacobson (1983) and Pilbeam

(1988). © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(24)

5. Summary and Conclusions

To summarize, the evidence suggests that central banks have

been 'leaning against the wind' in their reserve switching - in

particular industrialized countries since 1981. The substantial

'bending before the wind' of industrialized countries with respect to their dollar holdings in 1978 and 1979 can be considered as a signal to the United States to adopt policy measures in order to

stabilize the real value of outstanding dollar holdings. In

addition, this diversification out of the dollar can be

interpreted as the deliberate holding of non-dollar currencies as reserves in order to introduce a certain competition among reserve currencies. This competition can be regarded as a re-introduction of a convertibility constraint on foreign-exchange holdings. Under

the classical gold standard, this convertibility constraint

consisted in the agreement that each currency had a specific rate in terms of gold at which the issuing central bank had to exchange domestic banknotes for gold coins. Under the Bretton Woods system,

the convertibility constraint only applied to the US dollar. It

was abolished by the suspension of gold convertibility in August 1971.

However, it appears that reserve switching has been generally

unprofitable to central banks that have practiced it. This

suggests a commitment of authorities of - in particular

industrialized countries to conduct reserve switches in such a way as to offset exchange-rate changes even if this means dissipating

their foreign-exchange reserves'. Therefore, the generally

expressed fear of an 'inherent instability' of a multiple reserve- currency system seems to be largely overestimated.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research

(25)

1 h e U b D o l l a r .

_

Li LZ &^ aJ Li — k f a a r s -1 n R e s e r v e P f l r t f Q l i Q g,

_

Pf lr JL tf l-U Q P i t c h e s .

_

E x c h a n g e R a t e s , a n d L e a n i n g a g a i n s t 3 ■Ml U> a) K ' B<j<rMfl«7'rii)30-r ncm o 7 •7 o-7cocs.a>trjr'30jacD'i't d o; m cm co — cncn — it.coocn - — 7>r. .Decor*» C O C N - - C O O O O O O — 3 — - c o oi i i i i f-33CMOcoo)7incM(o N »■ W N-IO 7 (B # 0.0 i r n o c N c o n i n — cm — c o o — c o o o o o o <7 o cn — co o o 3 «7 CM CC O) 7 o co o cm ao co — cm a) & in c-i o - - c o .— CC D a> <q- CO o 03 '7 <o 33 if) 7- ■V. D co O •131 Q03 03 O' CO Ml 73 7 (N CM CN CN CN 7 7- CO 33 a; 03 — 0)1 i 1 1 1 Ml (71 cl a 3 *7" 77 J3

_ _

Lfl O CN 33 CN M 03 f) CO 7 CD o - 3 CM — CM — 3 O M 7 f) 03 o 03 fs~ 03 <ui < Oi > 1 1 1 1 (71 3X! scc I" 33 - 3)C 3 c CN CM CN ■r; O -v. CM 7 CD 'l CC r-~ CM M 3 CN CM CN 3 CO 7 C' 33 CC r- 03 -Ul 5 1 , , , i CM 03 CO 73 CO CN innccoo^-CD 7 CO 7 CO CO - O - <7 CM O - i) if. in ifi n ID ifl N n li o CO <7 — 0) — CN — — C CO CM — G - N C O J 1 - 03 03 7 CD 73 CD cm in 7 a> -o co CM CN C O O CM I I I 7 CO 73 f" D 7 r- - ;c *7 s) a> 7 I ' 3 <C m i t cm o - o o o «7 O <7 CD CD CM O C -o C CD Ifi m C i- CO E o - - c o oI I I I 73 C 3 7 7 -f ) cc 7- r- in — 73 m o c co — o — — - o — co — cciicroccco cob - o r~ .n co — C077C C ; o C 0 l f l O f l ' O N M C O - ' O O — O - 7 - C M O C M C N O O O C M O - — c o o I - I I I I I ! I I I m co in 7 O £> -33 - 3 CN J3 CO J3 t' 03 CD -7 O' oiocc<o:oco.nf~ CO D CC N —co o r- t- cc c o> — cn im 'O r- co CD(O B CD 3 10 B 7 B C NO N 3 L* CO <7 CM - - C D — N fv. td— 7 73 — i3 o -B CJi O L* B 3 3 C 3 -ii r» in c 33 C 33 CC (O 3 SI B C N CM m I (Jl 3 IT 3 E OlT. •I r It 33 I D C D C £3 © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(26)

n b o 10 a i N •- N O J | r O ) Q 7 a N n - N C C O I O l D C D C D — o r - *r r~ en 3 CM o O O O O O C O — C M 3 - 3 » - N Cs — O I I I I I i I I I I I i l 3 0 — O O CM O — — o r » - ® - 3 f ' - C M 3 3 * » t o c M r > - ® — . N C M 3 > a i 3 c o ® » T — o œ o o i o i o c o ^ — co — o œ *r cm oo — c o œ o r » a > o c M 3 — o- œ — en œ — N n o c r ' f o a a a I * ' - , - M - - l l l - l -3 C M O c o i n a œ a > i e i n c s c M c c o ® i r > ® e o -3 C O i n e o o > — m n n a œ c N — *» s h N f f l « N n s < i O ( c - - ( D a - - N . io r « a « N N i o o i N N - B N i n l O i n a O N C N ' Æ O s — > O C S ( D 3 < f Æ ' » J ) C O < T C C O L O i n 3 — J i œ e s c 0 C M C D C J > O ® œ ®0 <n®CM — — — |v. ® (O ® — — — N h - O l O ( N C C O ’» O C N 3 ® O a ) ^ t I I I — I l — — — — — CM CM (N — — I I I — I — o a o - i n s M n c v a a h c D a i n M û a j i c s L a n n ' i N a s M N n i N a (OcocD^ri^3<D30î — — coa3<Nco'jDcoi>c;cMcsinincN3’j — ^tcoifiOM

CM O CM O OT 3 C O n O I N O N l I l œ C M I B B l C CD X) — X J O l O O î l O - — CM — — 3 — O ^ O O C M O O O O O O O O O O O O O C O C O — — OO O — — — O C M I l I I I I I I I I I I I CM 3 CO 00 CO — C i n n i n i l (C x i es — ce — i f i c M « r c o 3 < o o o i n o > — o r ^ c M r » < £ > c o r » c M h ' a <i a i r a o f T a o CM CM CD Oî O O CO — CO CO CD ^ CD — CO CO h i n i n w CM X) *J T CM CM o — (N — c o c o o O CM 3 — 3 — - O CS O CO 3 — CM CD CD co r» io co O 3 «T CM — P- CO CM CD — n o a - î ü ■} — O O- o o CM O ' r a s i i i a a - t œ — œ N lil œ O O O O O O O io rs 3 co CM 1^ 3 CC "s O! O O 3 C 3 C I I I CM CD CO CO CO CD i o — m o co 3 i n o c o — — — o i l 1 co s i n i/i — — CM — (N o O — — — O CM I I i n r> <o n i n CD CM CM CM CM CO CD O CD co CO If) 3 IO ce CD f" CM O CM CO *» ce co ce CO — co CM — (O io o-co O o-co co t en ® co 33 3 o- 3-co <o 3-co CD X) ce in ~~ c IO T et CO CO ce x> ce CO Cs (D 3 3 *T co ce co ao in jî m *» cO O O h' CM CO CO X) 3 "- — O - 01 — ( 0 3 — — — CMOCMCM3 o ce o ce co ce co ce !S — CM® — Nf'XJCC 100)3100)*»— 3Q- — X)(DinCMeM .Qifì!'.ir)(03<nM — ie>T*r3®CO®lO — ® « T ’» ® O N O ® * » l 0 3 < N C 0 0 3 C M X > 3 l O C n ' » C O C M C S O — C M — eIl I oI I I e — C O — C M 3 — 3I I I I I— — O C s O — T 3 — CM — O C M O O I I I I I CD ce CM — ® 10 * T T C I < D i O — N (D S «J 0 1 0 - 1 0 ® ( O M | - ' ' T c n i n œ a ) ' ‘» o- a i o- CD co o- — o i-' ^ ce o- o i n co in o 3 . n c <o cs 3 3 r - ~ * » o 3 o c i ' » ® 3 C — 3 i ^ 3 C 3 œr ^ r > m > . 3 ® r ' - ^ ®s r 3 3 — — 3® ® * j r ^® 3 — — 3 © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research

(27)

P o r t f o l i o s w i t c h e s ( P S ) w e r e c a l c u l a t e d a c c o r d i n g t o t h e f o l l o w i n g f o r m u l a o </> u L 0) to u -- i> Oi E N C. 0 A C • — a.’ d w m u O t- -r-(0 -« a — £ d — * ■ H O O D i- T3 -D 01 0 o o — -H d o 3) O «T — C O u-— - / I O C — £ O --• a — o z -H i (0 i — £ 0 ID — $ u a — - s - X 0 u 1 s 1 — 2. D £ D © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(28)

a b l e 2 : T h e P o u n d S t e r l i n g . 1 9 7 5 -8 7 : S h a r e i n R e s e r v e P o r t f o l i o s . P o r t f o l i o S w i t c h e s . E x c h a n g e R a t e s , a n d L e r 0)1 •Ml d) L T> M c c HH 3 0 - E I D f f l O ' - N K l N i n « t o < t < x > c M i n c M O oc o cmo>c m c o- n o o o o o c m o o o C N O < M C 0 C D 3 3 O C 0 C 0 a s c o o c o i n - — c o o c m o — o — — o o o 0 0 - 0 0 0 0 0 0 a. Q (/) r ^ O C O C O O O — OOCM — B C O M l f i O i l f l l f l ' I co cm — o — o t o o- o — i n o c n i n c o o i o c o i t t i i i i f l i o o i o o i n ^ i n n h O N N f f l N f f l ^ i f l » — — c o T ' t o — in — c n c o o c o r ' i o o t n o ' j i i i i — — — — i i , i i i i i i f f ) 0 ® f f l l f l f l l l 0 1 J 1 3 ) i r N ( 0 1 N N N - M N I B C N J I C O O — O l C M O l i n i n ' T — C D ' T C M C M O i C M C O LO<Ninincoco*rincoor»<o<0or-»r>-r'*r<£> o a o — — CM <J> O NJ — — 03 <C — t o — to ® N to 05 i*» in <d co o N M O N ® N O) 7 N N 10 ^ K) <1 CO CO — o o o o CO — CO T o in cm o cc <o — k «r in co n IN 10 (O O M 0 0 — 0-0 o — io I I o o c — o o o o o o iO 't CD 10 - 35 in N I C I N N O I M - — Cm — 10 ffl IN IN f*« t" 33 O) O *t O <o CO - O 10 "I 0) IN CM O Nf - CO CM O O O C O C O — O O C O C — o o o o o o I I I I I I I I I O l O l O I C O I N O l ' T <T O — (M CM O) in CM O C M O C D ' T i n O O C M O C D ' T C M O O — O’ -O — -O-O — — o — — o o o — o o o o o o I I I I I I I ! I CC 0» — O ! i n C O 1 S I E N C 0 a ) N ( 3 ) N I O - CO N i D i O f f l u i — i O — ' • K i i o f f l n - — - n c o o i e C C M l D I N C f l O C C - CM CM CM — (O CO CO CO CO CO CO ' . N i o s c B i n o i N n o i i O N - o o i n i ' — CO — C O ) — CM — rf — C M O C C O — O O O O C O O O — O O C 0 0 - 0 0 0 0 0 0 no — co co co — o- cm !*» cc c o o - 3 3 m cm ( C l O R — 2 0 I O ® 3 K! ? ) 1 0 i O i nffl'J3l0 l0 N — — — — — o c - j - — — — — 0 0 0 3 0 0 0 © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research

(29)

0 0 4 oi io N - n ni io 7 n o io N co — co — o 3 o — o o — — — c o> co 3 co o — N M CN o — o o — —co — o 3 O O C O O O 3 (D CN 3 3 CN in o o in o in — O O O -O -O -O C -O -O ^ CO O P- CD 3 co COT CO (D CN — CO CN 0 — 0 0 — o o o o o a o co cn co r» n r> in 3 3 o cn ni c 3 o o cn o o c o 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 O CD N 11) ® 0 0( 0 0 03 co m co o cn — c 3 co o 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 0 0 o i n i n c o o o c o c o o - o c n3 B < r ® f f l n i N w - i i i i ( o i n o O — CN — — C N O O O O O C N C N 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 0 0 C O O O O O O O O C 0 0 0 0 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 CD o o o in (SI coii)'-in3iso7NN(!ioci®ii)0(flMNN7ii)03)aa)Si,)<ìa)>-o cc(Nr~o«rcNM»jocoaor~o3 0 — coo’ p' — uoointocsicNMcjicD'jcN'-co

— — CN M CN — — . I I I I • — «—I I I I I i I I I 3 3 C N ( N 3 ( D ,' ' L O O c o i n c D O O - ^ 3 c n c n— p» — — 3 3 3 :0 0:1^ — 3 0 3 n o ni œ n «j — n n «f io «r — 3 i n q ‘ C M O * - o i n a > o c n 3 i n ? ì e c < ’oc'4a>o)io — — — CN CN N — — — — — — I I I I I — —I I p~— < D < N 3 C N 3 0 3 c n c o 3 3 C N 3 3 0 3 ( C 3 c n c o c o c N : o — 3 co 3 c co cn r*> C h> O CO 3 — 0 f ~ 3 3 3 0 r ' - 3 C N 3 C N O — C O C 0 0 0 3 — 3 M P~ — ® 7 <T O — — CN — — I I — I I I — I l I I t N CO - 0 ( 0 3 3 C » > C C 3 0 < 0 0 * — l O( C > * 3 l ' * 3 r - ( n < J > — P* CO<DI'> — PI O) (O 0 3 3 0 0 3 0 — OOCNO — (r> ' - C C ' ' C C ; D C < D C 0 < D C O 3 ; Q 3 C N C N 3 C 3 3 ( D c o r * p * o > 3 a > N ( C 3 0 f ' * p » o > 3 0 3 c o a c n — p»c n w3 — c d o c c i o o c o- œ p~ —o) 3 c n c o o3 c n3 0 3 3 3 0 — 3 3 c c o o 3 0 ( N > - < D i 0 3 3 C N a > c o 3 P » 0> — 0 3 ( 0 3 — — — 3 — ( N C N — O - C N — C O - O W C O O C O — C C N C N O O — 0 0 0 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 0 3 0 0 C 0 0 0 0 0 3 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 I I I I I I I I I - I I I O CO O 3 3 r- CD — 3 co 0 — 00 — o o o o o o 3 CC <7 CN 3 3 CNp- in n <o CD c o o o 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 — 3 œ 7- CD 3 *7 Sì O) - c 3 — 3 0 3 7 3 C O O O C ■7 in 3 — 3 P- 0) 3 3 3 —O <N O O o o o o o CD CN O O P- CN m co co o CN CN — — 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 01 IO 7 N 3 ■n 3 3 P- 3 CD O CO 3 3 p. 3 3 3 3 CO 3 3 3 — 3 ( OOC N — 3 C 0 C O C N C N - CO — C N— O O — MCNCN — — M C O O C O — C C O C N O — 0 0 0 0 3 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 0 0 0 0 3 0 0 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 • I l i I I I I I 3 3 — 3 3 CN CN 3 CO 3 3 CO 3 3 3 3 ■*» CO 3 3 CO <D 3 CC co 3 co CN 3 CO 3 CO 3 3 3 3 — 3 — — — 3 in io 3 co cc 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 — r-~ — o cD IO 3 CN O 3 3 CO 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 CN CO 3 I " 3 3 3 3 3 3 CD 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 CN CO O h’' O CO N — CNLO CO 3 CD — CO 3 — 3 3 <N — 3 — O) 3 CO 3 O 0 0 0 0 0 — 0 0 0 0 — 0 0 — 0 0 — 3 3 — — — O O N C O O C N — — O C — o o o o o o o c o o o o o o o o o o c o o o o o o o o c o a o o o 3 P- 3 N CO 3 3 3 C 0 3 I ^ P ' P ~ 3 3 C D 3 C 0 3 i n ' ' C 3 - 3 3 CO P - P ' P ' P - B r ^ ' > P » P > 3 P - P ' 3 ; 0 P ' ?' ~ 3 — l f i P > C C P - 3 3 O r ' 3 3 < O L 0 3 3 i n o o o o o o o c o o o o o o o o o — — — — — — — M — — — — — — — — © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(30)

P o r t f o l i o s w i t c h e s ( P S ) w e r e c a l c u l a t e d a c c o r d i n g t o t h e f o l l o w i n g f o r m u l a CJ -r- — o o z ~ a> aj > .N i > /-* r 03 O ** T- — o — q: a x o — - to d r o 3 V) — 'J © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute

(31)

I f l g -Q e y t s Q h g m g r k , _ _ 1 9 Z 5~ 8Z ;

_

S h a r e i n R e s e r v e P o r t f o l i o s . P o r t f o l i o S w i t c h e s . E x c h a n g e R a t e s . a n d L e a n i n g a g a i n s t t h e W i n d 1) c D CD(O r-<0 CO 0 CD0 in<0 O’CO3 v (C CO(O a COao0 O in (Din 03 £0CD3 mi1 > CM CD 030 Cm 0 CDc 0 O CD<D n CM Ci* 0 c *— 0 3 O O CO O 0 O 0 O 0 0 O 0 3 O a atiT 0 1 1 01 c (_) (01 3 01 M c l a 3) O CO (D CO CO CD 03 CD CD CO3 r CO CO (D CDin O) soCO CM03 o-CMCO Cl inCO0 CMO O O O 0 0 cc (D CMO T (01 T3 Ol C 0 0 OO 0 O OO0 0 O OO O CM -J! 3 1 1 1 0 u 0) CD (N in CM03*0 03 «r ID 03 (O CO (O 03CO3 CC O in m CM h- r~ CO0 0 vOCOin03 O' 3 CO 3 Q * 1 #• Ml a» O O CD to co1"CM inO <T CD inO’ CO 3 vi < 3 (D - CO <r 0 0 IDinD r~ CD 03 in0 3 r-~ D (01 > a:l

1

1

1 — •" 0 1 S ao cmfN <D Cm co a)CD O LD co 3 CO 3 c : CC CM C C| coO CD <D O c 0 CM in O p- PM COCM <T (01 UJ CO Ol 1 1 oil u (0 — CD O 0 i" in D CD c inSO S ) 3 O O in (D in in inCl CM c LD in N O 3 — r» Q M Ml H 0)1 inin £33 CMCM CD D 03 —in in 3 CO 3 C l CD3 CD CD3 (D CD m to LO 0 0 CD 3 3 Ul > in0 <* O’ CM CO inO *3 0 co 1^ — T VI 0 CD 0 3 0 £0 a c —0 Oc 0 0 O — 3 O O 21 O 1 1 1 i/)| O Ol J> V Ol CM 0 CO CD0 CO 03 •c ID cc CDinr'- CD 3 0) CMt" 3D CD0) 0 03 CO (D co CO 3 T V T2 3 0 a O *0 CM ST CD PM O- 3 O 3 Li C in 1 Ol 3 c 3 O a O O O O c OCMO 0 0 3 O a; 0 1 1 O r - i n — q - C ' T c ' D ’ j ' - N C N i i n N q - : ^ n L'so'fin — '»3ico»nocM«;DN:ocMo ' - o n - o o — c o c o ' - o o — o o o c o c c - i f l N n o i m B - c s f f l ' - i o n N ' - ' - s r - c M ( N p » ( N ' - i n m » - N r ~ r - o i £ > ^ i r > - N ,T n 't o c o o t— • - ' - o * - — c ? ( N c o > a « r * » « r C M i O £ M 3 r ' i n — c o D c c 3 C O in — n cm 3 300CMO*tcM*j3CMC'iCMin>-co«-c33 C — 3I I 0 3 0 3 i l l C 3 C 0 C M 0 0 0I I I — CD — oo t cm co co — r* n «t 'N U! in 3 — 3 d d a > 3 > < £ > i n o o o c : D f « o c M i n ! >* < ' o . o « T — ■" a <o cc co 3 r- d to a l~. o cc ao 3 co 3 3 23 o a © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(32)

2 9 1 1 . 5 6 2 . 0 3 . 9 5 1 . 9 0 2 . 5 n i f l ! D l B N ( O O C - Q c n o o — o o o c o o o - o o c s i c o a c c o c c — r-o r-o r-o r-o r-o r-o r-o r-o c r-o c r-o s r a — c o c M t o i n o i n i ' ' 0 o — — o o o o o — o — i i i i l i i ( 0 ( D 01 Ifl <r - V N ' O i n O O ^ I f i t M I t ' T I J l N f f l N O I I N S h D ' f — 01 01 01 o i n c M i O N i n — o c o c o > 3 - - — i n c o — r ' - i N f ~ o a ) a > — i ' ' « r c N c o f ~ o c D r ' > c o

— T — ttiocNCM — cN — 'TCDOO'ï — incMœifiincN^rtDOfNocD'a'coco —

i n — — l o ^ - ' t o — T o c n i n c o c o i n r - r ^ — c m t c c i o c m c' - — o n c m o - T r - ~ i — — — — — — i i i i i i — — — — — — i — c o ' T f ' - o o c o c o i o — < N i n ( O r - a i L n f ' ~ o i r ! ' T C N i o r ~ c D — o <j ) <T C O ' a - c M < o o c M < T C M C M a — 0 ' T i o r ~ c o c o i ' - — o ^ r o m * » CM r* n in i*) 'i IT) CN o co CM C M i o o i ( O f ^ c o s r c r ^ i r o ) i n « o ^ r t o « T O M c o a o c c u ) M i o o c r ) - ^ r c M^ r o ) < f u i n ' i o i n - i i - n i i C N i n N O - N P i m N o a i i i i o i f l n - o o i o c o ' r N i o i n n - N o i ( C - N — o i n « r c o c N N O » r — o» — o > c o « O i o r » i o c M o — — — o - o o c o o I I I I I — o c o c o o c o c d o c m in co co csi oo in r*- o — — i n io T O i o r ^ i r i N - n o m o 0 0 0 0 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 i l i i i l i o - i n f ' - o c o o i n m c M c o i n < X 5 <r OC M{ Os r C Mr ' - <t <N<t — i n — m c M D C M C N c o r o o 0 0 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 i i i . i Ol l C l N f O I BB ^ C CNh-lN — co — t i n ^ o f » co c — C M O O C N - O O C o a c o o i r ' - c o c o c o i n c D c i n o c o o t D a o i r m oo - i^ o oì o c d 0 0 - 0 0 0 0 0 0 C N C M C N O C D C D C N O t ^ m c n ^ c c o o r ' C D ^ r o r ^ t o c c c N c c i n - o — 0 0 0 — 0 0 — 0 — ç U n n 7 i n 3 n r** r - <n co » r~ o r» 3 f~ - c o - o o co — f» i n o «ì V - CO 0) Ol B C o — — o o — o I i l m m cn œ co i n t <r r- i n cm t o co o o o o o o o co r- — i n cm r - i n co — co o o o o o c co co m co O) i n m i - i n - b N o o o o o o o ■o o (N in gocm 30 — co CSI cm o o o o o o a oi co i n m m c o c o c o i o c d — c o c n c0 3 c» c o c o- a o i n c o c o i n i n co cm t 3 — co n i o i n i n i n s • - l o c o c o o i n i n o » - i n n - i n cm co cm — cc co co - 3 co — co <o co 'TCOinO-in.'OCOCOCMCMCMCMCSI — — 0 0 0000)050)0)010 0 0 0 — o o c i n o — — ^ m — * < c i ( o c o i n^ 7 — i s > * ^ o o> co — r « h- cm n h n i n i o co ( o - c r n i n - œ n c n - o - s ' r o i G c c i D ' f o c n o o ï ï P i i D i D C N i O f l i i n — C M o a c M — o o c o o - o o o o o c o c o — o o — o — — c o — o a i i i l i i i i i — O) co o «o — >» ir. oo m t — co — m . n * f : n c c 3 c o c o - — 3 c m<t 3 i o i'“ m c c N x * T O i r o c . n o - T J i a ) M — — o) > -c m— o) c n c D M o i n o — o ' r r -o — — — ■ì c-o cs. c-o c-o c-o c-o <N m — ri co co co — i r n ts co a) o o no r~ co ce f»- co — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — CN — — — — — — O — IN CO © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research

(33)

P o r t f o l i o s w i t c h e s ( P S ) w e r e c a l c u l a t e d a c c o r d i n g t o t h e f o l l o w i n g f o r m u l a o a w -o 0) u o> C w j 1! -W 0) -© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(34)

1 9 7 5 -8 7 ; Share i n R e se r v e Port fo li os . Po r t f o l i o Snitches. E x c h a n g e R a t e s » . a n O Lea ni ng T C D c o r ' C O i n c D n c D — c c n — co — a o o c o •— < T l O C O ( O C N C O O " l O C M O T — ,T C M O — *J O — O ' T C N O C M — O O O C M — ^ 0 3® — O O O O O O O O O O O C O O O O O O O a. a in h O ' - i f l i n r i ' - O ' r o i f f l f f i n o i f i N N N i C o o c o o r - ' i n i o r ~ 3 ® 0 ' J C D C D i n r ' ( 0 ' T ® m®lOr''®lOCO(OMinCO(C®CO<DC5,TO*J C M n o i ^ m p - c o o c o f f l O - — c o o m c o c M f » ® CM — co n ® o p* co ( O i D O J l ' t O ' - in o — — c o co — CM I l" CO 05 05 < j ( O N c o ® « T ® ( M o c M s r — ^ <r t*- <r 05 o p* n (o a) ® ui i o- «* C OCO — O C O C O C D O C O — P ^ O O C D O i n - I" «t c m o-co o c m o o ® ( 0 0 0 3 0 0 0 3 0 l I ■ I l I - d O ' f f f l T ' J D l C ® — OOCOCDOtOCD occm — co — c m® o o o o o o o o o o sr co o> cm p> — — in co cd o — o in ^ o o o o o — CO <r co o co o o CD P- CO f" — o 3 O ao in in — CM O o c co co co n cn B N P C O - cn — — in co o o o o o p> co o o o c Hi <t ® n p >n o t ® i c ® c M ® c o c N ® i n CM O' co 3 — 3 0 ® — O C C O * f — < T < 0 0 — 0 0 0 0 0 3 0 3 0 0 0 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 I I I i I I in 7 IS ® ID ® T D ID - P IN co — (D~~P'-O O 3 ® 03 - M C O I C l D N C O S - N I c o ' T ' f ' j ' T c o c o ' j o c o o c o c o n c o j o c o i o r , p> *y a j P i f i - i c i n i o c o c o c N ' - i n c M i f i 3 O P » ^ T 3 C 0 — O — CM — O C N C M O O G 0 3 0 3 0 3 0 3 C O O O O O O O O O mi f l ON N ^ -C D "*• CO cf ID in M P~ D 5 ( D 5 ] ( D ® - N ( t v p j ) ! C S ® ® ® C O n r o o o o C 3 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

Siamo quindi convinti che l’importanza degli ordines coronationis risieda soprattutto nella capacità di indicarci come i loro compilatori – e i loro committenti – avrebbero volu-

For the first time, as far as we know, we proposed in the image registration context the use of com- pactly supported radial basis Gneiting’s functions, which perform well in

5 Una rassegna comparativa si trova nei Rapporti del Centro Ricerca sui Consumi di Suolo promosso dall’Istituto nazionale di urbanistica, da Legambiente Onlus, e dal Dastu

51 School of Physics and Astronomy, University of Edinburgh, Edinburgh, United Kingdom 52 School of Physics and Astronomy, University of Glasgow, Glasgow, United Kingdom 53 Oliver

Finally, a predictive numerical study on the time to failure response is presented for load levels that can not be experimentally tested..

E Glucose consumption per million of cells estimated in the cell-populated scaffold provided with a channel Ri /Re = 0.375 cultured in the perfused bioreactor and under

Once again, the importance of a cultural initiative, which is also rich in symbolic significance, has led to a very effective foreign policy by Mediterranean Europe,

Per quanto la fonte non sia esplicitamente indicata, non pare dubbio che il racconto della caccia sia ispirato alla parte iniziale di una leggenda molto diffusa, riferita