• Non ci sono risultati.

Game Theory: lecture of April 2, 2019

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "Game Theory: lecture of April 2, 2019"

Copied!
13
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

Game Theory: lecture of April 2, 2019

Chiara Mocenni

Course on Game Theory

(2)

Symmetric Games with two players (1/2)

A game is symmetric when the two players obtain the same payoff under the same conditions.

A symmetric game involves two players with the same number of strategies and the payoff function of any strategy is

independent on the location of the player that is playing at a given time.

Assuming the equivalence of the payoff functions of the pure strategies is equivalent to assume that the payoff bi-matrix of the second player is the transpose of the payoff matrix of the first player, that is: B = AT.

(3)

Symmetric Games with two players (2/2)

With K = {1, 2, ..., k} we indicate the set of pure strategies With x ∈ ∆ e y ∈ ∆ we indicate the mixed strategies of the first and the second player, where

∆ = {x ∈ R+k :P

i ∈Kxi = 1}, while Θ = ∆2.

The set of best reply β(z) is calculated with respect to one strategy z ∈ ∆ and it is the same for both players:

β(z) = {x ∈ ∆ : π(x , z) ≥ π(y , z) ∀y ∈ ∆}.

(4)

Symmetric Nash Equilibria

A couple of strategies (x , y ) ∈ Θ = ∆2 (strategy profile) is a Nash equilibrium, (x , y ) ∈ ΘNE, is and only if x ∈ β(y ) and y ∈ β(x ). If x = y , the equilibrium (x , y ) is said symmetric.

The subset of strategies x ∈ ∆ that are in equilibrium with themselves is:

NE = {x ∈ ∆ : (x , x ) ∈ ΘNE}

The Nash equilibria of a symmetric game can be asymmetric, but each symmetric game has at least one symmetric Nash equilibrium.

Theorem

For each finite symmetric game with two players,, ∆NE 6= ∅.

(5)

Classification of 2x2 symmetric games

In this section we analyze games where players have only two pure strategies available. Let be the generic payoff matrix of a 2 × 2 symmetric game:

A =

 a11 a12 a21 a22



Subtracting a21 from the first column and a12 from the second, we have:

A0 =

 a11− a21 0 0 a22− a12



In this way we obtain a symmetric matrix and then a symmetric game, with payoff matrix:

A0=

 a1 0 0 a2



Where a1 = a11− a21 and a2 = a22− a12.

(6)

Graphical representation

The obtained matrix is identified by one point a = (a1, a2) ∈ R2. This point will belong to one of the orthants of this cartesian plane, allowing us to identify the category to which the game corresponds.

(7)

Calculus of symmetric Nash equilibria

If x ∈ ∆NE (x is a symmetric Nash equilibrium), then x ∈ β(x ). In other words:

π(x , x ) ≥ π(y , x ) ∀y ∈ ∆, or

xTAx ≥ yTAx ∀y ∈ ∆.

We can rewrite the equation in terms of sums:

k

X

i =1

xi[Ax ]i

k

X

i =1

yi[Ax ]i ∀y ∈ ∆, (1) where [Ax ]i indicates l’i -th component of vector Ax .

(8)

Theorem for pure equilibria

Theorem

Let x be a pure strategy (x = eh). If [Ax ]h≥ [Ax]i ∀i 6= h, then x ∈ ∆NE.

Proof.

Let M = [Ax ]h. We have that:

k

X

i =1

xi[Ax ]i = xh[Ax ]h= M, and

k

X

i =1

yi[Ax ]i = yh[Ax ]h+

k

X

i =1,i 6=h

yi[Ax ]i = yhM +

k

X

i =1,i 6=h

yi[Ax ]i.

(9)

... cont

Since M ≥ [Ax ]i ∀i 6= h, then:

k

X

i =1,i 6=h

yi[Ax ]i

k

X

i =1,i 6=h

yiM = (1 − yh)M.

Therfore:

Pk

i =1xi[Ax ]i = M, e Pk

i =1yi[Ax ]i ≤ M.

From this it follows that

k

X

i =1

xi[Ax ]i

k

X

i =1

yi[Ax ]i ∀y ∈ ∆.

(10)

Theorem for the mixed equilibria

Theorem

Let x be a strategy belonging to int∆, that is it is a mixed strategy such that xi > 0 ∀i . If [Ax ]i = [Ax ]j ∀i , j, then x ∈ ∆NE. Proof.

Let M = [Ax ]i ∀i . Then:

k

X

i =1

xi[Ax ]i =

k

X

i =1

xiM = M

k

X

i =1

xi = M · 1 = M, and

k

X

i =1

yi[Ax ]i =

k

X

i =1

yiM = M

k

X

i =1

yi = M · 1 = M.

(11)

... cont

Then, equation (1) holds always in non strict form, that is:

k

X

i =1

xi[Ax ]i =

k

X

i =1

yi[Ax ]i ∀y ∈ ∆.

This means that x is a symmetric Nash equilibrium. Moreover, this equilibrium is non strict.

(12)

Theorem for pure/mixed equilibria

Theorem

Let x be a mixed strategy with only one null component (xh= 0, xi > 0 ∀i 6= h). If [Ax ]i = [Ax ]j ∀i 6= h, j 6= h, and [Ax ]i ≥ [Ax]h ∀i 6= h then x ∈ ∆NE.

Proof. Let M = [Ax ]i ∀i 6= h. Then:

k

X

i =1

xi[Ax ]i =

k

X

i =1

xiM = M

k

X

i =1

xi = M · 1 = M, and

k

X

i =1

yi[Ax ]i =

k

X

i =1,i 6=h

yiM + yh[Ax ]h= M

k

X

i =1,i 6=h

yi + yh[Ax ]h=

= M(1 − yh) + yh[Ax ]h.

(13)

... cont

In the second equation we have used the fact that

k

X

i =1

yi = 1 ⇒

k

X

i =1,i 6=h

yi = 1 − yh. By assumption, we have that M ≥ [Ax ]h. It follows that:

M ≥ [Ax]h

yhM ≥ yh[Ax ]h

yhM + M − M ≥ yh[Ax ]h

M − M(1 − yh) ≥ yh[Ax ]h ⇒ M ≥ M(1 − yh) + yh[Ax ]h

k

X

i =1

xi[Ax ]i

k

X

i =1

yi[Ax ]i ∀y ∈ ∆.

Since x satisfy eq. (1) for each y , then x is a symmetric Nash eq.

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

[r]

, n, has all entries equal to zero except those whose indeces are in ν(i) which are set equal to 1/µ i.. Let us explicit these formulas... Assume now that at the same time a new site

In the case of a matrix in reduced row echelon form this is even easier: the pivot columns are

[r]

Answer: the determinant of the matrix is always 0 so the matrix is not invertible for any k, and the rank is either 1 or 2.. So the function is injective, and

[r]

To receive full credit, show all of your work.. Neither calculators nor computers

To receive full credit, show all of your work.. Neither calculators nor computers