• Non ci sono risultati.

Three Dimensional Fractal Attractors in a Green Transition Economic Growth Model

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "Three Dimensional Fractal Attractors in a Green Transition Economic Growth Model"

Copied!
21
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

19/20

Working Paper Series

THREE DIMENSIONAL FRACTAL ATTRACTORS

IN A GREEN TRANSITION ECONOMIC

GROWTH MODEL

S IMO NE MARS I GL IO an d F AB IO P RIV IL EG GI

D

e

p

a

rt

m

e

n

t

o

f

E

co

n

o

m

ic

s

a

n

d

S

ta

ti

st

ic

s

C

o

g

n

e

tt

i

d

e

M

a

rt

ii

s”

Ca

mpu

s Lu

ig

i E

in

au

d

i,

Lu

n

g

o

Do

ra S

ien

a 1

00

/A,

1

01

53

Tori

n

o

(I

tal

y)

www

.est

.u

n

it

o.

it

(2)
(3)

Three Dimensional Fractal Attractors in a

Green Transition Economic Growth Model

Simone Marsiglio

Fabio Privileggi

August 26, 2020

Abstract

We analyze a two-sector stochastic economic growth model of green transition with pollution externalities and foreign capital. The final good is produced by combining dirty and clean inputs, with different implications on pollution accumulation. Pollution nega-tively affects production capabilities and can be reduced by switching to the clean input. The clean input is produced by using the dirty input and the foreign capital received (in the form of dirty input). Random shocks make the effective economy’s ability to transition to green activities highly uncertain, eventually undermining its economic development. Such a setting gives rise to a dynamic system represented by a three dimensional affine iterated function system. We show that the economy’s steady state is represented by an invariant measure supported on a compact set, characterizing its fractal nature and showing that its attractor may be a distorted Sierpi´nski tetrahedron.

Keywords: Development Aids, Economic Growth, Fractal Attractors, Green Transition, Pollution

JEL Classification: C61, O41, Q56

1

Introduction

Since Boldrin and Montrucchio’s seminal work (1986), the analysis of complexity and chaos in macroeconomic dynamics has received ever growing interest (Montrucchio, 1994; Nishimura and Yano, 1995; Brock and Hommes, 1997). A large share of the literature has focused on stochastic economic growth models showing that they may give rise to nontrivial dynamics eventually converging to invariant measures supported on fractal sets, characterizing the prop-erties of such invariant measures in terms of singularity and absolute continuity along with those of the fractal features of the steady states (Montrucchio and Privileggi, 1999; Mitra et al., 2003; Mitra and Privileggi, 2004, 2006, 2009). Most works focus on traditional one- or two-sector growth models in which economic dynamics are entirely described by (physical and human) capital accumulation and can be represented by a one or two-dimensional affine iter-ated function systems (IFS) converging to singular measures supported on either the Cantor set or the Sierpi´nski gasket (La Torre et al., 2011; Marsiglio, 2012; La Torre et al., 2015, 2018b). Very few works extend the traditional growth framework to analyze also environmental and

University of Pisa, Department of Economics and Management, via Cosimo Ridolfi 10, 56124 Pisa, Italy. Contact: simone.marsiglio@unipi.it.

Department of Economics and Statistics “Cognetti de Martiis”, University of Turin, Torino, Italy. Email: fabio.privileggi@unito.it.

(4)

sustainability problems by accounting for pollution accumulation, showing that the support of the invariant measure could even resemble the Barnsley’s fern (Privileggi and Marsiglio, 2013; La Torre et al., 2018a). Due to the growing importance of environmental considerations for the future prospects of economic development, in this paper we wish to contribute to this lat-ter branch of the lilat-terature by analyzing a stochastic growth model of green transition in a developing country to explore the fractal properties of the steady state of more sophisticated economic growth models with environmental feedback effects.

Since polluting emissions in developing countries are expected to increase by more than 50% in the next decades (Clarke et al., 2009; IEA, 2010), in order to ensure the sustainability of the world economy it is essential that industrialized countries and international organizations pro-mote and support a process of green transition in poor countries. For example, in recent climate change negotiations industrialized countries have committed to mobilize a substantial amount of resources to address the needs of developing countries and favor mitigation and adaptation policies through the means of development aid and foreign direct investments. However, despite the rhetoric, reality is much different. The development aid effectively in place in developing countries are still to a large extent devoted to projects financing traditional economic activi-ties, such as transportation, building infrastructure and mining, and only a very limited part is employed in green activities, such as favoring access to clean water, biodiversity, CO2 reduction

and soil conservation (Hicks et al., 2008). The effects of foreign direct investment are even more problematic: as extensively discussed in the pollution haven literature, regulation and distorted incentives in industrialized countries may push local firms to relocate their activities in poor economies exporting dirty technologies and increasing emissions in such countries (Mani and Wheeler, 1998; Copeland and Taylor, 2004). Therefore, future development prospects in developing countries are highly uncertain, and as a consequence so are those of the entire world economy. In order to consider the effects of development aid and foreign direct investments on the economic and environmental performance of developing countries we extend traditional growth models to account for foreign capital.

Specifically, we focus on a developing country and its transition towards green activities, and in particular on the effects of the foreign capital it receives, inclusive of development aid and foreign direct investments, on such a transitional process. We consider a two-sector economy in which one sector produces the final consumption good while the other a clean production factor. The final good is produced by combining two perfectly substitutable inputs, a dirty and a clean input, which differ only in their environmental implications: while the dirty input generates polluting emissions deteriorating environmental quality, the clean input is completely emissions-free. In particular, the use of the dirty input in the production process contributes to accumulate pollution, which in turn negatively affects the economy’s ability to produce the final good through a production externality. However, the dirty input can also be used to produce the clean input which by being totally environmental friendly does not lead to undesirable side-effects on production capabilities. Therefore, a share of the dirty input, along with a share of the foreign capital received (in the form of dirty input), is allocated to produce the clean input lowering thus environmental footprints. The amount of foreign capital received, its productivity in the production of the clean input, and its environmental efficiency are subject to random shocks due to political, technological and environmental issues. The existence of such shocks make the effective economy’s ability to transition to green activities highly uncertain, eventually undermining its entire economic development. Such a setting gives rise to a dynamic system which can be described by the means of a three dimensional affine IFS, which by borrowing from the mathematics literature (see, among others, Hutchinson, 1981; Barnsley and Demko, 1985; Barnsley et al., 1986; Vrscay, 1991; Barnsley, 1993; Diaconis and Freedman, 1999; Mendivil

(5)

and Vrscay, 2002a, 2002b; Ngai and Wang, 2005; La Torre et al., 2006; Kunze et al. 2007; Niu and Xi, 2007; Barnsley et al., 2008; La Torre and Vrscay, 2009; La Torre et al., 2009; Kunze et al., 2012), can be analyzed to characterize its steady state outcome along with its fractal nature. We show that, under a suitable parameter configuration, the attractor of such a three dimensional IFS is a distorted copy of the Sierpi´nski tetrahedron and we establish a novel mathematical result that simplifies the process of establishing whether the associated invariant measure is singular. To the best of our knowledge, no other paper has thus far explored the possibility that the fractal attractor of economic growth models may have a three dimensional representation.

The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 introduces our framework which consists of a two-sector stochastic growth model of green transition with pollution externalities and foreign capital, showing that the economy’s steady state is represented by an invariant measure sup-ported on a compact set. Section 3 briefly reviews the theory on IFS which we need in our analysis. Section 4 recalls the characteristics of the classical Sierpi´nski tetrahedron. Section 5 shows that, under some conditions on parameters, the fractal attractor of our dynamic system may resemble a (possibly highly) distorted of copy of the classical Sierpi´nski tetrahedron. Sec-tion 6 presents concluding remarks and proposes direcSec-tions for future research. Technicalities are postponed to the Appendix.

2

The Model

We analyze a two-sector model of economic growth with environmental feedback effects, and for the sake of simplicity we consider a purely dynamic setting abstracting completely from agents’ optimization. The unique final consumption good, yt, is produced through a linear

production function combining two perfectly substitutable inputs, a dirty input (i.e., capital or fossil fuels), kt, and a clean input (i.e., renewable energy), gt. A certain share 0 < u < 1

of the dirty input is invested to produce the clean input, thus only the remaining share 1 − u is devoted to the production of the consumable good. Therefore, the final output is produced according to the following technology: yt = a (1 − u) kt+ bgt, where a > 0 and b > 0 measure

the productivity of the two factors. The use of the dirty input in production activities generates emissions which increase pollution, pt, which in turn reduces production by a random factor

βt ≥ 0 via an additive productivity shock. Net (of pollution externality) output is thus given

by: ˜yt = yt− βtpt. The clean input is produced according to a linear production technology

employing only a given share of the dirty input as follows: xt = dukt, where xt is the newly

produced quantity and d > 0 quantifies the productivity in the clean input sector. Foreign capital, ft, inclusive of development aid and foreign direct investments, is received through a

transfer of the dirty input from industrialized countries. A share 0 < v < 1 of such foreign (dirty) input is devoted to the accumulation of the dirty input and the remaining share 1 − v to produce the clean input with random productivity et ≥ 0.

The dirty input accumulates due to saving and foreign capital while is reduced by depre-ciation as follows: kt+1 = s˜yt+ vft+ (1 − δk) kt, where 0 < s < 1 is the saving rate, ˜yt net

output, and δk > 0 the dirty input depreciation rate. Similarly, the clean input accumulates

due to the devoted investment and foreign capital while it is reduced by depreciation as follows: gt+1 = xt+ (1 − v) etft+ (1 − δg) gt, where δg >0 is the clean input depreciation rate. Pollution

increases with the emissions associated with the use of dirty input and foreign capital in the production process, and decreases due to the ability of the natural ecosystem to absorb pollu-tion as follows: pt+1 = γtkt+ µtft+ (1 − η) pt, where γt ≥ 0 and µt ≥ 0 quantify the random

(6)

respec-tively, and η > 0 is the natural decay rate of pollution. Therefore, given the initial conditions k0, g0 and p0, our model economy can be described by the following system of three difference

equations:    kt+1 = s [a (1 − u) kt+ bgt− βtpt] + (1 − δk) kt+ vft gt+1 = dukt+ (1 − δg) gt+ (1 − v) etft pt+1 = γtkt+ µtft+ (1 − η) pt (1) Some comments are needed in order to clarify our setting and assumptions. (i) The linearity of the output production function in the dirty and clean inputs implies that the two production factors are perfectly substitutable, and thus the economy is able to produce a positive amount of the consumable good by employing only one of two inputs. We may think of this as a scenario in which the production of the final good requires electricity, which may be alternatively generated through fossil fuels or renewable sources. (ii) The possibility to produce the clean input by employing only the dirty input builds on this type of interpretation allowing thus our model to describe the transition from fossil fuels to renewable energy. For example, polluting machines can be used to set up photovoltaic plans allowing to produce clean energy which can be used to produce consumable goods reducing polluting emissions. (iii) The assumption that foreign capital takes the form of the dirty input is consistent with empirical evidence regarding the functioning of developing aid and foreign direct investments in the real world (Hicks et al., 2008; Mani and Wheeler, 1998). (iv) The assumptions that pollution negatively affects only the production of the final good and that the clean input is entirely emissions-free are mere simplifying hypotheses. Relaxing them to allow for a detrimental effect of pollution also in the clean sector and for the generation of emissions also with the use of the clean input in the production process will not modify our main conclusions.

To emphasize the affine features of system (1) it is convenient to isolate all three variables, kt, gt and pt, from their coefficients and from the additive constants and rewrite it as follows:

   kt+1 = s [a (1 − u) + 1 − δk] kt+ sbgt− sβtpt+ vft gt+1 = dukt+ (1 − δg) gt+ (1 − v) etft pt+1 = γtkt+ (1 − η) pt+ µtft. (2)

We assume that some of the parameters in (2) represent random exogenous shocks, so that they can have different values according to different realizations of such shocks. Specifically, we shall assume that the economy is affected by N exogenous shocks determining the values of some of the parameters ft, et, µt, βt and γt. The stochastic process generating the sequence of

shocks will be assumed to be i.i.d. so that each realization will occur with a constant probability pi satisfying 0 < pi <1, for i = 1, . . . , N , and such that PNi=1pi = 1 (see La Torre et al., 2019,

for a generalization in which probabilities are state dependent). Hence, the parameter vector (ft, et, µt, βt, γt) will take on N values (fi, ei, µi, βi, γi), for i = 1, . . . , N , independently on time

t. Under these assumptions the dynamics described by (2) represent what is often referred to as an iterated function system with probabilities (IFSP) and turn out to be more conveniently handled in matrix form according to:

  kt+1 gt+1 pt+1  =   akk i a kg i a kp i agki a gg i a gp i apki apgi appi     kt gt pt  +   zk i zig zip   for i = 1, . . . , N, (3)

where the matrix’s coefficients are akk

i ≡ akk = s [a (1 − u) + 1 − δk], akgi ≡ akg = sb, a kp i = −sβi, agki ≡ agk = du, a gg i ≡ agg = (1 − δg), agpi ≡ agp = 0, a pk i = γi, apgi ≡ apg = 0 and

appi ≡ app = (1 − η), while the additive constants are zk

(7)

When the dynamics is stochastic and evolve according to a law of the type defined in (3) the long-run equilibrium steady state ceases to be a fixed point in the common sense and becomes an invariant measure supported on some compact set called attractor (Mitra et al., 2003; La Torre et al., 2015).

3

Mathematical Preliminaries

We now briefly review some well known results in the IFSP literature, and specifically we discuss the main definitions and results on IFSP, their attractor, the invariant measure supported on it and its singularity vs. absolute continuity. A huge literature is available on such topics; the reader is referred to, among others, Hutchinson (1981), Barnsley and Demko (1985), Barnsley et al. (1986), Vrscay (1991), Barnsley (1993), Diaconis and Freedman (1999), Mendivil and Vrscay (2002a, 2002b), Ngai and Wang (2005), La Torre et al. (2006), Kunze et al. (2007), Niu and Xi (2007), Barnsley et al. (2008), La Torre and Vrscay (2009), La Torre et al. (2009). For a recent comprehensive and detailed treatment see Kunze et al. (2012). We also present an original extension of these basic results (Corollary 3) that will be useful for our subsequent analysis.

3.1

Iterated Function Systems

Let (X, d) denote a compact metric space. An N -map Iterated Function System (IFS) on X, w = {w1, . . . , wN}, consists of N contraction mappings on X, i.e., wi : X → X, i = 1, · · · , N ,

with contraction factors ci ∈ [0, 1) (see Barnsley, 1993; Hutchinson, 1981; Barnsley et al., 1986;

Kunze et al., 2012). Associated with an N -map IFS one can define a set-valued mapping ˆw on the space H ([a, b]) of nonempty compact subsets of X as follows:

ˆ w (S) := N [ i=1 wi(S) , S ∈ H ([a, b]) . (4)

The following two results state a convergence property of an N -map IFS towards its at-tractor. More properties and results can be found in Barnsley (1993), Hutchinson (1981), and Kunze et al. (2012).

Theorem 1 (Hutchinson, 1981) For A, B ∈ H (X),

h( ˆw (A) , ˆw (B)) ≤ ch (A, B) where c= max

1≤i≤Nci <1

and h denotes the Hausdorff metric on H (X).

Corollary 1 (Hutchinson, 1981) There exists a unique set A ∈ H ([a, b]), the attractor of the IFS w, such that

A= ˆw (A) =

N

[

i=1

wi(A) .

(8)

3.2

Iterated Function Systems with Probabilities and their Invariant

Measure

An N -map Iterated Function System with Probabilities (IFSP) (w,p) is an N -map IFS w with associated probabilities p = {p1, . . . , pN} satisfying 0 < pi <1, for i = 1, . . . , N , and such that

PN

i=1pi = 1.

Let M (X) denote the set of probability measures on (Borel subsets of) X and dM K the

Monge-Kantorovich distance on this space: For µ, ν ∈ M (X), with Monge-Kantorovich metric, dM K(µ, ν) = sup f ∈Lip1(X) Z fd µ − Z fd ν  .

where Lip1(X) = {f : X → R | |f (x) − f (y)| ≤ d (x, y)}. The metric space (M (X) , dM K) is

complete (Barnsley, 1993; Hutchinson, 1981; Kunze et al., 2012).

The Markov operator associated with an N -map IFSP is a mapping M : M → M, defined as follows: For any µ ∈ M (X), and for any measurable set S ⊂ X, define a measure ν = M µ as: ν(S) = (M µ) (S) = N X i=1 piµw−1i (S) .

The following results show that the Markov operator has a unique invariant measure ¯µand it is globally attracting.

Theorem 2 (Hutchinson, 1981) For µ, ν ∈ M (X),

dM K(M µ, M ν) ≤ cdM K(µ, ν) .

Corollary 2 (Hutchinson, 1981) There exists a unique measure ¯µ∈ M (X), the invariant measure of the IFSP (w,p), such that

¯ µ(S) = (M ¯µ) (S) = N X i=1 piµ w¯ −1i (S) .

Moreover, for any ν ∈ M (X), dM K(¯µ, Mtν) → 0 as t → ∞.

Theorem 3 (Hutchinson, 1981) The support of the invariant measure ¯µ of an N -map IFSP (w,p) is the attractor A of the IFS w, i.e.,

supp ¯µ= A.

3.3

Singular Invariant Measures

When a IFSP (w,p) describes the dynamics of an economy the invariant measure ¯µassociated to (w,p) can be interpreted as the stochastic long-run equilibrium (steady state) of such an economy. If X = Rn the invariant measure ¯µ can be either absolutely continuous or

singu-lar with respect to the n-dimensional Lebesgue measure, according to the following general definitions.

Definition 1 Two positive measures µ and ν defined on a measurable space (Ω, Σ) are called singular if there exist two disjoint sets A and B in Σ whose union is Ω such that µ is zero on all measurable subsets of B while ν is zero on all measurable subsets of A. This is denoted by µ⊥ ν.

(9)

Definition 2 If µ and ν are two measures defined on a measurable space (Ω, Σ), we say that µ is absolutely continuous with respect to ν if µ (A) = 0 for any A ∈ Σ such that ν (A) = 0. The absolute continuity of µ with respect to ν is denoted by µ≪ ν.

This distinction is crucial as in the latter case, whenever Ω = X = Rn, Σ consists of the Borel

subsets of Rn and ν is the n-dimensional Lebesgue measure, ¯µcan be represented by a density

depending on some parameters, while in the former case there is no simple way to represent it— one actually has to list all its values on every point in its support. The mathematical literature so far has dealt with this issue by trying to characterize absolute continuity vs. singularity of ¯µ in terms of the parameters characterizing the IFS (w,p) (see, e.g., Mitra et al., 2003; La Torre et al., 2015, 2018b).

We now focus our attention on the case of affine IFSP on X = Rn. La Torre et al. (2018b)

has proved the following theorem that will allow us to study possible singularity properties of the invariant measure in the examples of the following section 5 built by means of IFSP in X = R3. In what follows let w

i(x) = Aix+ bi, where Ai are (n × n) matrices and bi ∈ Rn,

for i = 1, 2, . . . , N , in a fashion similar to the expression in (3), and pi be the associated

probabilities. The following result states a sufficient condition for the singularity of the invariant measure of an affine IFSP.

Theorem 4 (La Torre et al., 2018b) Let (w, p) = {w1, w2, . . . , wN; p1, p2, ..., pN} be an affine

IFSP on Rn having maps wi : Rn → Rn defined by wi(x) = Aix+ bi, for i = 1, 2, . . . , N , and

let p= (p1, p2, . . . , pN) be the associated probability weights. If

|det (A1)|p 1 |det (A2)|p 2 · · · |det (AN)|p N < pp1 1 p p2 2 · · · p pN N (5)

then the invariant measure µ defined by¯ (w, p) is singular.

The following corollary provides a lower bound for the RHS in (5) that will be useful in the subsequent sections, where we will be dealing with three-dimensional attractors and invariant measures supported on them.

Corollary 3 The IFSP (w, p) considered in Theorem 4 has a singular invariant measure ¯µ whenever |det (A1)|p 1 |det (A2)|p 2 · · · |det (AN)|p N ≤ e−Ne ≃ (0.6922)N. (6)

Proof. See the Appendix.

The lower bound in the RHS of condition (6) is a rough estimate; however it will be enough to establish singularity of all the invariant measures we will obtain in our simulations in the next sections.

4

The Standard Sierpi´

nski Tetrahedron

As our goal is to build three-dimensional attractors that resemble the well known Sierpi´nski tetrahedron by means of the affine IFS (3), before tackling such a construction we first recall how the tetrahedron can be obtained from an affine IFS. Abstracting from probabilities, the IFS that generates the Sierpi´nski tetrahedron in R3 consists of N = 4 affine maps w

i : R3 → R3

that have the following matrix representation:   kt+1 gt+1 pt+1  = wi     kt gt pt    =   akk i a kg i a kp i agki aggi agpi apki apgi appi     kt gt pt  +   zk i zig zip   for i = 1, . . . , 4, (7)

(10)

where we use the (kt, gt, pt) notation for the variables consistent with our economic model

defined by (3). The standard Sierpi´nski tetrahedron is characterized by six edges of size 1 and has its base on the Sierpi´nski triangle of vertices (0, 0), (1, 0) and12,√23, so that its vertices in R3 are (0, 0, 0), (1, 0, 0),1 2, √ 3 2 ,0  and12,√1 12, q 2 3 

. Table 1 reports the values for the matrix coefficients and the vector of additive constants zk

i, z g i, z

p

i required by the IFS (7) to generate

it recursively. Specifically, the matrix is diagonal having all terms in its diagonal equal to 12 and 0 elsewhere, while the crucial parameters turn out to be the additive terms zk

i, z g i and z

p i.

Clearly, under the parameterization of Table 1 the IFS (7) is a contraction. i akk i a gg i a pp i a kg i a kp i a gk i a gp i a pk i a pg i zik z g i z p i 1 12 12 12 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 2 12 12 12 0 0 0 0 0 0 12 0 0 3 1 2 1 2 1 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 4 √ 3 4 0 4 12 12 12 0 0 0 0 0 0 14 4√1 3 1 √ 6

Table 1: parameters’ values for the N = 4 maps wi characterizing the IFS generating the standard Sierpi´nski tetrahedron.

The standard Sierpi´nski tetrahedron, however, does not provide an appropriate reference point for our economic dynamics described by (3) because for values of the variables (kt, gt, pt) in

a neighborhood of the vertex (0, 0, 0)—i.e., the origin—a value sufficiently large for parameters s and βi might push the capital into negative territory. Therefore, we shall consider the same

tetrahedron defined by the parameterization in Table 1 but shifted inside the positive orthant by the constant 1

2 with respect to all three variables kt, gt and pt: specifically, we will focus

on the tetrahedron with vertices 12,12,12, 3 2, 1 2, 1 2,  1,√3+12 ,12and 1,√23+1√ 3 , √ 3+2√2 2√3  having parameter values listed in Table 2, where the slopes—the contraction factors—of the maps wi

are the same as in Table 1 and only the additive constants zk i, z

g i and z

p

i change their values.

i akk i a gg i a pp i a kg i a kp i a gk i a gp i a pk i a pg i zik z g i z p i 1 1 2 1 2 1 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 4 1 4 1 4 2 12 12 12 0 0 0 0 0 0 34 14 14 3 1 2 1 2 1 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 2 √ 3+1 4 1 4 4 12 12 12 0 0 0 0 0 0 1243+1√ 3 √ 3+2√2 4√3

Table 2: parameters’ values for the N = 4 maps wi characterizing the IFS generating a Sierpi´nski tetrahedron shifted inside the positive orthant.

It is well known that the standard Sierpi´nski tetrahedron has Hausdorff dimension given by ln 4ln 2 = 2; that is, it is a three-dimensional object having the same consistency of a surface. In fact, if all points are projected onto a plane that is parallel to two of the outer edges, they exactly fill a square of side length √1

2 without overlap. Moreover, without making any

assumption on the probability vector (p1, p2, ..., p4) to be associated to the maps wi defined in

(7) for the parameters’ values provided in both Tables 1 and 2 so to get a full IFSP, we can directly apply Corollary 3 to establish that the invariant measure ¯µ generated by any IFSP as in (7) is always singular, for any choice on the probabilities p1, p2, ..., p4. To see this, note

(11)

that the determinant of the matrices Ai in (7) are the same for all i = 1, ..., 4 and equal to

det (Ai) ≡ det (A) = 12

3

= 18 so that condition (6) boils down to |det (A1)|p 1 |det (A2)|p 2 · · · |det (A4)|p 4 = 1 8 p1+p2+···+p4 = 1 8 = 0.125 < e −4e ≃ 0.2296 (8)

and the singularity property is established for any probability vector (p1, p2, ..., p4).

By exploiting the “transform” routine in Maple, which is capable of transforming three-dimensional graphic objects in R3, we built a simple procedure to approximate the standard

Sierpi´nski tetrahedron by iterating the set-valued map defined in (4). Our procedure produces 4 modified copies of any geometric object in R3 recognizable by Maple by applying the

trans-formation through the N = 4 maps defined in (7) according to operator (4). Figure 1 plots the first 6 iterations of operator (4) according to such a procedure starting from the full tetrahedron with vertices 12,12,12, 3 2, 1 2, 1 2,  1,√3+12 ,12and 1,√23+1√ 3 , √ 3+2√2 2√3  . 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.81 1.2 g 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 k (a) 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.81 1.2 g 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 k (b) 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.81 1.2 g 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 k (c) 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.81 1.2 g 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 k (d) 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.8 1 1.2 g 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 k (e) 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.8 1 1.2 g 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 k (f) 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.8 1 1.2 g 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 k (g)

Figure 1: first 6 iterations of our algorithm to approximate the Sierpi´nski tetrahedron starting from the full tetrahedron with vertices 12,12,12, 3

2,12,12,  1,√3+12 ,12and 1,√3+1 2√3 , √ 3+2√2 2√3  .

5

Sierpi´

nski-Tetrahedron-Like Attractors

We now exploit the construction behind the standard Sierpi´nski tetrahedron presented in the previous section to build an IFS that embeds the assumptions of the economic model described in Section 2 and turns out to be a version of the IFS (7)—with parameter values slightly different from those in Table 2—capable of generating a distorted version of the Sierpi´nski tetrahedron as the asymptotic attractor of our model economy. The striking difference between

(12)

the IFS (2)—or (3)—and the IFS (7) with parameters defined in Table 2 is the presence of some mixed nonzero multiplicative coefficients in the matrix in place of the zeros featured by Table 2. We will keep such nonzero values small in order to build affine IFS that generate dynamics somewhat resembling those required to obtain the Sierpi´nski tetrahedron as an attractor.

We pursue such a goal through two examples characterized by opposite approaches. In the first one, after setting parameters βi, γi, s, a, u, δg, η, δk and v arbitrarily, we will compute

the random additive constants zk i, z

g

i and z p

i in order to obtain exactly the vertices of the

(shifted) standard Sierpi´nski tetrahedron as the four fixed points of the four maps wi in the IFS

(7), and, finally, we will determine the unique values of the remaining parameters (fi, ei, µi)

compatible with these zk i, z

g i and z

p

i values. In the second example, on the contrary, we first set

all parameters βi, γi, s, a, u, δg, η, δk, v, fi, ei and µi arbitrarily, and next use such values to

evaluate the four (deterministic) fixed points associated to each map wi in (7), for i = 1, . . . , 4;

the latter will then be used as the vertices of the non-standard full tetrahedron to be employed as initial geometric object for the iterations of operator (4) according to our Maple procedure.

5.1

Using the Standard Sierpi´

nski Tetrahedron as Reference Point

In our first exercise we assume that the shocks on the final good production and on the envi-ronmental inefficiency associated with the use of the dirty input are deterministic and constant over time, i.e., we set

βi ≡ β = 1 5 and γi ≡ γ = 1 10. Moreover, we assume s= a = u = δg = η = 1 2 and b = d = 1 5,

which imply that the diagonal coefficients aggi ≡ (1 − δg) and appi ≡ (1 − η) are both 12, as

desired, while akk

i ≡ s [a (1 − u) + 1 − δk] = 12 as well whenever

δk =

5 8.

Note that under such parameterization the mixed coefficients are kept small in absolute value, as akgi ≡ sb = 1 10, a kp i ≡ −sβ = −101, a gk i ≡ du = 101 and a pk i ≡ γ = 101 , while still a gp i = a pg i = 0.

In order to choose the values for the random additive constants zk i, z

g

i and z p

i in this first

example we set the steady state values (k∗

i, gi∗, p∗i) of the N = 4 maps wi in the IFS to be the

vertices 1 2, 1 2, 1 2, 3 2, 1 2, 1 2,  1,√3+1 2 , 1 2  and 1,√3+1 2√3 , √ 3+2√2 2√3 

of the full tetrahedron used as initial set in the approximation of the fractal provided by Figure 1(g), which is generated by the IFS defined by the parameters’ values in Table 2. In other words, we solve

   k∗ i = akki k∗i + a kg i gi∗+ a kp i p∗i + zik g∗ i = a gk i k∗i + a gg i gi∗+ z g i p∗ i = a pk i ki∗+ a pp i p∗i + z p i ⇐⇒    zk i = 1 2k∗i − 1 10gi∗+ 1 10p∗i zgi = −101 k∗ i + 12gi∗ zpi = −1 10k∗i + 12p∗i with respect to zk i, z g i and z p

i for all steady state (the 4 tetrahedron vertices) values (k∗i, g∗i, p∗i)

for i = 1, . . . , 4. The whole set of parameter values is reported in Table 3.

To conclude, we can choose any (constant) value for the deterministic parameter 0 < v < 1, the share of foreign (dirty) input devoted to the accumulation of the dirty input, kt, and solve

(13)

i akk i a gg i a pp i a kg i a kp i a gk i a gp i a pk i a pg i zik z g i z p i 1 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 10 − 1 10 1 10 0 1 10 0 1 4 1 5 1 5 2 21 12 12 101 −101 101 0 101 0 34 101 101 3 12 12 12 101 −101 101 0 101 0 10−20√3 3+520√3 203 4 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 10 − 1 10 1 10 0 1 10 0 0.5528 0.2943 0.5582

Table 3: parameters’ values for the N = 4 maps wi characterizing the IFS generating a distorted Sierpi´nski tetrahedron starting from the standard tetrahedron shifted inside the positive orthant.

the system    vfi = zik (1 − v) etft= zig µtft= zip (9) with respect to foreign capital, fi, its random productivity to produce the clean input, ei, and

the random environmental inefficiency associated with the use of foreign capital, µi, in each

random realization i = 1, . . . , 4 by using the zk i, z

g i, z

p

i values in the last three columns of Table

3. Following this approach we find 4 triples (fi, ei, µi), each corresponding to a realization of

the random shocks, for i = 1, . . . , 4. For example, by setting vi ≡ v = 13, Table 4 lists the

corresponding (fi, ei, µi) values solving system (9) in each random realization i = 1, . . . , 4.

i fi ei µi

1 0.75 0.4 0.2667

2 2.25 0.0667 0.0444

3 1.242 0.7051 0.1209

4 1.6583 0.2662 0.3366

Table 4: values of the foreign capital, fi, its random productivity for the clean input, ei, and the random environmental inefficiency associated with the use of foreign capital, µi, for v = 13 and

corresponding to each random shock realization i = 1, . . . , 4.

In this example the matrix of the affine maps wi in the IFS (7) is still constant through all

shocks configurations, although it is not diagonal anymore; specifically, according to the values in Table 3: Ai ≡ A =    1 2 1 10 − 1 10 1 10 1 2 0 1 10 0 1 2   .

Therefore, again without making any assumption on the probability vector (p1, p2, ..., p4) to be

associated with the maps wi to get a full IFSP, we can directly apply Corollary 3 to establish

that the invariant measure ¯µ generated by any IFSP (7) is always singular, for any choice on the probabilities p1, p2, ..., p4. In fact, the determinant of A above turns out to be the same as

that of the diagonal matrix that generates the standard Sierpi´nski tetrahedron, det (A) = 1 8, so

that condition (6) still holds and coincides with (8).

Figure 2 plots the first 6 iterations of operator (4) according to our Maple procedure starting from the full tetrahedron with vertices 1

2, 1 2, 1 2, 3 2, 1 2, 1 2,  1,√3+1 2 , 1 2  and 1,√3+1 2√3 , √ 3+2√2 2√3  . The distorting effect of the nonzero mixed coefficients akgi , akpi , agki and apki is immediately seen in Figure 2(b) already after the first iteration: the first four smaller tetrahedra generated by

(14)

the transformation appear to wander around the vertices of the initial tetrahedron and are being rotated counterclockwise. Moreover, by taking a perspective of the same prefractals from a different angle, Figure 3 shows that the smaller tetrahedra arising after each iteration of operator (4) become more flattened along the direction crossing the positive orthant of variables (k, g) from north-west to south-east and stretched along the direction entering the same orthant from the origin.

0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.81 1.2 g 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 k (a) 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.4 0.8 1.2 g 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 k (b) 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.4 0.8 1.2 g 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 k (c) 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.4 0.8 1.2 g 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 k (d) 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.4 0.60.8 1 1.2 g 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 k (e) 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.4 0.60.8 1 1.2 g 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 k (f) 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.4 0.60.8 1 1.2 g 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 k (g)

Figure 2: first 6 iterations of our algorithm to approximate the distorted Sierpi´nski tetrahedron generated by the IFS (7) with the coefficients’ values provided by Table 3 starting from the full

tetrahedron with vertices 12,12,12, 3 2,12,12,  1,√3+12 ,12and 1,√3+1 2√3 , √ 3+2√2 2√3  .

5.2

A More General Example

In the second example we assume that parameters βi and γi are random, while parameter

fi, the amount of foreign capital, will be kept constant. Moreover, now we follow a different

approach as we first choose the values of the four random exogenous shocks configurations, that is, the values of parameters (ei, µi, βi, γi), and next evaluate the four (deterministic) fixed points

associated with each map wi in (7), for i = 1, . . . , 4; the latter will be the vertices of the

non-standard full tetrahedron that will be employed as initial geometric object for the iterations of operator (4) according to our Maple procedure. Specifically, we keep the same constant values s = a = u = δg = η = 12, b = d = 15, δk = 58, and vi ≡ v = 13 as in the first example, while

we now assume that fi is constant (deterministic) as well by setting fi ≡ f = 1. For the

random parameters representing the exogenous shocks realizations (ei, µi, βi, γi) we consider

(15)

0.8 1 1.2 p 0.5 1 g 0.5 1 1.5 k (a) 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.5 1 g 0.5 1 1.5 k (b) 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.5 1 g 0.5 1 1.5 k (c) 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.5 1 g 0.5 1 1.5 k (d) 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.5 1 g 0.5 1 1.5 k (e) 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.5 1 g 0.5 1 1.5 k (f) 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 p 0.5 1 g 0.5 1 1.5 k (g)

Figure 3: same construction as in Figure 2 but with a view of the same prefractals from a different perspective.

1. a ‘best possible world’ type scenario characterized by high productivity of foreign capital, ei, and no damage both on production, βi, and on the environment, γi and µi, represented

by the parameter values reported in the first row of Table 5;

2. an intermediate scenario characterized by average productivity of foreign capital, ei, high

damage on production, βi, and average damage on the environment, γiand µi, represented

by the parameter values reported in the second row of Table 5;

3. another intermediate scenario characterized by average productivity of foreign capital, ei, low damage on production, βi, and high damage on the environment, γi and µi,

represented by the parameter values reported in the third row of Table 5;

4. a catastrophic scenario characterized by low productivity of foreign capital, ei, together

with disruptive damage both on production, βi, and on the environment, γi and µi,

represented by the parameter values reported in the fourth row of Table 5. i ei βi γi µi 1 1 0 0 0 2 12 15 101 101 3 1 2 1 10 1 5 1 5 4 14 12 12 12

Table 5: values of the foreign capital’s productivity, ei, damage on production due to pollution, βi, impact of pollution on production, γi, and the environmental inefficiency associated with the use of

(16)

The parameters’ values listed in Table 5 lead to the values of the matrix coefficients and additive constants for the IFS (7) reported in Table 6.

i akki a gg i a pp i a kg i a kp i a gk i a gp i a pk i a pg i zik z g i z p i 1 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 10 0 1 10 0 0 0 1 3 2 3 0 2 21 12 12 101 −101 101 0 101 0 13 13 101 3 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 10 − 1 20 1 10 0 1 5 0 1 3 1 3 1 5 4 21 12 12 101 −14 101 0 12 0 13 16 12

Table 6: parameters’ values for the four maps wi characterizing the IFS (7) associated to the random shocks’ values reported in Table 5.

In this example the matrix of the affine maps wiin the IFS (7) is not constant but it depends

on each shock realization; that is, according to the values in Table 6, there are four different matrices: A1 =    1 2 1 10 0 1 10 1 2 0 0 0 1 2   , A2 =    1 2 1 10 − 1 10 1 10 1 2 0 1 10 0 1 2   , A3 =    1 2 1 10 − 1 20 1 10 1 2 0 1 5 0 1 2   , A4 =    1 2 1 10 − 1 4 1 10 1 2 0 1 2 0 1 2   .

However, Corollary 3 can still be applied to establish that, again without making any assump-tion on the probability vector (p1, p2, ..., p4) to be associated with the maps wi to get a full

IFSP, the invariant measure ¯µ generated by the IFSP (7) having parameter values as in Ta-ble 6 is singular, for any choice on the probabilities p1, p2, ..., p4. In fact, det (A1) = 0.12,

det (A2) = det (A3) = 0.125 and det (A4) = 0.1825, so that

|det (A1)|p 1 |det (A2)|p 2 |det (A3)|p 3 |det (A4)|p 4 = (0.12)p1 (0.125)p2 (0.125)p3 (0.1825)p4 <(0.1825)p1+p2+···+p4 = 0.1825 < e−4e ≃ 0.2296

and condition (6) holds also in this example.

Unlike the construction of the first example in which we have taken the vertices of the standard Sierpi´nski tetrahedron shifted inside the positive orthant as the fixed points of the four maps wi for the IFS and then calculated the maps’ parameter values which are consistent

with them, in this case we follow the opposite route and evaluate the fixed points of the four maps wi defined by the parameter values already set in Table 6. Specifically, for i = 1, . . . , 4

we solve the four systems    akk i − 1 k + a kg i g+ a kp i p+ zik= 0 agki k+ (aggi − 1) g + a gp i p+ z g i = 0 apki k+ apgi g+ (appi − 1) p + zip = 0

with respect to k, g and p for the parameter values in Table 6 to find the four fixed points (k∗

1, g1∗, p∗1) = (0.9722, 1.5278, 0), (k2∗, g2∗, p∗2) = (0.76, 0.8187, 0.352),

(k∗

3, g3∗, p∗3) = (0.76, 0.8187, 0.704) and (k4∗, g4∗, p∗4) = (0.1598, 0.3653, 1.1598).

Such four vector values are used to define the tetrahedron that will be taken as initial condi-tion in the same Maple recursive procedure already used in previous attractor approximacondi-tions. The resulting first 6 iterations of operator (4) generated by our Maple procedure in this case are shown in Figures 4 and 5, which report the same prefractals, only observed from different

(17)

perspectives. Clearly, as the nonzero mixed matrix coefficients akgi , a kp i , a gk i and a pk i now have

different values in different shock realizations, and in some scenarios are larger in magnitude than in the previous example, the dynamics generated by this IFS produce a more complex evolution pattern than that reported in Figures 2 and 3, as, after the tth iteration, the initial

tetrahedron, already exhibiting a sharp and streamlined shape itself, happens to be recursively sliced into 4t smaller and thinner copies resembling ever sharper blades, some of which are also

being rotated along different directions.

0 1 p 1 1.5 g 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 k (a) 0 1 p 1 1.5 g 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 k (b) 0 1 p 1 1.5 g 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 k (c) 0 1 p 1 1.5 g 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 k (d) 0 1 p 1 1.5 g 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 k (e) 0 1 p 1 1.5 g 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 k (f) 0 1 p 1 1.5 g 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 k (g)

Figure 4: first 6 iterations of our algorithm to approximate the attractor of the IFS (7) with the coefficients’ values provided by Table 6 starting from the full tetrahedron with vertices (0.9722, 1.5278, 0), (0.76, 0.8187, 0.352), (0.76, 0.8187, 0.704) and (0.1598, 0.3653, 1.1598).

Note that, unlike the IFS generating the standard Sierpi´nski tetrahedron in Figure 1, whose prefractals are all contained in the full initial tetrahedron having as its vertices the four fixed points of the maps wi, in Figures 2 – 5 the prefractals’ components wander all around the

vertices of the initial tetrahedron because of the rotations induced by the mixed coefficients akgi , akpi , a

gk

i and a

pk

i (either deterministic or stochastic). As a result, after each iteration

all prefractal’s components are being scattered around inside a set which is larger the initial tetrahedron; such a feature is clearly more evident in Figures 4 and 5.

6

Conclusion

Since polluting emissions in developing countries are expected to increase substantially in the future, in order to ensure a sustainable process of economic development at world level it is essential that industrialized economies support the green transition in developing countries. In order to shed some light on this issue, we analyze the implications of foreign capital on the economic development of a developing economy transiting from dirty to clean activities in a two-sector stochastic economic growth model with pollution externalities. Output is produced by combining dirty and clean inputs with the latter being completely emissions-free, while the clean input is produced by using the dirty input. Foreign capital (in the form of dirty input), inclusive of development aid and foreign direct investments, is partly allocated to the production of the clean input. Such a setting gives rise to a dynamic system represented by a three dimensional

(18)

0 0.5 1 p 0.5 1 1.5 g 0.6 k (a) 0 0.5 1 p 0.5 1 1.5 g 0.6 k (b) 0 0.5 1 1.5 p 0.5 1 1.5 g 0.6 k (c) 0 0.5 1 1.5 p 0.5 1 1.5 g 0.6 k (d) 0 0.5 1 1.5 p 0.5 1 1.5 g 0.4 0.6 0.8 k (e) 0 0.5 1 1.5 p 0.5 1 1.5 g 0.4 0.6 0.8 k (f) 0 0.5 1 1.5 p 0.5 1 1.5 g 0.4 0.6 0.8 k (g)

Figure 5: same construction as in Figure 4 but with a view of the same prefractals from a different perspective.

affine IFS. We show that the economy’s steady state is represented by an invariant measure supported on a compact set, characterizing its fractal nature and showing that (under a specific parametrization) its attractor may look like a distorted Sierpi´nski tetrahedron.

To the best of our knowledge, our paper is the first work investigating the possibility that the fractal attractor of stochastic economic growth models may be have a three dimensional representation. In order to do so we have kept the model as simple as possible but it would be interesting to extend it along different directions to capture some other aspects of the problem under investigation. The Sierpi´nski tetrahedron is the natural candidate to start the analysis of three dimensional fractal attractors but it may also be worthwhile to explore whether economic growth models may give rise to other more complicated, but well known, attractors, like the Sierpi´nski pyramid or the Menger sponge. The analysis has been carried out in a purely dynamic setting abstracting completely from agents’ optimization while it may also be interesting to assess whether and how optimal saving and investment decisions may change our conclusions. These further issues are left for future research.

Technical Appendix

Proof of Corollary 3. We just need to show that e−Ne is a lower bound for the term

pp1

1 p p2

2 · · · p pN

N for any choice of probabilities p1, ..., pN satisfying 0 < pi < 1, for i = 1, . . . , N ,

and such that PN

i=1pi = 1. To this purpose we consider the generalized open cube

(19)

and solve min(p1,...,pN)∈Φln (p p1 1 p p2 2 · · · p pN

N ), which is equivalent to min(p1,...,pN)∈Φ(p

p1 1 p p2 2 · · · p pN N ). Note that ln (pp1 1 p p2 2 · · · p pN

N ) = p1ln p1+p2ln p2+· · ·+pN ln pN is strictly convex as sum of strictly

convex functions of each variable pi; therefore (p∗1, . . . , p∗N) = arg min(p1,...,pN)∈Φln (p

p1 1 p p2 2 · · · p pN N )

is unique provided it exists. FOC on p1ln p1 + p2ln p2 + · · · + pN ln pN yields (p∗1, . . . , p∗N) =

(e−1, . . . , e−1), which is the unique (interior) solution of min

(p1,...,pN)∈Φln (p p1 1 p p2 2 · · · p pN N ) = min(p1,...,pN)∈Φ(p p1 1 p p2 2 · · · p pN

N ), to which corresponds the minimum value

(e−1)e−1

(e−1)e−1

· · · (e−1)e−1

= e−Ne. As PN

i=1e−1 = Ne 6= 1 for any N ∈ N, the open

sim-plex Ψ = ( (p2, ..., pN) : 0 < pi <1, i = 1, . . . , N, N X i=1 pi = 1 )

is a proper subset of the open cube Φ which does not contain the point (p∗

1, . . . , p∗N) = (e−1, . . . , e−1). Therefore, necessarily pp1 1 p p2 2 · · · p pN N > e− N e for any (p 2, ..., pN) ∈ Ψ and the proof is complete.

References

[1] Barnsley, M. (1993). Fractals Everywhere (2nd Ed.). San Diego, CA: Academic Press

[2] Barnsley, M., Demko, S. (1985). Iterated function systems and the global construction of fractals. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London Series A 399, 243–275

[3] Barnsley, M., Ervin, V., Hardin, D., Lancaster, J. (1986). Solution of an inverse problem for fractals and other sets, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA 83, 1975–1977

[4] Barnsley M., Hutchinson, J., Stenflo. O (2008). V –variable fractals: fractals with partial self similarity. Advances in Mathematics 218, 2051–2088

[5] Boldrin, M., Montrucchio, L. (1986). On the indeterminacy of capital accumulation paths. Journal of Economic Theory 40, 26–39

[6] Brock, W.A., Hommes, C.H. (1997). A rational route to randomness, Econometrica 65, 1059–1095

[7] Clarke, L., Edmonds, J., Krey, V., Richels, R., Rose, S., Tavoni, M. (2009). International climate policy architectures: overview of the EMF 22 International scenarios. Energy Eco-nomics 31, S64-S81

[8] Copeland, B.R., Taylor, M.S., (2008). North-South trade and the environment, Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, 755–787

[9] Diaconis, D., Freedman, P. (1999). Iterated Random Functions. SIAM Review 41: 45–76 [10] Hicks, R.L., Parks, B.C., Roberts, J.T., Tierney, M.J. (2008). Greening aid?:

understand-ing the environmental impact of development assistance, New York: Oxford University Press

[11] Hutchinson, J. (1981). Fractals and self-similarity, Indiana University Journal of Mathe-matics 30, 713–747

(20)

[12] International Energy Agency (2010). World energy outlook 2010, Paris: International En-ergy Agency

[13] Kunze, H., La Torre, D., Mendivil, F., Vrscay, E.R. (2012). Fractal-based Methods in Analysis, New York: Springer

[14] Kunze, H., La Torre, D., Vrscay, E.R. (2007). Contractive multifunctions, fixed point inclusions and iterated multifunction systems. Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Ap-plications 330: 159–173

[15] La Torre, D., Marsiglio, S., Privileggi, F. (2011). Fractals and Self-similarity in Economics: the Case of a Two-sector Growth Model, Image Analysis and Stereology 30: 143–151 [16] La Torre, D., Marsiglio, S., Mendivil, F., Privileggi, F. (2015). Self-similar measures in

multi-sector endogenous growth models, Chaos, Solitons and Fractals 79: 40–56

[17] La Torre, D., Marsiglio, S., Privileggi, F. (2018a). Fractal attractors in economic growth models with random pollution externalities, Chaos 28, 055916

[18] La Torre, D., Marsiglio, S., Mendivil, F., Privileggi F. (2018b). Fractal attractors and singular invariant measures in two-sector growth models with random factor shares, Com-munications in Nonlinear Science and Numerical Simulations 58, 185–201

[19] La Torre, D., Marsiglio, S., Mendivil, F., Privileggi, F. (2019). A stochastic economic growth model with health capital and state-dependent probabilities, Chaos, Solitons and Fractals 129, 81–93

[20] La Torre, D., Mendivil, F., Vrscay, E.R. (2006). IFS on multifunctions, in Aletti, G., Burger, M., Micheletti, A., Morale, D., Eds., Math everywhere: deterministic and stochas-tic modelling in biomedicine, economics and industry. Berlin Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag, 125–134

[21] La Torre, D., Vrscay, E.R. (2009). A generalized fractal transform for measure-valued images. Nonlinear Analysis 71: e1598–e1607

[22] La Torre, D., Vrscay, E.R., Ebrahimi, M., Barnsley, M. (2009). Measure-valued images, associated fractal transforms, and the affine self-similarity of images. SIAM Journal on Imaging Science 2: 470–507

[23] Mani, M., Wheeler, D. (1998). In search of pollution havens? Dirty industry in the world economy, 1960–1995, Journal of Environment and Development 7, 215–247

[24] Marsiglio, S. (2012). Stochastic shocks in a two-sector Solow model, International Journal of Mathematical Modelling and Numerical Optimisation 3, 313–318

[25] Mendivil, F., Vrscay, E.R. (2002a). Fractal vector measures and vector calculus on planar fractal domains. Chaos Solitons Fractals 14: 1239–1254

[26] Mendivil, F., Vrscay, E.R. (2002b). Self-affine vector measures and vector calculus on fractals, in Barnsley, M., Saupe, D., Vrscay, E.R., Eds., Fractals in multimedia. Proceedings of the Meeting on Fractals in Multimedia. IMA Vol Math Appl 132. New York: Springer-Verlag, 137–155

(21)

[27] Mitra, T., Montrucchio, L., Privileggi, F. (2003). The Nature of the Steady State in Models of Optimal Growth under Uncertainty, Economic Theory 23, 39–71

[28] Mitra, T., Privileggi, F. (2004). Cantor type invariant distributions in the theory of optimal growth under uncertainty, Journal of Difference Equations and Applications 10, 489–500 [29] Mitra, T., Privileggi, F. (2006). Cantor type attractors in stochastic growth models, Chaos,

Solitons and Fractals 29, 626–637

[30] Mitra, T., Privileggi, F. (2009). On Lipschitz continuity of the iterated function system in a stochastic optimal growth model, Journal of Mathematical Economics 45, 185–198 [31] Montrucchio, L. (1994). Dynamic complexity of optimal paths and discount factors for

strongly concave problems, Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications 80, 385–406 [32] Montrucchio, L., Privileggi, F. (1999). Fractal steady states in stochastic optimal control

models, Annals of Operations Research 88, 183–197

[33] Ngai, S.M., Wang, Y. (2005). Self-similar measures associated to IFS with non-uniform contraction ratios. The Asian Journal of Mathematics 9: 227–244

[34] Nishimura, K., Yano, M. (1995). Nonlinear dynamics and chaos in optimal growth: an example, Econometrica 63, 981–1001

[35] Niu, M., Xi, L.F. (2007). Singularity of a Class of Self-similar Measures. Chaos, Solitons Fractals 34: 376–382

[36] Privileggi, F., Marsiglio, S. (2013). Environmental shocks and sustainability in a basic economy-environment model, International Journal of Applied Nonlinear Science 1, 67–75 [37] Vrscay, E.R. (1991). Moment and collage methods for the inverse problem of fractal con-struction with iterated function systems, in Peitgen, H.O., Henriques, J.M., Penedo, L.F., Eds., Fractals in the fundamental and applied sciences, 443–461, North-Holland: Amster-dam

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

While maintaining its good properties (see Table I), we extend [18] in the following ways: (i) the assumption of perfect communication (necessary for safety in [18]) is removed;

La carta del patrimonio relativa a questo contesto mostra infatti una vasta intersezione di componenti di valore inerenti le diverse strutture territoriali (qui definite

The computed feature maps are subsequently processed by a three-branch multi-stage CNN where each branch focuses on a different aspect of body pose estimation: the first branch

1 Yoshida Kenko filosofo giapponese del quattordicesimo secolo. 2 Lesson from Bernard Rudofsky, Life as a voyage, Architekturzentrum Wien, The Getty Research Institute, Los

To address this goal, we examined the factor structure of the Italian version of the ERI-SQ, assessed internal consistency for the dimensions of effort, reward, and over-commitment,

Topographic changes in macular ganglion cell-inner plexiform layer thickness after vitrectomy with indocyanine green-guided internal limiting membrane peeling for idiopathic

Anche le polemiche nei confronti del re tra la fine del 1864 e l’inizio del 1865 per il trasferimento della capitale da Torino a Firenze; il veloce e non organizzato ingresso a Roma

Test platform consists of a commodity PC equipped with a dual-head Intel(R) Xeon CPU E5-2630 at 2.4 GHz with 256 GB of RAM, running CentOS Linux release 7.2 and Intel compiler