• Non ci sono risultati.

The Americas

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "The Americas"

Copied!
81
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

The Americas

# 13

24 October 2016

(2)

The two Americas:

the divergent trajectories

North and South Americas followed two different trajectories

replicating divergence tendencies emerging within the world economy as a whole

Continental divergence dating back to the colonial epoch and originated from geography and

demography

North America had a geographical advantage being closer to Europe as the main market for colonial goods (+ “connecting” rivers)

(3)

Two demographies

Pre-Colombian populations fell dramatically, natives collapsed for arms and disease

North America, a temperate climate: not densely populated (in 1500 0,25m in the original 13 colonies)

the asymmetrical mortality rate between natives and settlers allowed of the “transplant” of

England

South America, more densely populated (1500: 57m;

1750: 5m, but the drop was even larger)

The ethnic structure and deep social (and income) polarisation was a brake to growth

(4)

The colonial economy of North America

The settlement of North America (New England + Canada) derived from exporting

The staples thesis [Innis, 1930]: the growth of British colonies was determined by the

growth of their exports to Europe

Staples were: wheat, timber and wood products (ships), whale oil, fish, furs

Colonies exported staples to Europe and imported manufactures whose

competitiveness depended by the production scale

(5)

The staple economy

Staple colonies had three characteristics:

Staples had lower prices and were

correlated to Europe’s as they were linked by trade (+ Navigation’s Acts) Exports amounted to a large share of

colonial aggregate income (+ services) The returns exceeded returns in Europe by

a margin covering costs and risks of

moving to colony: labour + capital

(6)

Pennsylvania (1681) illustrates these principles

The wheat prices in Philadelphia and London were

synchronised (with two exceptions confirming the rule) Exports amounted to 30% ca of colony’s aggregate output (1770)

So the colony could pay for British

consumer goods

(7)

The differences

within the colonies

The growth of the British colonies in the 18

th

century attracted immigrants from Europe (UK)

The dynamics of real wages was similar to London’s, but to a higher level to balance costs and risks

Yet, in the colonies without staples, or

where staples prices were on a par with London, real wages were quite similar to London’s

(8)

Real wages in Europe and New England,

1700-1855

(9)

The sugar colonies

The sugar colonies in the Caribbean (sugar & coffee) had different dynamics

sugar cultivation in large plantations staffed by

African slaves (N) grew as well as exports proving hugely profitable (K by European investors)

a very high mortality rate made suitable to replenish slaves by purchasing new slaves more than by natural increase (BWI: 4m vs 0,4m in 1832)

profits were invested in the UK not in the Caribbean The model was replicated in the Southern US (rice +

tobacco + cotton) (SC, MD, VA)

(10)

One size does not fit all

British colonies actually evolved along three different models in terms of social structure, income and inequality (+ rights)

New England: high real wages, abundant &

cheap land, an equal society, a few slaves Caribbean (Jamaica): large plantations, a few

settlers, the most of the population was slaves, extreme inequality

Southern US: in the middle, inequality in large plantations and egalitarianism of small-scale farmers

(11)

Colonial economy of Latin America

Latin America follows three trajectories, all of them different from the USA’s

Caribbean and Brazil

Cono Sur (Argentina, Chile and Paraguay) Mexico and Andes

Spanish colonies

combines enslavement forms (low cost) with productions

unrelated to the European markets for

high transportation costs

(12)

The three models

The Brazilian economy was a sort of Caribbean economy on an expanded size

The Portuguese introduced sugar and

substituted native slaves with African slaves But Brazilian crops producers were undercut

by Dutch who transplanted the “sugar

model” into the Caribbean, closer to Europe Brazil experienced a staple boom after another (gold in the early 18th c; coffee in 1840-1930,

rubber in 1879-1912)

(13)

Cono Sur, Mexico and Andes

Cono Sur means Pampas: wheat and meat

Thus, Cono Sur economies were similar to New England but with higher transportation costs (at least, until 1860 ca)

Mexico and Andes differed as the Spanish conquistadores encountered complex

civilisations, in not a sparsely populated area like New England

Polities and societies, cities and agriculture, hierarchies and religions (Incas, Aztecs)

(14)

The silver vs staples

The Spanish colonies exported silver (Potosi in Bolivia), not staples, with negative long-term effects

silver provoked inflation but no specialisation (they just swapped silver for Chinese silk

and tea shipped with galleons from Acapulco and Manila)

no significant exports nor employment (a mere 4% of GDP)

an uneven income distribution (only a few rich) did not attract labour and capital from Europe

as competing New England did

(15)

Wages of unskilled labourers in London and Mexico, 1525-1900

Mexico was a low wages economy as agriculture was largely inefficient, nor its products could be efficiently exported to Europe for an

unlucky geography (the plateau and no rivers to Vera Cruz)

Inverse correlation

between wages and population for demand expanded much faster (integration of crops and animals)

(16)

Independence: USA

The American economy grew significantly after independence (1776-1787)

population by 8, income per capita by 2 prior 1860

raw cotton production in the Southern States and wheat and meat in the Mid-West

But it was not just a staple economy

Hamilton doctrine (1792) for the “American model”

It became the standard model for the entire 19th century

(17)

The standard model

The Hamilton’s doctrine introduced the four-point standard model

universal education (egalitarian societies)

improvements in transport infrastructures

a national bank to stabilise the currency and promote investments and trade

external tariffs to foster a unified

national market

(18)

An import-substitution model

The standard model aims to substitute British imports (duties on imports 20-25%)

The abolition of state tariffs and new infrastructures created a national market

Cumberland Road (1811-1818), Erie Canal (1817- 1825)

A characteristically American protectionism emerged Tariff of 1816; Morrill Tariff, 1861; Smoot-Hawley,

1929

An experiment in bank of issue

Bank of the United States (1791 and 1816)

(19)

The industrialisation of the USA

From 1800 to 1860 the cotton industry took off in the USA

After 1825 American real wages continued to grow while the British ones stagnated

The immigration from Europe should have aligned the American wages to Europe’s (and UK’s)

But it did not happen as the American wages were linked to specific technological

trajectories

That’s why it was not a staple growth

(20)

The end of the Atlantic labour market

(21)

High wages, technology and productivity

The Habakkuk hypothesis [1962] is based on the relationship between labour

(population size) and resources (cheap land and the frontier)

The technological dynamics is a function of high wages

So that the USA pioneered high-

productivity and capital intensive

technology to save expensive labour

(22)

Independence in Latin America

The colonial societies dilemma:

protectionism or international trade but at a cost (de-industrialisation)?

Since the early 19

th

century Mexico adopted a spurious standard model

“external” protectionism, but no national market integration, and a national bank no infrastructures to cut transport costs,

nor mass education to improve human capital

(23)

Industry without innovation

Growth phases during Alamàn and Porfirio Diaz (1877-1911) were depending on

machinery and technology transfer (typically, railways)

Yet, such policies did not ignite an

endogenous process of technological innovation

so that growth was only in the State- backed sectors

and real wages stagnated as a result!

(24)

Africa

and the Great Divergence

# 14

26 October 2016

(25)

Was Africa poor?

Sub-Saharan Africa poverty is a long-run matter, as Africa was poor even before European colonialism (prior to 1500), at least as far as estimates suggest:

a low and stagnant GDP per capita

GDP per capita (Geary-Khamis 1990$)

1500 1600 1700 1820

Core Western Europe (12)

798 908 1033 1245

Western Europe (27)

771 890 998 1204

Asia + Middle East

568 572 608 581

Africa 414 422 421 420

(26)

Why is Africa poor?

The colonial ideologies:

Africans are bound by traditions more than to commercial values

The institutional approach:

The slave trade (but also areas not involved are amongst the poorest)

Colonialism as extraction of wealth without development strategies

Too much globalisation (a dependency from exporting commodities and primary products)

Inefficient governments (authoritarianism, corruption)

(27)

Africa

and the Great Divergence?

Sub-Saharan African poverty is related to a specific agricultural regime before 1500

hence, the highest income per capita in

North Africa (from Morocco to Egypt) and the Middle East

and the absence of advanced agrarian civilisations,

like in South East Asia, Northern Eurasia, Polynesia and North America, with a few exceptions (Ethiopian Plateau)

(28)

The importance of agriculture

Advanced agrarian civilisations had many advantages:

productive agriculture + diversified

manufacturing (labour specialisation) institutional and cultural resources (from

property rights to complex expressions of a written culture → literacy and numeracy)

specialisation between private property of land and landless labourers

long-lasting effects on the ability to generate technological progress

(29)

The African agriculture

Prior to 1500 African agriculture had some

momentous innovations (so, no “unchanging traditions”):

Ethiopia (2500-1500 BC): a sophisticated agrarian civilisation (crops + husbandry) including

investments in terracing and irrigation

Nigeria (1500-onwards): introduction of yams and palm oil fitting to the rainforest environment

West Africa: introduction of new crops such as yams, bananas and beans (1st-8th cent. CE) + maize, manioc, tobacco from America (16th

cent.)

(30)

Diverging demographies

Wherever agriculture domesticated crops and allowed of permanent villages

population grew and a complex society took place with a written culture and

sophisticated institutions (polities)

e.g., Ethiopia (Kingdoms of D’mt and Aksum)

In West Africa the population growth was

restrained because of tropical diseases

malaria + sleeping sickness (↑ CMR)

(31)

The shifting cultivation

In a land-abundant area shifting cultivation represented a rational response to

specific circumstances

e.g., the Yakö group from the Eastern

Nigeria rainforest farming region, 1930s

But with permanent effects

no specialisation between land owners and labourers, no land to buy or lend (and no property rights)

a low population density as a result

(32)

and the resulting politics

This production system generated two different styles of politics

a relatively egalitarian political system based on “confederation” of the

cultivators (“band” or “tribe”)

vs the West African Empires (states),

like Ghana, Mali and Songhai, vastly

centred upon revenues from trans-

Saharan trade, gold production and

slavery

(33)

The slave trade

From the 16

th

century the slave trade greatly modified African societies, although slavery and slave trade preceded the Europeans (as well as West Africa exported gold to Europe and the Arab world)

Kingdoms of Dahomey, Ashanti and Kongo responded to the increased demand for

cheap labour coming from the Americas (the sugar economy) by slave-raiding

1500-1850: 10-12 million slaves were traded to the New World (and even more to Asia)

(34)

The “legitimate commerce”

The end of the slave trade within the British Empire (1807) called for the substitution of exports from Africa,

such as palm oil in demand as a lubricant and for candles and soaps

The new legitimate commerce used the old commercial networks in West Africa

The wild stands production depended on

how much Africans could buy with a

given extra work (oil/manufactures)

(35)

Prices of palm oil and cocoa

relative to the price of cotton cloth, 1817-2000

Likewise, cocoa prices oscillated, plummeting

conspicuously between 1920 and 1950, quite remarkably in the 20th century >

< palm oil prices relative to prices of cotton cloth

in relative terms the incentive to produce palm oil grew in the 19th century and diminished throughout the 20th century

35

(36)

Colonialism in Africa

The European colonialism in Africa

developed during the 19

th

century in order

to have access to raw materials and

commodities as well as Africa being a market for their manufactures

as Africa was a territory for European settlers and offered profitable investments

opportunities

But it created particularly inefficient

institutions by introducing “indirect rule”

(37)

Colonialism

as a brake to growth

European colonialism was remarkably

detrimental to African growth by pursuing inefficient policies

infrastructures to facilitate exporting of primary goods (e.g., railways)

tariffs were tuned low for revenue purpose globalised Africa at worst by specialising its

regions in low value added primary goods low investments in human capital

land and (forced) labour policies not favourable to native interests

(38)

Why are Africans poor?

Today Africans have a WWI living standard as the continent’s agriculture has low

levels of productivity

as technological progress keeps low the price of its products with substitute

products (mineral oil vs palm oil)

because of the Asian competition and the extension of cultivation in Africa as well

But above all as productivity has been

stagnating or even falling

productivity trap + cheap labour

(39)

The standard model

and late industrialisation

# 15

27 October 2016

(40)

Does one size fit all?

By 1850 Western Europe and the USA were ahead of the rest of the world

Colonies

could not opt for development

strategies as they had “external” constraints as colonies

The “Resteners” could rely on the standard

model, but it proved less and less effective as

time went by (e.g., peripheral Europe)

as the “technology gap” deepened (was it also a capital gap?)

(41)

Why didn’t the standard model work any more?

Two new constraints arose with second industrial revolution sectors and

technologies

the minimum efficient scale of production increased (capital to labour ratio – K/N) the market size (how large is the domestic

market?)

Such constraints may explain why the

standard model did not work any more in

late industrialisation cases

(42)

Three cases: Russia, Japan and Latin America

Although Russia, Japan and most of Latin America adopted development strategies (late 19

th

century to mid-20

th

century) catch- up efforts did not always result in a full-

fledged industrialisation process

Russia: “half-baked” by merely importing technologies, without any adaptation Japan: first in Asia, succeeded in

industrialisation by hybridising former models Latin America: an inefficient equilibrium

(43)

Imperial Russia

Russia was for a long time a backward part (a frontier?) of Europe, despite modernisation attempts (Peter the Great, 1672-1725)

After the Crimean War (1853-1856) Alexander II launched a string of modernising reforms, such as abolishing serfdom

but there was no adequate response to this attempt to create a proper labour market and a market for private property

(44)

A modified standard model

The Tsarist governments (Witte and Stolypin) adopted a modified standard model:

promoting the railway construction (71,000 km by 1913) to link Russia to the global economy

building up a “national” industry through tariffs (1891) both for heavy sectors (iron and steel sectors, engineering industry) and light sectors (textiles, cotton)

fostering investments by luring FDIs more than reforming the financial system → a major pitfall:

foreign capital built up plants regardless of the specific context

(45)

Witte’s successes, 1890-1916: FDIs and industrial production

FDIs, in million of roubles

1880 98

1890 215

1895 911

1914 2000

in millions of tonnes

coal pig iron oil

1880 3.2 0.42 0.5

1890 5.9 0.89 3.9

1900 16.1 2.66 10.2

1910 26.8 2.99 9.4

1913 35.4 4.12 9.1

1916 33.8 3.72 9.7

(46)

Trans-Siberian Railway

(47)

Why didn’t this model work?

The standard model did not work as

technologies were imported but not adapted to specific circumstances

Mass education was too slow in spite of the higher earnings for literate workers

Thus, heavy industry progressed but Russian economy remained based on agriculture

(1885:1913: slightly slipped from 59% to 51% of GDP)

Tsarist economic growth was an agricultural boom depending on international prices

(48)

Japan: the first Asian country to industrialise

Japan has been the first Asian country to catch up with the West

The Japanese history may be divided in four periods:

Tokugawa (1603-1868); Meiji (1868-1905); Imperial (1905-1940); the Era of high speed growth and catch up (1950-1990)

Tokugawa period had mixed dynamics:

political fragmentation (shoguns) and property

insecurity, restricted international trade (Nagasaki) technology was compatible with endowment (labour)

(49)

The deep roots of growth

Even though prosperity was uneven distributed, both income and population grew, as well as technological innovations introduced (but they were labour-intensive as labour was cheap) Productivity was improved in manufacturing and

agriculture (irrigation – new crops)

Technological improvements were based on

reverse-engineering or manufacturing copies (e.g., cannon foundry)

Literacy spread and large cities grew (Edo, Osaka, Kyoto)

(50)

The Meiji Restoration

The Meiji Restoration represented a reaction to military and economic weakness (1868) Technocrats modernised Japan so as to

have a “rich country” and a “strong army”

the four-order society was abolished, a

constitutional monarchy established, samurai were substituted by a Prussian-style army

property rights and land taxes were introduced railways were constructed (and Western 24-hour

time!) and mass education adopted

(51)

The Meiji economic development

Japanese governments could adopt only two measures of the four ones of the standard model

Japan encountered difficulties in modernising her financial system so the State initially

acted as a sort of “venture capitalist”

as international treaties prevented Japan to adopt external tariffs industrial targeted policies were applied by MITI

and State-owned firms privatised in the 1880s

(52)

Hybridising Western technologies

Western technologies needed to be

amended to specific circumstances (cheap labour and expensive capital)

a low labour cost and dependency on

Western technologies imposed a creative, adaptive response to make them cost-

effective in a low-wage economy

less capital and more labour through a re- engineering of Western technologies

e.g., silk and cotton industries

(53)

The Imperial period

Economic growth was relatively slow in the Meiji period as Japan exported traditional products (tea, silk, cotton) to pay for imported

machinery and raw materials

Industrial output accelerated between 1905 and 1940 (20 to 35% of GDP) as Japan could

implement the standard model entirely protectionism

universal banks

universal education + studying abroad heavy sectors

(54)

Mitsubishi Zero Fighter

Mitsubishi Zero Fighter (1940) was a typical

technological effort along the Japanese trajectory:

500 km/h, 4,000 m were not achieved by

increasing the power of its engine but reducing its weight

(55)

Targeted industrial policies

State intervened to transfer and adapt

technologies to reduce the gap in strategic sectors (heavy + automotive industries

subsidised steel sector: Yawata Steel Works (1905)

During WWI imports were substituted by a mix of private and State intervention

zaibatsu (conglomerate groups) to increase saving and investment rates

R&D departments + inventory techniques to save capital, such as “just in time” in the 1930s

(56)

Latin America

Many South American countries were too

small to industrialise, others experimented the standard model in the late 19

th

century (until the 1980s)

Yet the import-substitution industrialisation [Prebish, 1950] proved to be ineffective as protectionism and subsidies were

misdirected with no regards to plants’

efficiency and the market size

(57)

The car industry case

The car industry case may be a case in point

Argentina and Brazil promoted car making in the 1950s-1960s also by strong

protectionism variants

Argentina law (1959) restricted imports allowing to produce cars by 13 firms

In 1965 the largest plant could produce 57,000 cars per year (the overall car production

amounted to 195,000 per year)

but the MES was 200,000 cars per year

(58)

Ousted from Detroit,

established in Argentina

Kaiser-Frazer Corp was an

American car maker ousted from Detroit by more efficient

competitors (GM, Ford Motor Co., Chrysler) established in

Argentina as protectionism and alliances (with Industrias

Aeronauticas y Mecanicas de Estado) allowed to breath… but beneath efficiency cost levels

(59)

A growing gap

Smaller firms (plants) had to deal with higher costs and their inefficiency

burdened the overall productivity as their relative weight was relatively high:

10%/GDP

As a result real wages stagnated thus

affecting the actual size of the domestic market (aggregate demand)

Thus, it was not a K/N problem but a MES

issue!

(60)

A most courteous reminder…

Please, remember that you have to register yourselves online for the mid-term exam!

(segreteria online at

https://segreteriaonline.unisi.it/Home.do)

References: slides + Acemoglu, Laibson & List (chaps. 6, 7 and 8) + Allen (chaps. 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7 and 8)

(61)

The Big Push

industrialisation

# 16

2 November 2016

(62)

The Big Push

Late joiners in the 20th century had to reduce a wider gap than previously, starting from a

lower income per head level in a shorter time Large economies has been able to grow fast by

constructing all the elements of an advanced economy simultaneously: this is the big push:

everything is built ahead of supply and demand:

steel mills before car plants, car plants before rolled sheets, both of them before occurring the actual demand for them

(63)

The Big Push, the income gap and scale economies

The Big Push strategy is an alternative strategy to the import-substitution strategy, as the MES

affects industrialisation strategies after 1910 The Westerners widened the gap but some

countries were able to reduce it

The higher starting differential in income and

productivity is to be compensated by a higher growth rates (approx. 6%) to catch up

The Big Push anticipates investments by a

planning authority to coordinate them before both supply and demand materialise

(64)

Number of years to develop from low- to middle- income economy [Prescott & Parente, 2001]:

Thus, growing means growing faster

country starting year number of years

UK 1835 54

The Netherlands 1855 64

Belgium 1856 55

USA 1856 44

Italy 1870 54

Russia/USSR 1870 66

France 1872 54

Germany 1872 55

Japan 1894 38

Mexico 1950 22

Iran 1955 17

Brazil 1957 17

Hong Kong & Singapore 1960 10

Taiwan 1965 10

(65)

Breaking out of poverty

in the 20

th

century means planning

Three national cases suggest that growing in the 20

th

century require a certain amount of planning, although planning apparatus vary Only a few countries have been able to catch

up with the West after 1950, except for small city states (Hong Kong, Singapore)

USSR: a successful but too rigid a model Japan: heading towards the technology

frontier

China: the next candidate?

(66)

USSR

A successful case but at a cost, at least until 1980

The Soviet solution to backwardness was central planning to build up a modern economy by transferring state-of-the-art technology in capital-intensive sectors

The Five Year Plan (1928): state-owned

enterprises receiving instructions from the top, not from the market

The target: capital equipment production, instead of consumer goods

(67)

Maximizing the output

The growth strategy had four legs:

channelling investment into heavy sectors and machinery production (↑ investment rate)

output targets to direct business operations without financial restrictions (“soft budget constraints”)

agriculture collectivisation (famine in 1933) mass education (universal and compulsory

schooling)

(68)

Soviet + electrification

The Soviet planning economy fostered the investment rate:

9%/GDP in 1928 to 19%/GDP in 1938

The industrial output tilted rapidly and significantly The creation of large scale in the steel sector and

power industry furthered productivity growth rates and, generally, living standards

education and public health improved

despite mortality rate increases related to

collectivisation and famine episodes (+ WWII: a huge blow to USSR economy and population)

(69)

Comparing USSR national accounts, 1927-1987

(70)

Too rigid a model

Although capital stock was restored by 1950 development strategies proved effective only, or especially, in capital- and

technology-intensive sectors

also because it was a surplus labour economy

The increase in income per capita was partly a result of a decrease in CBR

The model was too rigid to be effective once USSR reached the technology frontier

(71)

Japan as a “rich country”

After WWII Japan renounced to get a “strong army” and concentrated on economic

growth

GDP per capita: 1950-1990: ↑ 5.9% per year (a peak: 1953-1973: ↑ 8% per year

The growth strategy focused on reversing its adjusting policy:

instead adjusting modern technology to its

factor prices, Japan adopted the most

modern and capital-intensive technology

(72)

Reversing the Meiji model

Investment in capital stock (30%/y) succeeded in adjusting factor prices to the most

advanced technology, shifting to the frontier The Japanese strategy consisted in investing

in scale efficient plants – a green field choice

Thus, Japan rapidly fostered productivity in second industrial revolution technologies (+ just in time) through the MITI coordination in the 1960s

In car and steel industries and shipbuilding outcompeted the USA by 1970

(73)

Investment and economic growth in

Japan after WWII

(74)

The Japanese big push

The big push strategy required to overcome some constraints:

MITI opted for efficient scale plants through

green field sites (different from Latin America) but who would consume low-cost steel? A scale

efficient car industry (Honda, Toyota)

and who would consume cars? Increasing

income at home thanks to adequate industrial

relations + international markets (exports)

(75)

The end of big push in Japan?

The high growth period in Japan ended in

1991 when the real estate bubble collapsed Could Japan grow faster during the “lost

decade”?

Hard to assess, unlikely, perhaps no…

Once caught up with the leader, as Japan did, growth rates depend on variations of the

technology frontier, slower by definition

(76)

China’s miracle

South Korea and Taiwan followed the

Japanese big push model with a time lag

They substituted Japan in some sectors with a two-decade delay

Successful cases of Asian Tigers have been dwarfed by the Chinese miracle in recent decades

How did China do it? Just free-market

reforms?

(77)

Economic growth in East Asia after 1960

(and China after 1980)

(78)

A two-period story

Mao’s Soviet-style planning (1949-1978)

a planning policy pursued along Soviet lines but income per capita increased slowly

(2.9% per year on average)

A market reform (1978), not a shock therapy

producing over targets was stimulated by

state procurement agencies

collective cultivation was replaced by the Household Responsibility System – small farms leased to families

(79)

China’s performance, 1952-2007

(80)

A gradual strategy

China’s success depends on market reforms (animal spirits) but also on previous policies

agriculture productivity growth deriving from new technologies (water supply, fertilisers, IR-8 rise)

adapting technology to the specific factor endowment (prices)

large-scale plants in capital-intensive sectors mass education and investment in R&D

lowering CBR and CMR

(81)

…adapting big spurt strategies

China has been adapting big spurt

strategies by adopting both institutional innovations

special economic zones (SEZ) in South East

and macroeconomic policies

exchange rate and reserve policies

relatively soft budget constraints (banks vis- à-vis firms)

surplus labour economy (Northern regions)

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

Denominazioni della Val di Vara : brigo, canüa, carrùdena, canuo, canuda, canuto, canùu, cocheto, cogianco, erba da puia, erba dell’Ascensione, erbu gianco/u, ochetta, ochettu,

Le ristrutturazioni interessano anche l’area presbiteriale dove all’interno del recinto di accesso colonnato, che in questa fase non risulta più in uso con la stessa forma

Book advertisements; Book trade; book market; history of the book; 16th-century books; printed booksellers’ catalogues; early modern book

Un con- vegno come quello odierno non poteva infatti trovare una migliore col- locazione, sia perché la città è ormai matura per implementare gli even- ti legati alla cultura

Anche su questo aspetto la tecnologia ha contribuito a rendere più autonomo il cieco: all’interno di strutture, infatti, molto spesso, oltre alle visite guidate

This work proposes a new method to compute tortuosity, a key parameter for drug diffusion in fibrous tissue, starting from a model which incorporates the main

Commission; the Ministry of Science and Higher Education and the National Science Centre, Poland; the Fundação para a Ciência e a Tecnologia, Portugal; JINR, Dubna; the Ministry

Il primo blocco è quello dei conti de numerato, le cui partite derivano da un movimento di denaro o da un giro conto e sono liquidabili a vista nello stesso modo; qui compaiono i conti