• Non ci sono risultati.

production using revealed preferences andhousehold Is the environment a luxury? An empiricalinvestigation Resource and Energy Economics

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "production using revealed preferences andhousehold Is the environment a luxury? An empiricalinvestigation Resource and Energy Economics"

Copied!
21
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

ContentslistsavailableatScienceDirect

Resource and Energy Economics

jo u r n a l h o m e p a g e :w w w . e l s e v i e r . c o m / l o c a t e / r e e

Is the environment a luxury? An empirical investigation using revealed preferences and household production

Chiara Martini

a,,1

, Silvia Tiezzi

b,1

aDepartmentofEconomics,UniversityofRomeRomaTre,viaSilvioD’Amico77,00145Roma,Italy

bDepartmentofEconomicsandStatistics,UniversityofSiena,PiazzaSanFrancesco7,53100Siena,Italy

a r t i c l e i n f o

Articlehistory:

Received3September2012

Receivedinrevisedform8November2013 Accepted25November2013

Availableonline4December2013

JELclassification:

H22 H23 D63

Keywords:

Incomeelasticityofwillingnesstopay Householdproduction

Mixeddemandsystems Integrability

a b s t ra c t

Thispapercombinesdemandanalysiswithhouseholdproduction toestimatethemarginalwillingnesstopayforimprovementsinair qualityinItalyandthecorrespondingincomeelasticityofwilling- nesstopay.WeusechoicebaseddataonItalianhouseholds’current consumptionexpendituresfromJanuary1999toDecember2006 mergedwithanairqualityindex.Weconsistentlyfindthatthe incomeelasticityofwillingnesstopayforenvironmentalquality isveryclosetooneacrossincomegroups.Besidescontributingto astrandofliteraturewherethereisscantempiricalevidence,we providethefirstattemptatimplementingthetheoreticalapproach suggestedbyEbert(2007),whichderiveswillingnesstopayandits incomeelasticityusingrevealedpreferencescombinedwithhouse- holdproduction.

©2013ElsevierB.V.Allrightsreserved.

1. Introduction

Theobjectiveofthispaperistoestimatethewillingnesstopay(WTP)andtheincomeelasticity ofWTPforimprovementsinairqualityinItalyusinganewmethodologicalapproach,proposedby Ebert(2007),andanewdataset.

∗ Correspondingauthor.Tel.:+393337611200.

E-mailaddresses:cmartini@uniroma3.it,martinichi@gmail.com(C.Martini),silvia.tiezzi@unisi.it(S.Tiezzi).

1 Authorsorderisalphabetical.

0928-7655/$seefrontmatter©2013ElsevierB.V.Allrightsreserved.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2013.11.014

(2)

Themethodologyappliedinthispaper(Ebert,2007)isbasedonthefollowingassumptions:(i)a complete(conditional)demandsystemformarketgoods,whichmaydependonenvironmentalgoods, canbeobserved;(ii)ahouseholdproductionfunction,combiningmarketandenvironmentalgoods accordingtoagiventechnology,isknown;(iii)theenvironmentalgoodsconsidereddonotenterthe utilityfunctiondirectly.Usingtheseassumptions,Ebertshowsthatonecanderivethemarginalwill- ingnesstopayfunctionsforthenonmarketgoodswhichaugmenttheconditionaldemandsystem.

Thenonehastoinvestigatetheintegrabilityofthemixeddemandsystemconsistingofthedemand functionsformarketgoodsandtheinversedemandfunctionsforthenonmarketgoods.Iftheintegra- bilityconditionsaresatisfied,auniquepreferenceorderingcanberecoveredwiththepossibilityof performingwelfareanalysisandofestimatingimportantderivedparameters,liketheincomeelasticity ofwillingnesstopay.

Toimplementthisapproachweconsiderhouseholdproductionoftheinternallevelofairquality chosenbythehouseholdsandassumethattheycombineamarketgood,airconditioning,withanon marketgood,thelevelofexternalairquality,accordingtoagiventechnologytoproducethedesired levelofinternalairquality.Sincethehouseholdproductionfunctionimplicitlydescribesthemarginal rateofsubstitutionbetweenairqualityandairconditioning,wecancomputethemarginalwillingness topayformarginalimprovementsinairquality.Wethusestimateacompleteconditionaldemand systemformarketgoodsaugmentedbytheWTPfunctionforimprovementsinairquality.Thedata setweuseisobtainedbymergingdataonItalianhouseholdsmonthlycurrentexpenditureandunique informationonabundleofairpollutantsconcentrations.Weshowthattheresulting(mixed)demand systemisintegrableandwecomputethemarginalwillingnesstopayforamarginalincreaseinthe indexofairqualityandthecorrespondingincomeelasticityofWTP.Besidescontributingtoastrandof literaturewherethereissurprisinglylittleempiricalevidence,thisisthefirstattemptatimplementing theapproachdevelopedbyEbert(2007),usingdemandanalysiscombinedwithhouseholdproduction toestimateWTPforanonmarketgood.

WefindanincomeelasticityofWTPnotsignificantlydifferentfromoneacrossincomegroups.Our findingshaverelevantpolicyimplications.Growthinincomeandinenvironmentalqualitycouldbe decoupledashigherincomegroupswouldnotshowstrongerpreferencesforenvironmentalquality thanlowerincomegroupsdo.TheincomeelasticityofWTPisalsolikelytoinfluencecost-benefit analyses,becauseignoringtherealincidenceofsocialprojectsmayproducedecisionsthatare“biased”

againstthepoor.1Moreover,theincomeelasticityofWTPforenvironmentalbenefitsisimportantfor shapingefficientenvironmentalpolicies.ChichilniskyandHeal(1994)showthat,ininternational agreementsforcurbingcarbon-dioxideemissions,poorercountriesshouldbeallocatedlargershares ofthetotalnumberofemissions’rightsatanefficientallocation,iftheincomeelasticityofWTPis betweenzeroandone.Finally,thepoliticalappealofenvironmentalpolicieswouldbeincreasedrather thanlimited,sinceincomegroupswouldbenefitfromenvironmentalimprovementsinaproportional way.

Theremainderofthepaperisstructuredasfollows.Section2reviewstheliteratureonthemethods forestimatingthedemandfornonmarketgoodsandonthemeasuresofincidenceofenvironmental benefits.Section3introducesthemethodologybasedonrevealedpreferencesandhouseholdproduc- tion.Thespecificationofthedemandsystem,theestimationstrategy,thedata,andtheresultsare presentedinSections4and5.Section6concludes.

2. Demandfornonmarketgoodsandmeasuresofbenefitsincidence

Researchersfacetwomainproblemswhentryingtoevaluateenvironmentalgoods:firstthese goodsarenottradedinmarkets,thereforeitisnotpossibletoobserveprices.Second,eventhough priceswereobservable,theymightnotreflecttheconsumer’smarginalwillingnesstopaybecause

1GiventheuseoftheHicks-Kaldorcompensationcriterion,aprojectresultinginaregressivedistributionofenvironmental benefitsislesslikelytopassthanaprojectthatwouldprimarilybenefithighincomegroups.Thisisbecausethesocialprofitability oftheprojectisdecidedbythesumofWTPsandrichpeoplehaveahigherWTPthanpoorpeople(HökbyandSöderqvist,2003).

Therefore,thefindingthatenvironmentalbenefitsareregressivelydistributedsuggeststheneedtouseappropriateweights takingintoaccountthedistributionofcostsandbenefitsofprojects.

(3)

thequantityofanenvironmentalgoodistypicallyrationedandcannotbemodifiedbyconsumers,at leastintheshortrun.Becauseofthepublicgoodnatureofenvironmentalcommodities,therelevant incidencemeasureisnottheincomeelasticityofdemand,buttheincomeelasticityofwillingnessto pay(KriströmandRiera,1996).Inthissectionwereviewbothissues:howtoestimateWTPandhow tomeasurebenefitsincidence.

Sincetheearlyseventiesdifferentapproacheshavebeenadoptedtoestimatethedemandforpublic goods.Thefirstwasacollectivechoiceapproachbasedonthemedianvotertheorem(Boercherding andDeacon,1972;BergstromandGoodman,1973).Theassumptionisthatpoliticaldecisionsaboutthe levelofexpendituresonpublicgoodswillbeidenticaltothequantitydemandedbythemedianvoter.

Theexpenditureofanymunicipalityonapublicgoodisassumedtobeanobservationonthedemand curvefortheconsumercharacterizedbythemedianincomeofthatmunicipality.Thisapproachhas beenpartiallyoutdatedinrecentyears.Champetal.(2003),Freeman(2003),andMälerandVincent (2005)provideusefulandbroadoverviews.

Thehedonicandlocationchoiceapproacheshavebeenwidelyused,sincetheseminalpaperby Rosen(1974),formeasuringthevalueofpublicgoods,includingcleanair,especiallyintheUnited States.Theappealofthisapproachisgivenbytheuseofobservedbehaviorinthehousingandlabor marketstoinferthevalueofnon-marketgoods.Themarginalwillingnesstopayforpublicgoods ismeasured,inthiscase,bytheirimplicitpricesasreflectedinhousingpricesandwages.Recent methodologicalinnovationscanbefoundinBajariandBenkard(2005),Ekelandetal.(2004),and Bayeretal.(2009).Inparticular,Bayeretal.(2009)showhowmigrationcostscanbeincorporated intoahedonicanalysis,includingmigrationintothecanonicalwage-hedonicmodel(Roback,1982).

AnotherimportantsurveybasedapproachwasintroducedbyBergstrometal.(1982)whofitted demandequationsforlocalpublicservicesondatafromahouseholdsurveyondemandsforpublic spendingsuppliedbytheUniversityofMichigan.Thiswasfollowedbytheflourishingofcontingent valuation(CV)studiesusingstatedpreferencestoestimateWTPforpublicgoods,suchasKriström andRiera(1996),Alberinietal.(1997),HökbyandSöderqvist(2003),Schläpfer(2006)tociteafew.

Finally,theavertingbehaviorapproachemploysthedemandformarketgoodsasaproxyforenvi- ronmentalgoodsorservices(Costa,1997;PereyraandRossi,1999;Ghalwash,2006).Severalstudies –suchasBergeretal.(1987),DickieandGerking(1991),Bresnahanetal.(1997)andMansfieldetal.

(2006)amongothers–usedavertingbehaviortoobtainWTPvaluesforareductioninexposuretoair pollutantsorinthesymptomsthatresultfromit.DickieandGerking(1991),forexample,presentan applicationofthehouseholdproductionapproachtovaluingpublicgoods.Technicalrelationshipsare estimatedbetweenhealthattributes,privategoodsthataffecthealth,andairquality.Resultsshow thatindividualsequatemarginalratesoftechnicalsubstitutioninhouseholdproductionwithrelevant priceratios.Differently,Mansfieldetal.(2006)combinestatedpreferenceandavertingbehaviordata toestimateparents’WTPforadecreaseinchildrenexposuretoozonepollution.Bergeretal.(1987) developamodeltoevaluatechangesinriskstohumanhealthandderivewillingnesstopayusing bothcostofillnessandavertingexpendituresincludingairconditioners.

Clearly,eachoftheapproachesoutlinedherehasitsadvantagesanddisadvantages,theanalysisof whichwouldbeoutofthescopeofthispaper.Itisimportanttohighlightthatthetheoreticalapproach developedbyEbert(2007)isanalternativemethodforestimatingWTP,whichwillbediscussedin thefollowingsections.

OnceanestimateoftheWTPfunctionforimprovementsinoneenvironmentalgoodisavailable,the incomeelasticityofWTPcanbecalculated.Correctlymeasuringtheincidenceofenvironmentalpoli- ciesiscrucialforassessingtheirdistributionaleffectsandhasveryimportanteconomicandpolitical consequences.Forexample,howthenetbenefitsofenvironmentalimprovementswillbedistributed byincomelevelsisveryimportantwhenevaluatingreforms,liketheKyotoprotocol,thatwillaffect othercountriesorgenerationsordifferentgroupsofcitizenswithinacountry.Dependinguponthe distributionofcostsandbenefits,environmentalpoliciesmaybepro-richorpro-poor.Environmental benefits,expressedasafractionofincome,areprogressivelydistributedwhentheyrisewithincome.

(4)

Inthiscasethecorrespondingenvironmentalpolicyispro-rich.Environmentalbenefitsare,instead, regressivelydistributed,andenvironmentalpoliciesarepro-poor,whentheyfallwithincome.2

Thedegreeofprogressivenessmaylimitapolicy’spoliticalappeal.Ifenvironmentalbenefitsare progressivelydistributed,forexample,opponentsofenvironmentalpolicies(thinkoftheU.S.refusalto ratifytheKyotoprotocol)couldgroundtheirargumentsondistributionalissuesbecause“...excessive concernwiththeenvironmentisbasicallymiddleclass”(Beckerman,1974,p.49).Paradoxically,itcould bearguedthatfurtherimplementationofenvironmentalpolicieswouldresultinaredistribution againstlowerincomegroups.

Sincethequantityofmostenvironmentalgoodsisrationed,theincomeelasticityofWTPfora fixedquantityofthepublicgoodratherthantheincomeelasticityofdemandistherelevantparam- eterformeasuringbenefitincidence.Themainproblemisthatwecannotdirectlyobserveindividual demandandpricesforapublicgood.Differentapproacheshavebeenadoptedintheliterature.The mainoneusesstatedpreferencedatabasedoncontingentvaluationsurveys(KriströmandRiera, 1996;HökbyandSöderqvist,2003;Schläpfer,2006).Studiesbasedonthisapproachconsistentlyfind averylowincomeelasticityofwillingnesstopayintherange0.1–0.5.McFaddenandLeonard(1993) andMcFadden(1994)arguedthatincomeelasticitiesinCVsurveysaretoolowaccordingtoeconomic intuition.Schläpfer(2006,p.16)emphasizesthatincomeelasticitiesofWTPbasedonCVstudiesmay bebiasedby“apeculiarcombinationofrandombidlevelsandwell-specified,realisticsurveyscenarios inCVsurveys”.Moreover,theseelasticitiescontrastinmagnitudewiththosecalculatedfromcollec- tivechoice-basedstudiesforvariouspublicgoods(BoercherdingandDeacon,1972;Bergstromand Goodman,1973)whereelasticitiesaregreaterthanone;andfromavertingbehaviorapproachesusing thedemandformarketgoodsasaproxyforenvironmentalgoodsorservices(Costa,1997;Pereyraand Rossi,1999;Ghalwash,2006).Boththecollectivechoiceapproachandtheavertingbehaviorapproach haveweaknessesthough.Asemphasizedearlier,socialchoiceprocessesaredifficulttolinktoindi- vidualpreferences.Avertingbehaviorapproaches,ontheotherhand,onlyallowforthecalculationof theincomeelasticityofdemandandnotoftheincomeelasticityofWTP.FloresandCarson(1997,p.

294)explainthatthetwomaywelldivergeandthat“discussingtheissueintermsoftheincomeclas- sificationofdemandsmayhavelittle,ifany,relevancewhenquantityrationingapplies”.Sotheincome elasticityofWTPforapublicgoodremainsanunresolvedissueeventhoughthedistributionofbene- fitsbyincomeisclearlyimportantforpolicydesign.FloresandCarson(1997)andEbert(2003)usea standardrationedmodelofconsumption(DeatonandMuellbauer,1980a)toderivetheincomeelas- ticityofWTP.Hereconsumerswiththesamepreferenceorderinghaveconvexpreferencesovern marketgoods,denotedbythevectorxandkpublicgoods,denotedbythevectorq.Consumersmay freelychoosethelevelsofx,butfacequantityrationingoverq.Virtualprices,pv,aredefined(Flores andCarson,1997)asthosethatwouldinducechoosingthesamelevelsofxandqasthoseresulting underrationingofq.Thus,avirtualpriceisaninversedemandfunctionthatdependsonthelevelsof p,qandontheutilitylevelu,whenutilityisheldconstantandonp,qandincomey,whenincomeis heldconstant.

Ifweareinterestedinthedegreetowhichthesevirtualpriceschangewhenincomevaries,the incomeelasticityofthevirtualpricecanbecalculatedas3:

vi= ∂pvi(p,q,y)

∂y y

pvi (1)

whereastheincomeelasticityofdemandis4:

di = ∂qmi (p,pv,ev)

∂y ev

qmi (2)

2Turningtoenvironmentalcosts,ratherthanbenefits,theywillbeprogressively(pro-poor)distributedwhentheyrisewith incomeandregressively(pro-rich)distributedwhentheyfallwithincome.

3Whenqmi,theMarshalliandemandofgoodi,varies,totalvirtualexpenditureevvariesaswell,thisiswhythederivativeof qmi wrtincomeismultipliedbytheratiobetweenevandqmi.

4Thecaseofmorethanonepublicgoodismorecomplexandthecorrespondingmeasuresofbenefitsincidencearederived byFloresandCarson(1997)andEbert(2003).

(5)

whereiisthegoodinvolved,qmi is theuncompensateddemandforgoodi,and evis totalvirtual expenditure.Totalvirtualexpenditureisdefinedasthelevelofexpenditureresultingfromchoosing thequantitiesxandqatthevirtualprices.Therelationshipbetweenthesetwoelasticitiesisnot determinate.Whenmorethanonepublicgoodisinvolveditmaywellbethatagoodwithanincome elasticityofdemandgreaterthanone(aluxury)hasanincomeelasticityofWTPsubstantiallyless thanone(FloresandCarson,1997).Whenonlyonepublicgoodisinvolved,Ebert(2003)provedthe followingrelationshipbetweentheincomeelasticityofthevirtualprice,v1,andtheincomeelasticity ofdemand,d1,(seeEbert,2003,equationR6candHanemann,1991,equation16):

v1=−d1

11d y

ev (3)

whered11istheowncompensatedpriceelasticityofdemandforgood1.Thisincomeelasticitydepends ond11andontheincomeelasticityofdemand,d1.Sincetheownpricesubstitutioneffectisalways negative,thesignofthisincomeelasticityisgivenbythesignoftheincomeelasticityofdemand.

FloresandCarson(1997)furthershowthattheincomeelasticityofwillingnesstopay,definedas

WTP=(∂WTP/∂y)(y/WTP),liesbetweentheminimumandthemaximumvirtualpriceincomeelas- ticity.Ingeneral,WTPexpresseshowmuchincomehouseholdsarerelativelywillingtopayforan increasedprovisionofanenvironmentalgood.WTPcanbeusedtoidentifythedistributionalpattern ofWTP,i.e.whichgroupsinsocietybenefitthemostfromenvironmentalimprovements.Environmen- talbenefitsaresaidtoberegressivelydistributedifWTP<1,proportionallydistributedifWTP=1and progressivelydistributedifWTP>1.

3. Householdproductionanddemandanalysis

Householdproduction5impliesthataspecificmarketgood,m,iscombinedwithanonmarketgood q6toproduceacommodityZ.Wethushaveamodelofavertingbehavior(Bartik,1988;Courantand Porter,1981;Harford,1984)wheremisthequantityofavertingordefensivegood.7Whilethevector ofmarketgoodsxconsumedbythehouseholdyieldsutilitydirectly,qyieldsutilityonlyindirectly throughthecommodityZ.Inourapplication,qisthelevelofairpollution,misairconditioning,and Zisthehousehold’spersonallevelofairquality.Thetechnologyisdescribedbyatwicecontinuously differentiableproductionfunctionZ=F(m,q)strictlyincreasingandconcaveinmandq.Households preferencesformarketgoodsxandforthecommodityZarerepresentedbyatwicecontinuously differentiabledirectutilityfunction,U,whichismaximizedsubjecttoabudgetpxx+pmm=yandwithq fixed.Assumingaweaklyseparableutilityfunction,agivenspecificationforthehouseholdproduction functionF(m,q),andassumingthatUdoesnotdependonqdirectly,theWTPforimprovementsinair quality,wq,canbeobtaineduniquelybytheconditionalsystemofdemandfunctions:

x=x(p,q,y) (4)

and

m=m(p,q,y) (5)

wherep=(px,pm)andbythehouseholdproductionfunctionF(m,q).Becauseofweakseparabilityof theutilityfunction,themarginalrateofsubstitutionbetweenqandmissimply:

MRSqm(m,q)= ∂F/∂q

∂F/∂m= Fq(m,q)

Fm(m,q) (6)

5ThissectionreliesonEbert(1998,2007).

6Weassume,forsimplicity,thatthereisonlyonenonmarketgoodqwhichisthelevelofoutdoorairquality.

7Inthismodel,followingEbert(2003),itisassumedthatpeopletaketheenvironmentalgood(i.e.airquality)asanexogenous factor.Inotherwords,thedecisionabouthousinglocationisexogenous,anditcanbeconsideredashavingalreadybeentaken inapreviousstage.Thisisnotthecaseintheliteratureonsortingequilibriumandhedonicmodels.

(6)

whereFqandFmdenotepartialderivatives.Themarginalwillingnesstopayforimprovementsinair quality,wq,isimplicitlydefinedbyMRSqm=wq/pmfromwhichweobtain:

wq=pv=pmMRSqm=pm

Fq(m,q)

Fm(m,q) (7)

Thedualminimizationproblemofchoosingbothqandxsoastominimizetotalexpendituresub- jecttopricespandpvandtotheutilitylevelUwouldalsoproducetheconditionalmixeddemand systemdefined byEqs.(4), (5)and (7)by applicationof Shepard’sLemma sothatwecan write wq=−Cq(pm,q,F(m(p,q,y),q))whereCq=−pmFq/Fm.ThemarginalWTPfunctioncanthereforebe determinedfromtheobserveddemandfunctionsformarketgoodsx,fromthehouseholdproduction function,andfromthemaintainedhypotheses.

Inpracticewehaveaconditionaldemandsystemforx,tobeestimated,augmentedbytheWTP function(7).Wedonotknow,atthisstage,whethertheconditionaldemandsystem(4)and(5)sup- plementedby(7)isconsistentwithutilitymaximization.Stateddifferently,wedonotknowwhether thereisaquasi-concaveutilityfunctionfromwhichthemixeddemandsystem(4),(5)and(7)canbe derived.Ebert(2007,p.283)setsoutthenecessaryandsufficientconditionsforintegrabilityofthis conditionaldemandsystemsupplementedbyaWTPfunction.Thefirstthreeconditionsaresymmetry conditionsoftheSlutskymatrixfortheaugmenteddemandsystem:

sxm= ıx ıpm+mıx

ıy= ım ıpx+xım

ıy =smx (8)

sxq= ıx ıq−wq

ıx ıy=−



ıwq

ıpx +xıwq

ıy



=−sqx (9)

smq=ım

ıq −wqım ıy =−



ıwq

ıpm+mıwq

ıy



=−sqm (10)

wheresxmaretheconventionalSlutzkysubstitutioneffectsformarketgoodsxandm,i.e.theymeasure thechangeinthequantitydemandedofeachelementinvectorxfollowingachangeinthepriceof goodm,whereassxqisthechangeinthequantitydemandedofeachelementinxfollowingachange intheprice(WTP)ofq.Condition(8)issatisfiedbyassumption,becausexandmformaconditional demandsystem,butconditions(9)and(10)havetobechecked.Inaddition,theSlutskymatrixof substitutioneffectsforthemarketgoodsxandmmustbenegativesemidefinite.Finally,thechange inthequantitydemandedofgoodqfollowingachangeinitsprice(WTP)mustbenegative:

sqq=ıwq

ıq −wq

ıwq

ıy <0 (11)

Whenconditions(8)–(11)aresatisfied,themixeddemandsystemwithhouseholdproductiondefined by(4),(5)and(7)isintegrable.

Thisapproachdoesnotrequirefurtherassumptionsanditprovidesausefulandoperationalbasis forrecoveringpreferences.Itsstartingpointsarethe“observed”demandfunctionsforthemarket goodsandthehouseholdproductionfunction.Conditionslikeweakcomplementarityortheessen- tialityofinputsarenotrequired,norisrequiredtheimpositionoftheWilligconditiontoderiveexact welfaremeasures(seeEbert,2007,p.278foradiscussionofthispoint).

4. Specificationandestimationofaconditionaldemandsystemwithhouseholdproduction

4.1. AConditionalCensoredAlmostIdealDemand(CCAID)System

Conditionaldemandfunctionscanbeusedtodealwithnonmarketgoods,suchasenvironmental goodsorbads.Thelevelof,forexample,airqualityprovidedwithoutchargetotheusermayaffect theindividual’sconsumptionofgoodsavailableinthemarket.Sinceconsumptionofairqualityis fixed,itistheconditionaldemandfunctionswhichareappropriatefortheanalysisofanindividual demandforgoodsandservicesintheshortrun(Pollack,1969).Thefunctionalformchosentospecify

(7)

ourmodelistheAlmostIdealDemandSystem(AIDS,DeatonandMuellbauer,1980b).Toobtainthe systemofconditionaluncompensatedsharesequationsweusealogarithmicconditionalcostfunction, forhouseholdh,whichimpliesPIGLOGpreferences(PollackandWales,1992):

lnC(u,p,dh,q)=lna(p,dh,q)+ub(p) (12)

wherea(p,dh,q)andb(p)arefunctionsofthemarketpricevectorp,lnindicatesthenaturallogarithm, dharedemographicvariablesandqisthefixedquantityofthenonmarketgood,airqualityinthiscase.

a(p,dh,q)isincreasingandhomogenousofdegreeoneinpandb(p)isincreasingandhomogenous ofdegreezeroinp.C(u,p,dh,q)istheconditionalcostfunction,i.e.theminimumcostnecessaryto achieveutilitylevelu,giventhepricevectorp,givendemographicsdhandwhenthequantityqofthe nonmarketgoodisfixed.ThecorrespondingsystemofconditionalMarshalliandemandfunctionsfor householdhandgoodsi=1,...,nexpressedasexpendituresharesisgivenby:

whii+



j

cij lnpj+biln



yh Ph



+



i

iikdhk+giq)lnpi (13)

whereyhistotalexpenditureofhouseholdh;theparameterscijaredefinedascij=(1/2)(cij+cji)=cji;

˛ikarethecoefficientsofthetranslatinginterceptsdh=dh1...dhkwhichinthismodelincludehouse- holds’types,households’locationandanannualtimetrendandPhisaTranslogpriceindexspecified as:

Ph0+



i

i+giq+˛ikdhk)lnpi+1 2



i



j

cij lnpilnpj (14)

Demandfunctions(13)satisfyintegrability,i.e.areconsistentwithutilitymaximization,whenthefol- lowingparametricrestrictionshold:



i˛i=1,



ibi=



jcij=0,



i˛ik=0∀k(Adding-up);



jcij=0 (Homogeneity);cij=cjiforalli,j(Symmetry).

Thepresenceofzerosinthedependentvariablesisquiteimportantforourspecificsample.To dealwiththisproblemweusethetwo-stepestimatorproposedbyShonkwilerandYen(1999)which involvesprobitestimationinthefirststepandaselectivity-augmentedequationsysteminthesecond step.8Thesystemofequations(13)isthusestimatedinthefollowingform:

si=˚(zii)wi(p,y;)+ıi(zii)+i (15) wheresiistheobservedexpenditureshareforgoodi;ziisavectorofexogenousvariables;iisa parametervector;isavectorcontainingallparameters(˛iik,bi,giandcij)inthedemandsys- tem,i=si−E(si)and where(·) and˚(·)arethe standardnormal probabilitydensity (pdf)and distribution(cdf)functions,respectively.Thesystemofequations(15)isestimatedintwo-steps:

(i)weobtainMaximumLikelihood(ML)probitestimates ˆiof iusingthebinaryoutcomesi=0 andsi>0;(ii)wecalculate˚(zi, ˆi),(ziˆi)foralliandestimate,ı12,...,ınintheaugmented system(15)byML.Suchtwo-stepestimatorisconsistent,buttheerrortermsareheteroscedastic, thustheestimatedelementsofthesecond-stepconventionalcovariancematrixareinefficient.For simplicity,weempiricallycalculatethestandarderrorsofWTPandelasticitiesusingbootstrapping andrunning500replications.Thisensuresthatthestandarderrorsofthesederivedparametersare correct.9

Thedependentvariableinthefirst-stepprobitestimatesisthebinaryoutcomedefinedbythe expenditureineachgood.TheproportionofconsuminghouseholdsforFood,HousingandCommuni- cationallexceed95%,whichpreventsreliableprobitestimates.Thus,probitisestimatedonlyforthe

8ShonkwilerandYen(1999);Yenetal.(2003)andYenandLin(2006)provideusefulliteraturereviewonestimation proceduresforcensoreddemandsystems.

9DifferentiationofEq.(15)givesdemandelasticitiesforthefirstn1goods.Elasticitiesforthenthgoodareobtained exploitingtheCournotandEngelrestrictions(DeatonandMuellbauer,1980a,p.16).DenotingtheMarshallian,Hicksianand expenditureelasticitiesforgoodiashij,∗hij andih,respectively,thennjh,∗hnj andnhcanbecalculatedusingtheCournot restriction



n

i=1whihij+whj=0andtheEngelrestriction



n

j=1hij+hi =0.

(8)

remainingcommodities,forwhichthepredictedpdfandcdfareincludedinthesecondstepofthe procedure(seeYenetal.,2003,p.464).Exogenousvariablesusedinthefirst-stepprobitestimatesare:

totalexpenditure,anannualtimetrendinlogarithmsandasetofdummyvariablestocapturespatial effectsinexpenditures:householdlocation,whetherthehouseholdresidesinabigtown,seasonality.

Inallestimatesweimposehomogeneityandsymmetry.Economictheoryalsorequiresthematrix ofthesubstitutioneffectstobenegativesemi-definite.Sucharequirementissatisfiedbyadopting aCholeskydecompositionprocedureofthepricecoefficients.Finally,wedropthe“othergoodsand services”equationtoaccommodateaddingup.

4.2. HouseholdproductionandWTPforairqualityimprovements

TospecifytheWTPfunctionforimprovementsinairqualitywechoosetheclassofhousehold productionfunctions:

Z=Fε(m,q)=(m1/2+1)qε (16)

forε∈(0,1/2]proposedbyEbert(2007,p.285)wheremistheimplicitquantityofairconditioning usedasaninputintothehouseholdproductionofZ,theinternallevelofairqualitychosenbythe household,andqisourindexofairquality.Inthishouseholdproductionfunctionmisanonessential good,thatistosaymisnotnecessarilyrequiredtoproduceZgivenq.10Thisisoneofthedesiderable propertiesofthechosenclassofproductionfunctions:wecanhaveaWTPdifferentfromzeroeven whentheexpenditureonairconditioningequalszero.Moreover,thisclassofproductionfunctions hasdecreasingreturnsofscaleinairconditioningexpenditure,namelywhenthelatterincreases, WTPincreaseslessthanproportionally.Thisisarealisticrepresentationoftheuseoftheconditioning technology.Theparameterεcanbeconsideredameasureofthedegreetowhichthelevelofexternal airqualityinfluencestheinternallevelofairqualitychosenbythehousehold.Thehigherisε,the higheristheimpactofexternalairqualityonthehouseholdproductionfunction.Finally,badair qualityconditionsareverylikelytobecorrelatedwithairconditioningexpenditures,whicharean inputinproducingthelevelofairqualitypreferredbythehousehold.Consequently,intheproduction functiontheexternallevelofairquality,q,isincludedasaninputbesidesm.Theexternaltemperature levelisnotincludedasaninput,eventhoughitcouldalsoberelevantininfluencingairconditioning’

demand.Itcanbeassumedthatahighconcentrationofthesepollutantsismainlyassociatedwitha demandforventilationandinternalairquality.Thisisbecausethebundleofairpollutantsconsidered inourairqualityindexisknowntohavestronghealtheffectsintermsofrespiratorydiseases(WHO, 2005)buthigherconcentrationsarenotcorrelatedwithhighertemperaturelevelsanddiscomfort fromheat.11Moreover,withtheexceptionofozone12(IPCC,2007), theotherpollutantsincluded intheairqualityindexarenotgreenhousegases,thereforetheyarenotassociatedwithlongterm temperatureeffects.

Thisclassofhouseholdproductionfunctionsimpliesthecostfunctions13:

Cε(pm,q,z)=

⎧ ⎨

0forZ≤qε pm

z

qε−1

2

forZ>qε

(17)

AccordingtoEq.(7),thecorrespondingWTPfunctionis:

wq(p,q,y)=2εpm(m1/2+1)m1/2/q (18)

10SeeEbert(2007),footnote11,foraninterpretationofthisproperty.

11Thecorrelationcoefficientbetweentheindexofairqualityandmaximumandminimumaverageannualtemperatures(in Celsiusdegrees)intheeightregionsunderconsiderationis0.327and0.325,respectively.

12SeeSection4.3foradetaileddescriptionoftheairqualityindex.

13ForeachhouseholdthetotalcostofproducingZisgivenbyCε(pm,q,Z)=pm(m)andtheclassofcostfunctionsinEq.(17)is obtainedbysolvingthehousehold’stotalcostminimizationproblem.WhenZqεthequantityofinputmisnegativeandthis isnotafeasiblelevel,thisiswhythecostfunctionequalszero.

(9)

Weconsiderthreevaluesofε:ε=0.1,ε=0.35andε=0.5andwetestwhethertheWTPfunction(18) isintegrablebycheckingwhetherconditions(8)–(11)aresatisfied.

4.3. Data

Weusemonthlycross-sections,fromJanuary2002toDecember2006,ofindividualItalianhouse- holds’currentexpenditurescollectedbytheIstitutoNazionalediStatistica(ISTAT)throughaspecific androutinelyrepeatedsurvey.14Currentexpendituresareclassifiedinabouttwohundredelementary goodsandservices,withtheexactnumberchangingfromyeartoyearduetominoradjustmentsin theitem’slist.15Thesurveyalsoincludesdetailedinformationonthehouseholdstructure,sothatrel- evantdataondemographiccharacteristics(suchaslocationonaregionalbasis,numberofhousehold members,ownershipofairconditioners)areavailable.Allannualsamplesareindependentlydrawn accordingtoatwo-stagedesign.16

Asub-sampleof10,671observationshasbeenselectedconsideringonlyhouseholdsowningair conditioners,usingadichotomicvariableincludedinthesurveywhichcontrolsforownership.There- fore,ourresultsarevalidforthespecificfamilytypesweconsideronlyandarenotrepresentativeof theentireItalianpopulationofhouseholds.

Airconditioningexpendituresaremainlycurrentexpenditures,soobservingazerovalueimplies thatduringthespecificmonththehouseholddidnotuseit.Thisisconsistentwithconditionersbeinga nonessentialinputinthehouseholdproductionfunction.17Thehouseholdsincludedinthesamplelive ineightregionsofItaly:Friuli-VeneziaGiulia,TrentinoAltoAdige,Liguria,Lombardia,Toscana,Lazio, SardegnaandSiciliarepresentingfourmacro-regions:Northeast(NE),Northwest(NW),Centre(CE), SouthandtheIslands(SI).Weestimateatencommoditiesdemandsystem:(1)Foodandbeverages;

(2)Housingexcludingrent18;(3)AirConditioners;(4)Clothing;(5)HealthCare;(6)Transports;(7) Communication;(8)Recreation;(9)AlcoholandTobacco;(10)Othergoodsandservices.19

Thesecommoditiesarechosenaccordingtomonthlyandregionalconsumptionpriceindicesavail- ablealsosuppliedbyISTAT,whichareincludedinthedataset.Thesepriceshavebeenextracted fromtheConsumerPriceIndex(1998=100),alsopublishedbyISTAT.SpecificallyweusetheCon- sumerPriceIndexforthewholenation(NIC)whichmonitorssalespriceseverymonthinallItalian provinces.NICisdividedinto12expenditurecategoriesenteringthenationalindexwithaspecific weightreflectingtherelativeimportanceoftheconcernedgoodontotalconsumption.Manyofthese categoriescoincidewiththecommoditiesinourdemandsystem.Someofthemhavebeenaggregated tocorrespondtotheremaininggoodsinourdemandsystem.Inaddition,weconsiderexpenditures onairconditioningandthecorrespondingelementarypriceindexalsosuppliedbyISTAT.Wehave identifiedtheexpenditureonconditionersasthebestproxyofdefensiveexpenditureagainstairpol- lutionandclimatechangewecouldfindintheSurveyonHouseholdsExpenditures.ISTATrecords expenditureonairconditionersbyItalianhouseholdsonamonthlybasis.Weselectonlyhousehold owningairconditionersfortworeasons:first,thisallowsustoestimatethehouseholdproduction function(forwhichotherwisearelevantinputwouldhavebeenequaltozero);second,byassum- ingthathouseholdspurchasedairconditionerspreviously,theexpenditurerecordedbyISTATcanbe

14Adifferentsampleofhouseholdsisinterviewedduringeachmonth;theitemlistincludesalsononcurrentexpenditures, withatotalnumberofabout280goodsandservices.

15Weimplicitlyassumestrongseparabilityinconsumers’preferencesbetweencurrentandotherexpenditures.

16DetailsonthesamplingprocedureusedtocollectthesedatacanbefoundinISTAT,IndaginesuiConsumidelleFamiglie.File standard.Manualed’uso.Anni1997–2006.

17SeeSection4.2foradescriptionofthehouseholdproductionfunction.

18Therationaleforchoosingtoincludehomerelatedexpenditures(compositecommodity(3))isthatasubstitutionrelation- shipislikelytoexistbetweenairconditioningandothergoodsandservicespurchasedbythehousehold(bywayofexample, theneedofairconditioningislikelytodiminishinbetterinsulatedhouses).

19Eachcommodityhasbeenobtainedasanaggregateofdetailedcurrentexpendituresonmorethantwohundredelementary goodsandservices.Aggregationispossibleassuming,asitisusuallydone,thatgoodswithineachgroupareconsistentwith theHicksandLeontiefCompositeCommodityTheorem(DeatonandMuellbauer,1980a,pp.120–121).

(10)

consideredasbeingcurrentasitisgivenbyoperatingandmaintenancecostsonly.20TheNorthwest (NW)regionhasthehighestexpenditureshareonairconditioners(seeAppendixTableA1),followed bytheSouth(SI),theNortheastand theCentre(CE).Thusa markedgeographical trenddoesnot exist:livingintheNWproducesapositiveeffectonconditionersexpenditureshare,butthisisalso trueintheSouth.Airconditioners’demanddependsonhouseholdlocationanditdoesnotincrease proportionallywithtotalexpenditure.Thesepatternssuggesttheimportanceofincludingdummy variablesrelatedtotheregionandlocationwherethehouseholdliveswhenanalysingWTPforair quality.

Tosummarize,thesampleusedinourestimationsconsistsof10,671householdobservationscol- lectedfor8regionsover12monthsfor5years.Usingrtoindicatetheregion,mthemonthandy theyear,thedatahavebeenorganizedbyliningupmonthlydata(m=1−12)oneachmacro-region (r=1−4)foreachyear(y=1−5)inavectorof10,671observations.Asetofdummyvariablesisincluded toaccountforthemacro-areainwhichthehouseholdlives(NW,NE,CE,SI)inordertomodeldiffer- encesinpurchasingpatterns,inparticularwithrespecttotheexpenditureonairconditioners.Inorder totakeintoaccounttherelevantroleplayedbyexternaltemperature–andthenthelikelyseasonality inairconditioningexpenditure–weincludeadummyvariable(SEASON)equalto1forthewarmest monthsoftheyear:June,July,AugustandSeptember.Ourhypothesishereisthattheeffectofair pollutionmaybeworsenedinthewarmestmonthsoftheyear.Forthisreason,itseemsappropriate tocontrolfortheseasonalityeffectofexternaltemperaturesininfluencingtheexpendituresrelated totheuseofairconditioners.Theseasonalityeffectsassociatedwithtemperatureareinsteadashort termphenomenaandassuchseemedworthtobetakenintoaccountbyusingadichotomicvariable.

Wealsoaddacategoricvariable(LOC)forwhetherthehouseholdlivesinatownwithmorethan 50,000inhabitants(1),lessthan50,000inhabitants(2)orinasmallvillage(3)inordertomodel spatialeffects,andalogarithmicannualtimetrend.

Wecombinethesedatawithinformationonairconcentrationsofthreepollutants:Ozone(O3), Particulate(PM10)andNitrogenDioxide(NO2).Thesehavebeenusedtocomputeacategoricallycon- tinuousindexofairquality(IQA),astandardizedindicatorofairqualityinagivenlocation.Following thedefinitiongivenbytheNationalAgencyfortheProtectionoftheEnvironment(APAT)according toguidelinesfromtheEnvironmentalProtectionAgency(EPA),theindexisconstructedasaweighted averageofdataonhourlyconcentrationsofthreeairpollutantssuppliedbyAPAT.21Theweightswere providedbyeachoftheagenciesinchargeofcalculatingairqualityindicesonaregionalbasis.

DataonhourlyconcentrationsofOzone(O3),Particulate(PM10)andNitrogenDioxide(NO2)were availablefromJanuaryfirst2002toDecember31st2006.ForeachItalianregionhourlypollutants concentrationshavebeencollectedfromaverylargenumberofstationslocatedinaTraffic,Industrial orBackgroundarea.WeconsiderconcentrationsfromTrafficandBackgroundstationsonlyinorder tomergethemwithconsumptionexpendituresofhouseholdsinUrbanorBackgroundareas.Dueto missingdataovertheinvestigationperiod,onlyeightItalianregionshavebeenconsidered:Lombardia, Liguria,FriuliVeneziaGiulia,TrentinoAltoAdige,Lazio,Toscana,SiciliaandSardegna.

Startingfromatotalof1,596,938hourlyobservations,adailyregionalIQAdhasbeenobtainedas:

IQAd=(I1+I2)/2wherethesubscriptdindicatestheday;I1=(PM10/PM10)×100isasub-indexwhere PM10isthemeandailyparticulateconcentrationandPM10isthethresholdvalueforparticulatecon- centrationsadmittedbytheItalianlaw22(50␮g/m3).Thesecondsub-index,I2,issimplythehighest betweenNitrogenDioxideandOzoneconcentrations:I2=max(NO2,O3).ThresholdvaluesforNO2and O3concentrationsare,respectively,200␮g/m3and120␮g/m3.

DailyIQAshavebeenaveragedovereachmonthtoobtainmonthlyindices.Asaresult,ourregional IQAisgivenbyasampleof960observations(12months×5years×16areas).Fromthesemonthly

20Itisimportanttonotethattheexpenditureonconditionersisnotrelatedtotheelectricitybill,sincehouseholdswouldnot beabletodisentangletheshareofelectricityconsumptionrelatedtoconditioners.Theexpenditureonelectricityiscollected inaspecificcategoryincludedintheSurveyonHoseholdExpenditure.

21Dataonairpollutantsconcentrationsarefreelydownloadableatwww.apat.it.ThesamedataareavailablefromtheEuropean AirQualityDatabaseoftheEuropeanEnvironmentalAgency.

22D.M.60/02.

(11)

Table1 Thedata.

No.ofhouseholds:10,671

Currentexpenditures(Euro/month) Mean Std.dev. Min Max

Totalexpenditure 1784.705 1063.757 250.019 6958.370

Foodfromstores 485.747 283.304 0.000 2374.739

Alcoholandtobacco 44.466 58.495 0.000 551.480

Clothing 190.509 285.023 0.000 4387.530

Householdoperation 210.760 154.237 0.000 3501.580

Airconditioners 12.315 82.999 0.000 1028.930

Health 112.068 278.392 0.000 5228.750

Transports 162.021 129.441 0.000 1042.620

Communication 64.838 50.950 0.000 652.949

Recreation 52.934 85.197 0.000 1597.560

Othergoodsandservices 458.282 530.354 0.000 5228.920

Priceindices(1998=1)

Foodfromstores 1.135 0.034 0.826 1.337

Alcoholandtobacco 1.247 0.115 0.826 1.436

Clothing 1.127 0.040 0.824 1.364

Housing 1.145 0.053 0.821 1.365

Airconditioners 0.964 0.040 0.869 1.074

Health 1.095 0.034 0.816 1.365

Transports 1.190 0.068 0.815 1.392

Communication 0.842 0.083 0.701 1.393

Recreation 1.101 0.030 0.813 1.393

Othergoodsandservices 1.185 0.052 0.809 1.393

Otherexogenousvariables

IQA 5.630 1.232 1.000 7.000

NW 0.279 0.448 0.000 1.000

NE 0.108 0.311 0.000 1.000

CE 0.219 0.414 0.000 1.000

SI 0.393 0.488 0.000 1.000

LOC 1.158 0.446 1.000 3.000

SEASON 0.346 0.476 0.000 1.000

Annualtimetrend 3.183 1.378 1.000 5.000

indices,theIQAisconstructedasacategoricalvariable(LQ)varyingbetween1(Veryunhealthy)and 7(Excellent).23SummarystatisticsofthedataareshowninTable1.

4.4. Results

TableA2intheappendixshowsfirst-stepprobitestimatesalongwiththeirasymptoticstandard errors.Thedependentvariablesaretheexpendituresharesforthe9commoditiesinoursystemof demands,listedinthefirstrowofthetable.Manyofthevariablesincludedaresignificantatthe5%level ineachexpenditureshareequation.Incomeplaysapositiveroleinexplainingthebudgetshareofall goods.Seasonalityandtheannualtimetrendalsoplayasignificantroleintheprobabilityofconsuming manyofthecommodities.Theindexofairquality(LQvariable)isalsosignificantinexplainingthe expendituresonairconditionersandhastheexpectednegativesign,24namelybadairqualitylevels areassociatedwithhigherexpenditures.Goingfromabigtoasmalltown(LOCvariable)hasanegative roleindeterminingairconditioners’purchase,probablybecausebigcitiesaremorepolluted.Going froma bigtoa smalltownalsoplaysapositive andsignificantroleinexplainingTransportsand Alcohol/Tobaccochoices,buthasanegativeandsignificantrole,asexpected,inexplainingrecreation

23Wetreateachchangeincategoryashavingthesameeffectonairquality.WefollowtheRegionalAgenciesfortheProtec- tionoftheEnvironment(APATs)thatconstructregionalairqualityindicesaccordingtotheguidelinesoftheEnvironmental ProtectionAgencyascategorical/ordinalvariables(ARPAPiemonte,2007).

24WeexpectanegativesignsincetheIQAiscomputedinsuchawaythathighervaluesareassociatedwithbetterairquality conditions.

(12)

Table2

Integrabilityconditions(samplemean).

Conditions Estimate

Sx1,q+Sq,x1=0 0.000529

Sx2,q+Sq,x2=0 −0.024384

Sx3,q+Sq,x3=0 0.369060

Sx4,q+Sq,x4=0 −0.121260

Sx5,q+Sq,x5=0 −0.036447

Sx6,q+Sq,x6=0 −0.036262

Sx7,q+Sq,x7=0 −0.024694

Sx8,q+Sq,x8=0 −0.036455

Sx9,q+Sq,x9=0 −0.036107

Sq,q<0 −0.259180

choices.TableA3showssecond-stepestimatesoftheCCAIDsystem.25 Standarderrorshavebeen computedfromaheteroscedastic-consistentmatrixusingtheWhitecorrection.

Hicksian(compensated)elasticities,basedonparametersofthesecond-step,arecomputedatthe samplemeanas:∗hij =hij+hiwhj wherehij is theuncompensatedpriceelasticityofgoodiwith respecttopricejandihistheexpenditureelasticityofgoodi.TheseelasticitiesareshowninTableA4 alongwithexpenditureelasticitiesforallgoodsandtheestimatedbudgetshares.Allexpenditure elasticitiesaresignificantlydifferentfromzero.Airconditioningappearstobealuxurygood,withan incomeelasticityequalto1.30.26Astothebudgetshares,Food,Housing,TransportsandClothingare theconsumptioncategoriesonwhichthelargestpartofthemonthlyexpenditureisallocated.Thisisin linewithsimilarworksonItalianhouseholdconsumption(MoschiniandRizzi,1997;BalliandTiezzi, 2010).Allthecompensatedownpriceelasticities,calculatedatthesamplemeansofvariables,have thecorrectsignandarestatisticallysignificant.Airconditioningdisplaysaveryhighandsignificant compensatedownpriceelasticity(1.80),butnoneofthecross-priceelasticitiesaresignificant.Some oftheothercompensatedownpriceelasticitiesaregreaterthanone:Food,Clothing,Health,Transport andCommunication.

Theconditionaldemandsystem(13)andtheWTPfunction(18)areintegrableifandonlyifcondi- tions(8)–(11)aresatisfied.Theseintegrabilityconditionshavebeencheckedatthesamplemeanand theresultsforε=0.5areshowninTable2.Theconditionsareallsatisfied,thereforethemixeddemand systemwithhouseholdproductionisintegrable.WTPformarginalimprovementsinairqualityand itsincomeelasticitycalculatedatthesamplemeanofexogenousvariables,alongwiththeirstandard errors,areshowninTables3and4.

HouseholdmarginalWTPforimprovementsinairqualityinEuro/monthforfiveincomegroupsare showninTable3forthreevaluesofε.WTPissmallerthan10eurosformosthouseholds,inparticular avaluearound3euroshasaveryhighfrequency. TheWTPispositivelycorrelatedtohousehold incomerevealingthatrichhouseholdsvalueairqualityimprovementsmorehighlythanpoorones.

NeverthelesswhenexpressedasafractionofhouseholdincomeWTPincreasesonlyslightlywith incomeforanyvalueofε.ForhigherincomelevelsWTPasafractionofincomedecreasesfrom0.25%

fory≤6000to0.13%fory>6000.Thefactthathouseholdsinlowerincomegroupshavearelatively higherWTPforairqualityimprovementsisconsistentwithfindingsbyKriströmandRiera(1996) andHökbyandSöderqvist(2003).Thismaybebecausehigherincomehouseholdsliveonaveragein areaswithrelativelylowlevelsofairpollutionandtheythereforeexperiencealessrelevantphysical improvement(e.g.airqualitychangesfromgoodtoverygood)inair qualityin comparisonwith

25Wereplicatedfirst(Probit)andsecond-stepestimatesaddingaverageregionalmaxtemperaturesamongtheexplanatory variablesoftheshareequations.IntheProbitequations,thecoefficientofmaxtemperaturesissignificantforthe“Clothing”

equationonly.Wedidnotdetectanyremarkablechangeintheestimatedparametersofthedemandsystem.

26Itisworthmentioningthattheincomeelasticityassociatedtoairconditioning,aswellasthepriceelasticities,areallshort termelasticities.Sincethestockofairconditionersisbuiltupovertime,andsuchaprocessislikelytobeincompleteinsome regions,theincomeelasticityofWTPisalsotobeinterpretedasvalidintheshortterm.

(13)

Table3

WTPforairqualityimprovements(Euro/month).

Incomelevel ε=0.15 ε=0.35 ε=0.5

Overallsamplemean 0.687 1.602 2.290

(10,671) 0.025 0.062 0.087

y800 0.141 0.329 0.470

(1016) 0.018 0.044 0.062

y2000 0.475 1.108 1.582

(4993) 0.022 0.049 0.070

y4000 1.476 3.444 4.920

(2808) 0.059 0.140 0.194

y6000 2.260 6.207 8.867

(401) 0.253 0.587 0.870

y>6000 2.296 5.357 7.652

(72) 0.484 1.071 1.568

Note:StandardErrorsinItalicsbelowcoefficients.BoldentriescorrespondtorejectionofH0:e=0atthe5%significancelevel foratwotailedtest.

y=householddisposableincomeproxiedbytotalcurrentexpenditure.

Table4

IncomeelasticityofWTPforairqualityimprovements.

Incomelevel WTP

Overallsamplemean 1.164

(10,671) 0.245

y800 1.234

(1016) 0.311

y2000 1.165

(4993) 0.266

y4000 1.128

(2808) 0.178

y6000 1.174

(401) 0.155

y>6000 1.345

(72) 0.258

Note:StandardErrorsinItalicsbelowcoefficients.BoldentriescorrespondtorejectionofH0:e=0atthe5%significancelevel foratwotailedtest.

y=householddisposableincomeproxiedbytotalcurrentexpenditure.

lowincomehouseholds.AlowerWTPforricherhouseholdsmayalsobeexplainedbyalargersetof substitutionpossibilities.

5. IncomeelasticitiesofWTPforairqualityimprovements

WecalculateWTP=(∂WTP/∂y)(y/WTP)fortheentiresampleandforfiveincomegroups.Theoverall samplemeanelasticityisequalto1.164,thusaonepercentincomeincreasewouldimplyanincrease inWTPofslightlymorethanonepercent.Therefore,WTPisbasicallyincome-neutralandanincome variationismorethancompletelytransferredtoWTP.Thisresultisconsistentwithotherstudiesfind- ingaWTPforenvironmentalgoodsbeinganincreasingfunctionofincome(HarrisonandRubinfeld, 1978;KriströmandRiera,1996;HökbyandSöderqvist,2003).

AnincreasingpatternoftheabsolutelevelofWTPwithrespecttohouseholdincomesignalsthat thedemandfunctionsforcleanairhavepositiveincomeelasticities.Weconsistentlyfindapositive incomeelasticityofWTP.Thusthericheracountry,thelargeristheabsolutelevelofWTPforair qualityincomparisonwithapoorercountry.Thismightbeimportantforenvironmentalplanswith longtimehorizons,asitsuggeststhat,associetiesgetricher,theytendtovalueenvironmentalquality morehighly.

Sincetheincomeelasticityofhigherincomegroupsmaybedifferentfromthatoflowerincome groups,wehavecomputedthiselasticityfordifferentincomeclasses(Table4).TheelasticityofWTP

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

Giocoli N., Games judges don't play: predatory pricing and strategic reasoning in US antitrust, Supreme Court Economic Review, Vol.. Giocoli N., Predatory Pricing in

We analyzed the first visits carried out by a local mountain psychiatric service in 9 months from January to September 2013.. OBJECTIVES and

Such variety of gain layers will allow identifying the most radiation hard technology to be employed in the production of UFSD, to extend their radiation resistance beyond the current

We divided potential factors that could influence a household’s decision about installing RES into two groups: (1) demographic and social factors and (2) economic

Thus, in the course of mathematical modeling established that the proposed method of using an air curtain in the air supplier and ventilation shafts will prevent the negative and

Marine air conditioning system mainly includes chiller, water system and wind system. The water system includes chilled water pump and cooling water pump [9,10].Analysis of table

Con este obje- tivo debe ponerse especial atención en el comercio realizado en el mundo árabe y en los documentos firmados fuera de Génova para buscar posibles causas de

Dottorato di Ricerca in Economia Politica, XVIII ciclo.. Microeconomics: production and cost functions May