• Non ci sono risultati.

Competent demand pull and technological flows within sectoral systems: the evidence on differences within Europe

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "Competent demand pull and technological flows within sectoral systems: the evidence on differences within Europe"

Copied!
34
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

Competent demand pull and technological flows within sectoral systems: The

evidence on differences within Europe

Abstract

The paper implements the competent demand pull hypothesis. Accordingly demand-pulling effects take place only if the increase of the derived demand for both capital and intermediary inputs is accompanied by knowledge interactions carried by the market transactions of intermediate inputs between competent customers and their upstream suppliers. Vertical knowledge interactions-cum-transactions yield pecuniary knowledge externalities that are substantial ingredients in making the competent demand operate the positive impact on productivity growth. The competent demand pull hypothesis rejuvenates the standard demand pull approach through the focus on the sectoral architecture of market-embedded inter-sectoral knowledge linkages between competent users and innovative producers. To empirically test the hypothesis, we measure such market-embedded and competent influence with the derived demand for intermediates – taken from input-output tables – accounting for productivity increases downstream. Dynamic panel techniques are implemented to exclude the possibility of reverse causal effects. The evidence regarding the European Union (EU) over the period 1995-2007 suggests the presence of strong and positive competent demand impulses, but the effects vary between three European Union (EU) sectoral systems, EU core, East and South, stressing the role of the sectoral architecture.

Keywords Competent demand. Derived demand. Knowledge interactions. Pecuniary knowledge externalities Productivity growth Sectoral system.

JEL Classification L16 • O3 O52

1 Introduction

The importance of demand in the process of economic growth was extensively discussed in the past theoretical and empirical literature. The positive relationship between output and productivity growth identified by the Verdoorn’s Law stresses the role of demand as the driver of increasing returns that account for output growth Verdoorn (1949). Building upon the Verdoorn’s Law, Kaldor (1966 and 1972) narrows the scope of the analysis and elaborated the demand pull hypothesis, according to which, the increase of the aggregate demand, is likely to stir economic system to innovate. Schmookler (1966) introduced further refinements focusing the positive effects of investments and more specifically of the demand for capital goods. An array of empirical and

(2)

theoretical contributions tested the demand pull hypotheses with contrasting results (Brouwer and Kleinknecht, 1999; Crespi and Pianta, 2008; Edquist et al., 2000; Guerzoni, 2010; Jaffe, 1988; Kleinknecht and Verspagen, 1990; McCombie, Pugno, Soro, 2002; Mommen and Rolfstam, 2009; Nemet, 2009; Piva and Vivarelli, 2007; Scherer, 1982a and Walsh, 1984; Di Stefano, Gambardella, Verona, 2012; Vergeer & Kleinknecht (2014)).

The results of Vergeer & Kleinknecht (2014) are of particular relevance in this context. They show that the evidence of the Verdoorn-Kaldor Law disappears completely as soon as shorter-term business cycle fluctuations are taken into account. The positive relationship between output and productivity growth seems to be driven exclusively by short-run dynamics in capacity utilization. This is because the labour productivity measure (expressed in terms of value added per hours worked) is sensitive to such fluctuations, due to labour hoarding over the business cycle.

Both the standard view and the later elaborations of the demand-pull hypothesis, however, have two main limitations. First, the role of competences of who demands in generating positive impulses to innovate is not sufficiently accounted for. Second, both the early demand-pull hypothesis and its extensions are silent about the precise channels through which the positive impulses to innovate would be transmitted. This second limitation is due to the lack of proper microeconomic foundation of the demand-pull hypothesis.

The aim of this paper is to make a further step along the line of analysis Verdoorn-Kaldor-Schmookler, introducing more articulated microfoundations that qualify the driving role of demand. Specifically, we articulate the competent demand-pull hypothesis that calls attention on the derived demand for both capital goods and intermediary inputs as the driver of knowledge interactions between competent users and receptive producers as the key element that accounts for increasing returns to technology (McCombie, Pugno, Soro, 2002; Antonelli and Gehringer, 2015a, b, c).

According to the hypothesis, demand impulses need to come from competent and productive, rather than generic customers, in order to generate significant upstream effects in terms of productivity growth (as measured in terms of total factor productivity, TFP). Generic demand pull is not sufficient to support TFP growth. However, the increase of competent demand is a necessary, but not sufficient condition for the increase of TFP. The increase of demand can exert the – expected – positive effects only if it is strictly associated with the access to knowledge externalities that make possible the necessary generation of new technological knowledge and the eventual introduction of innovations in upstream sectors.

The competent demand pull hypothesis differs from the hypotheses of both Kaldor and Schmookler as it stresses the role of the derived demand of both capital goods and intermediary inputs. The analysis is focused on the derived demand, instead of the Kaldorian aggregate and final

(3)

demand. It also broadens the scope of the analysis implemented by Schmookler as it includes not only capital goods, but also intermediary inputs as key drivers of knowledge interactions. Finally, the competent demand pull hypothesis builds upon the contributions of Scherer (1964; 1982a and b) Von Hippel, (1976) and Lundvall (1985) who identified the central role of user-producer knowledge interactions which parallel, within value chains, inter-sectoral transactions.

More specifically, the competent demand pull hypothesis suggests that demand impulses – expressed by the derived demand of both capital and intermediary inputs – can pull the introduction of innovations only if effective user-producers interactions along value chains can actively support the generation of new technological knowledge. When demand impulses are originated by downstream activities with low levels of competence and user-producer interactions are not able to provide upstream industries with sufficient access to external knowledge, the increase of demand is not sufficient to pull the generation of additional technological knowledge. When downstream users command qualified technological knowledge, they activate sophisticated feedbacks that make external knowledge available at costs below equilibrium levels. When such knowledge interactions-cum-transactions complement demand impulses, upstream producers take advantage of pecuniary knowledge externalities, generate new technological knowledge at costs that are below equilibrium levels and introduce innovations (Antonelli, 2013).

The contribution of this paper is complementary to three previous investigations (Antonelli and Gehringer, 2015a, 2015b and 2015c). Prior analyses had three main aims: 1) to lay down conceptual basis for the concept of competent demand, 2) to elaborate a general perspective, in which the working of the competent demand-pull hypothesis is investigated on average across all industrial sectors and national systems and 3) to analyse the relative importance of nineteen manufacturing and service sectors in generating positive productivity impulses based on the transmission of the competent demand.

The present paper enriches the picture, by disentangling and characterizing the intra-European differences in the operating of the competent demand-pull effects. Precisely, it focuses the attention on the distinctive characteristics of the sectoral architectures across different economic systems. The comparative context of the empirical framework aims to assess how the demand of intermediates and the underlying pecuniary knowledge externalities, coming from competent downstream sectors, influence the productivity performance of upstream sectors in different European sectoral systems. In doing so, we first look at purely domestic inter-sectoral influences and then compare them with effects stemming from a combination of both domestic and international factors.

(4)

Within the context of the competent demand approach, this paper articulates and tests the specific hypothesis that the sectoral architecture of an economic system plays a role in stirring and channeling effective knowledge transactions. In order to appreciate the effects of the differences across economic systems in terms of organized complexity and knowledge connectivity, our attention concentrates on the assessment of intra-European differences in the occurrence of competent demand effects. Our expectation here is that such effects are not distributed evenly across sectoral systems, but crucially depend on the underlying, economic and non-economic conditions. Within our sample of 15 EU countries, we distinguish between three groups of countries, namely, EU core, East and South. The distinction is motivated by the within-group homogeneous performance in terms of productivity growth over the observation period.

The results of our analysis confirm that the rate of technological change, proxied by TFP, at the system level is, indeed, pulled by the growth of the competent demand, but depends strongly on the type of the sectoral architecture. Some sectoral architectures are able to activate – more than others – the inter-sectoral knowledge complementarities that take place by means of knowledge interactions-cum-transactions. The sectoral architecture of market transactions cum knowledge interactions is essential in explaining intra-European differences in the sectoral productivity performance. In this sense, our analysis makes clear that, although competent demand impulses are significant and strong across the entire EU, there are non-negligible differences between the three country groups that depend upon their sectoral architecture.

Following Fingleton and McCombie (1998) and McCombie and Robert ( 2007) the results of our analysis may help to articulate a long-term interpretation of the Verdoorn’s Law as a form of dynamic increasing returns that overcomes the criticisms of Vergeer & Kleinknecht (2014). Our evidence confirms, in fact, that the relationship between output and productivity growth holds in the long-term, provided that: i) the derived demand of both capital and intermediary inputs and ii) the mechanisms by means of which demand is able to drive the growth of productivity are taken into account.

The rest of the paper is structured as it follows. Section 2 provides a theoretical framework briefly summarizing the standard hypothesis and discussing the crucial ingredients of the competent demand-pull hypothesis. Section 3 presents the empirical framework of analysis. In Section 4, data and its sources are briefly discussed. Section 5 describes the econometric strategy and presents the main results based upon input-output tables for 15 European countries in the years 1995-2007. Section 6 extends the results by re-estimating the model in the way to account for influences of sectoral openness to trade. The last section summarizes the main results and proposes some policy implications.

(5)

2. The competent versus the standard demand-pull hypothesis

With respect to the basic frame laid down by Kaldor and Schmookler, an array of contributions enriched the understanding of the demand-driven mechanisms, providing positive evidence on the role of the bottom-up growth. Crucially, the focus in this strand of the literature has been on productivity impulses rather than on output in general. Those studies differ in three dimensions regarding the choice of the method to measure innovation, the choice of the aggregation level and the choice of the empirical method. More precisely, to measure innovation, different indicators have been implemented: dedicated patents (Scherer, 1982a), R&D expenditures (Jaffe, 1988; Kleinknecht and Verspagen, 1990), total factor productivity (Jaffe, 1988) and labour productivity (Crespi and Pianta, 2008). The aggregation levels have been chosen between the sector-level and firm-level (Brouwer and Kleinknecht, 1999; Piva and Vivarelli, 2007). Others based their empirical strategies on case-study analyses as in Walsh (1984), Nemet (2009) and Guerzoni (2010).

The aforementioned contributions developing the demand-pull hypothesis suffer from two important limitations. First, the competences of who generates the demand flows play a very limited role. Second, and most importantly, it is unclear by means of which precise mechanism the demand of competent customers is channeled to the upstream producers. This second drawback is due to the lack of proper microfoundations of the standard demand-pull hypothesis.

A careful reading of the literature suggests the existence of the distinction between the contributions more directly inspired by the macroeconomic approach articulated by Kaldor and those that elaborate upon the legacy of Schmookler. The former stresses the positive effects of an increase of final demand on aggregate demand and on the levels of the division of labour. In so doing, Kaldor relies upon the analysis of Allyn Young (1928) about the positive effects of the increased size of the market upon productivity levels, emphasizing at the same time the role of specialization of economic activities in new industries. While Kaldor (1972) calls attention to the general effects of the shift of aggregate demand engendered by an increase of final demand, Schmookler (1966) stresses the positive effects of the derived demand of innovative capital goods and intermediary inputs, focusing on the vertical flows of transactions along the value chains as vectors of crucial inter-sectoral flows of technological knowledge. Schmookler pays a much stronger attention to the complementarity between demand impulses and the economic conditions for the generation of technological knowledge, emphasizing the important role of the sectoral architecture of economic systems and of the institutional set-up characterizing the organization of inventive activities. Schmookler (1966) synthesizes the analysis of the demand-pull effects with two sets of outcomes. The first refers to a long standing exploration of the role of technological

(6)

knowledge as an indispensable input into the introduction of innovations (Schmookler 1962). The second appreciates the industrialization of inventive activity based upon the formation of professional inventors with dedicated training that complement the inventive activity of part-time practitioners (Schmookler, 1954 and 1957). Schmookler narrowed the scope of the Kaldorian analysis to the driving role of the demand of capital goods. In his approach the derived demand of intermediary inputs does not receive the necessary attention.

Our contribution aims to re-assessing the demand-pull hypothesis taking advantage of the recent advances of the economics of knowledge (Antonelli and David, 2015) with two distinct changes: i) it calls attention on the role of the derived demand of both capital goods and intermediary inputs; ii) it stresses the role of vertical knowledge interactions that parallel and complement vertical transactions.

A major input in this direction has been made by the literature on procurement and specifically by the pathbreaking contribution of Clarles Edquist and colleagues at the Lund Univerity (Edquist et al., 2000; Hommen and Rolfstam, 2009). They have shown how important the role of sophisticated users in guiding upstream suppliers towards the generation of new technological knowledge and the eventual introduction of technological innovations is. Their contribution has revealed that the traditional demand-pull mechanism can be fruitfully enriched by the appreciation of the central role of the bottom-up flows of knowledge ‘spilling’ from customers to suppliers. 1

The grafting of the economics of knowledge into the demand-pull framework enabled Antonelli and Gehringer to articulate the “competent demand-pull” hypothesis (Antonelli and Gehringer, 2015a, b and c). The competent demand-pull hypothesis relies upon the analysis of Schumpeter (1947), according to which – unexpected – changes in both factor and product markets, including changes in demand, expose firms to mismatches. As a response to such mismatches, they can react creatively and innovate, but only when rich knowledge externalities are available. Firms that cannot rely upon strong knowledge externalities can only react in an adaptive way changing their techniques in the given map of isoquants (Antonelli, 2011). The demand-pull without knowledge externalities are not sufficient to engender the creative reaction that leads to the introduction of innovations.

1 The debate on the validity of the demand-pulling hypothesis and on the empirical strategies for its verification was attracting a lot of attention especially in the 1980s. There are prominent contributions (Mowery and Rosenberg, 1979; Dosi, 1982; Geroski and Walters, 1995; Di Stefano et al., 2012) which succeeded in discussing some important methodological issues referred to the demand-pulling empirical evidence. For an overview, see Antonelli and Gehringer (2015b).

(7)

The competent demand-pull hypothesis applies to the derived rather than generic demand and takes into account the downstream sector-level rates of technological change. The derived demand includes both capital goods and intermediary inputs. In so doing, the competent demand pull hypothesis places itself in between the approach elaborated by Kaldor that calls attention on the role of the final demand, and Schmookler that calls attention on the role of capital goods alone. The derived demand of both capital and intermediary inputs is clearly closer to the Kaldorian aggregate demand and yet it qualifies it as it calls attention on the vertical value chain. This new, re-defined, scope of application of the classical demand-pull hypothesis stems directly from the appreciation of the role of knowledge interactions as carriers of pecuniary knowledge externalities. The latter make the external knowledge available at costs below equilibrium levels (Antonelli, 2008; Gehringer, 2011).

The capability of a system to introduce and adopt timely technological innovations is influenced not only by the internal efforts to generate new technological knowledge, but also and most effectively, by the amount of external knowledge that flows between the sectors of the system, taking into account the strength of their links as measured by the Leontief coefficients. This, in turn, emphasizes the role of the levels of organized complexity of each system, with all the consequences in terms of quantity and quality of knowledge externalities that are available. The structure, the organization and the institutional set-up of economic systems differ widely in terms of knowledge connectivity that affects their capability to disseminate knowledge spillovers and to use them to generate new technological knowledge (Page, 2011).

The organized complexity of a system differs according to its composition in terms of a wide range of mesoeconomic characteristics, such as the distribution of clusters, districts and networks, the levels of skilled workers mobility, the types of institutional set-up and the sectoral involvement in international trade. The most of the aforementioned characteristics – with the non-negligible exception of international trade – are incorporated in the sectoral architecture of value chains as synthesized by the input-output matrices, which, thus, are a key component and determinant of the organized complexity of an economic system. The organized complexity of a system shapes the quality of market transactions and knowledge interactions. Systems with higher levels of organized complexity experience higher levels of knowledge connectivity. In turn, higher levels of connectivity make the access to the existing stocks of knowledge - both internal and external to each firm and other research institutions - easier and cheaper. This favours the generation of technological knowledge, into which external knowledge is an indispensable input, at costs that are below equilibrium levels. The access and use of external knowledge at costs that are below equilibrium levels account for the eventual increase of TFP (Antonelli, 2013).

(8)

The competent demand pull is likely to be more effective in economic systems characterized by high levels of organized complexity. To better understand this issue, it is useful to recall the systemic approach introduced by Scherer (1982b) and Pavitt (1984). Their elaboration, indeed, stresses the role of the competence of the sources of the demand impulses and their distribution within the organized complexity of the system with special attention to its sectoral architecture.

For given levels of innovation input (R&D and non-R&D activities), a system can generate more technological knowledge and, hence, introduce and adopt faster technological innovations, according to the sectoral architecture of the system. A system endowed with innovative sectors that have high levels of centrality can support the innovative performance of all the system with the dissemination of knowledge and the activation of learning processes by means of knowledge interactions accompanied by commercial transactions. Advanced users can provide innovative inputs to many other sectors and demand innovative inputs from their suppliers, stimulating further innovations of the latter with demand-side knowledge impulses.

Sectoral architectures characterized by the centrality of such innovative sectors, able to activate both downstream and upstream knowledge interactions, will display higher levels of innovative performance than other systems where innovative sectors are either weak or poorly connected to the rest of the system. The composition of the system in terms of distribution of industrial sectors and the architecture of the links play a crucial role in assessing the innovative output of an economic system and its better performance with respect to alternative systems. Consequently, the differences in sectoral architectures between economic systems explain the differentiated impact of the competent demand.

In this context, the levels of trade openness play an important role. A large empirical literature has provided reliable evidence on the strong, positive and direct relationship between the levels of openness to trade and the levels of competence (Wagner, 2007; Lileeva and Trefler, 2010); Lööf, Nabavi Larijani, Cook, Johansson, 2015). Sectors with large shares of imports have higher chances to interact with suppliers of international quality and hence to increase their own levels of competence. High shares of exports on total output are not only a clear proxy of the high levels of competence, but also a reliable measure of the opportunity to increase competence for the higher chances to interact with high quality users, and imitate from high quality rivals. Trade openness -typically measured by the share of the sum of exports (E) and imports (I) to output (Y) (E+I/Y) - is itself a relevant aspect of the sectoral architecture of an economic system. Consequently, downstream sectors involved in international trade can be expected to increase their competence. It remains, however, unsure, whether this competence will be transmitted to the upstream suppliers. In principle, one cannot exclude that, having broader options to choose between domestic and foreign

(9)

supplier, the domestic downstream customers will opt more intensively for relations with more efficient foreign suppliers. The consequence would be that the increased competence would not necessarily benefit domestic suppliers. The verification of the direction of influence remains thus an empirical issue.

Building upon these arguments, in the rest of the paper we explore the relevance and magnitude of the downstream-to-upstream linkages. Precisely, we analyze the effects of the demand directed from downstream users, according to their own levels of technological advance and competence, to their upstream suppliers. We expect that the larger the derived and competent demand by advanced users, the larger are the opportunities and the incentives to introduce technological innovations in upstream sectors. The rate of introduction and adoption of technological innovations, as proxied by the rate of increase of total factor productivity of a system, are larger: a) the higher the downstream Leontief coefficients that link each sector to the others, i.e. to the extent to which each sector receives its derived demand from all the others that are part of the economic system, taking into account b) the downstream rates of introduction and adoption of technological innovations. Given that the strength of the impact of the demand impulses originated by downstream sectors depends on the intensity of their competence, for economic systems characterized by higher sectoral intensity of technological competencies, the demand impact on the upstream producers will be more significant. For the same token, we also explore the effects of the openness to trade of the different economic systems considered. Here, along the lines explained above, the direction of impact is a priori uncertain.

3 Empirical model

To grasp the effects of inter-industrial competent demand influences requires an empirical design accounting for the simultaneous role of both transactions and interactions. The analysis of the input-output context is a crucial source of valuable information on inter-sectoral flows of intermediate goods. However, as it has been discussed in the previous section, the transactions alone do not deliver insights on productivity influence stemming from them. For that reason, for each transaction between an upstream producer and a downstream user, as documented in the input-output tables, we match the productivity performance of the user. In what follows, we illustrate this process in more details.

Input-output framework and knowledge-based inter-sectoral transactions

Given input-output tables for country g and time t, let’s define matrix

(10)

Ag ,t=Cg ,t

(

^Xg , t

)

−1

also Ag ,txg , t=cg ,t(1)

where cg , t is the vector of total intermediate inputs supplied by each row sector and

(

^Xg ,t

)

−1 is the diagonal matrix of total sectoral output represented in a column vector xg ,t . Each element of matrix Ag ,t , given by aij , g ,t , expresses direct requirements of intermediate goods that sector i demands from sector j relative to total output of j (i, j=1, …, N).2

From the input-output model - describing for each row sector the distribution of its total output between the intermediate and final uses - we have:

cg , t+yg ,t=xg ,t (2) with yg , t being the vector of final demand. Substituting for cg , t an adequate expression from equation (1), we have

Ag ,txg , t+yg ,t=xg ,t (3) that, after simple matrix algebra, gives

Bg , tyg ,t=xg ,t. (4) Matrix Bg , t is called Leontief’s inverse matrix, in which each single element, bij , g ,t , describes direct and indirect requirements that industry i demands from industry j in order to

produce one additional unit of goods in industry i going to final demand. This matrix, thus,

describes the full spectrum of market-based bi-directional relative transactions between using and

producing sectors. Among such transactions, we focus on those going from each producer to the

respective users. Moreover, we are interested in transactions that are accompanied by productivity

improvements. For that reason, for each row sector from the input-output tables, we construct a

vector rj , g ,t as follows

rj , g ,t=bj ,g ,tpg , t (5) where bi , g ,t is a transpose vector of the j-th row vector from matrix Bg , t and pg , t is a vector of sectoral productivity growth rates.3 Each element of vector r

j , g ,t expresses direct and indirect relative intermediate demand for inputs offered by j to all the sectors in the national system,

2 We apply standard notation, according to which matrices are in bold and with capital letters, whereas scalar and vector variables are in italics and lower-cases letters. Moreover, matrix and vector components are in lower-cases italic letters.

3 Expressed as a row vectors, we have b 'j , g ,t=

[

bj 1 ,g , t… bij ,g ,t… bjN ,g ,t

]

and p'g , t =

(11)

matched with the productivity increases experienced by the using sectors. This vector enables to operationalize the recombinant generation of technological knowledge where external knowledge contributes the generation of new knowledge and the eventual introduction of productivity-enhancing innovations. This vector constitutes the central part of the estimating equation, as shown below.

Finally, along the entire empirical procedure, as a measure of sector-level productivity growth we use the logarithmic growth rate of TFP. With this measure, which adopts the standard growth accounting framework based on a constant returns Cobb-Douglas production function, we follow Jorgenson and Griliches (1967) and Jorgenson et al. (1987). The functional form of the TFP growth rate is given by ∆ lnTFPi , g ,t=∆ ln xi , g ,t− ´αi , g ,t k ∆ ln ki , g ,t−´αi, g , t l ∆ ln li , g ,t− ´αi ,g ,t c ∆ ln ci , g ,t(6)

where xi ,g , t is total output of sector i in country g at time t, ki , g ,t is sectoral capital stock, li,g,t is labour force measured in terms of total employment and ci,g,t expresses intermediate inputs. Moreover, ´αi ,g , tf where f = (k, l, c) denotes the two-period average share of factor f over the nominal output defined as follows:

´ αi ,g, tf =

(

αi , g ,f (t −1) +αi , g , tf

)

2 (7) whereas αi ,g , t l =li , g ,t xi , g ,t ;αi , g , t c =ci , g , t xi , g ,t and αi , g ,t k =1−αi , g ,t lαi ,g ,tc . (8) The model

Given such knowledge-based inter-sectoral transactions-cum-interactions and their influence on productivity growth upstream, the dynamic panel model to estimate assumes the following form:

∆ lnTFPj , g ,t=β1+β2∆ lnTFPj , g , t−1+β3 ' rj , g ,t+β4 ' zj ,g ,t+γg+δj+μt+εj , g ,t ∆ lnTFPikt=β1+β2∆ lnTFPikt−1+β3 ' Rikt+β4 ' Zikt+γk+δi+μt+εikt (9)

where β1 is a constant, ∆ lnTFPj , g ,t −1 ∆ ln TFPikt −1 is the lagged dependent variable referring to sector ij country g and time t, γg γk , δj and μt are the country, sector and time specific effects, respectively, and εj , g ,t εigt εjkt is the idiosyncratic error term. Vector rj , g ,t rigt Rikt includes explanatory variables measuring the productivity-enhanced demand-side influence. In particular, each of the 19 variables in vector rj , g ,t rigt refers to each pair ij, where i refers to single manufacturing and service sector, going from “food” to “real estate”, and is

(12)

constructed as a product between the corresponding Leontief coefficient bij , g ,t bij ,k , t

(expressing the derived demand – direct and indirect – of intermediate inputs that sector i demands from sector j in order to produce one unit of final demand) and the growth rate of TFP of the corresponding sector i.4 Finally, vector z

j , g ,t Zikt includes four control variables, namely, a variable measuring an average supply-side influence on the productivity growth of sector j deriving from all linkages that this sector maintains with its suppliers by means of intermediate inputs transactions, in addition to sectoral unit wages, sector-level final demand and sector-level R&D expenditures as a percentage of sectoral output.5 Regarding the variable expressing the average

influence coming from the supply-side, its inclusion is motivated by the necessity to account for both the demand- and supply-side effects in a unique framework. We have already discussed this hypothesis in the previous section. Moreover, it has been confirmed in the past empirical investigations, for instance, by Mowery and Rosenberg (1979) and more recently by Arthur (2007). Finally, the inclusion of sectoral unit wages, of sector-specific final demand and of the R&D variable should separate their possible influence on the TFP growth from the demand-pulling effect, on which we focus.

4 Data source and description

The estimation of the general model presented in equation (9) refers to an unbalanced panel of 19 manufacturing and service sectors in 15 EU countries, observed over the period 1995-2007.6 In

particular, to the extent to which data availability permits us, we include both the old and the new EU member states. Given that we are interested in differences in the relative importance of single sectors within the EU, we estimated equation (9) separately for three groups of countries. More precisely, we split our sample of 15 countries into core EU, East and South.7 This distinction is

4 For a full list of sectors taken under analysis, see Appendix A.1.

5 The method used to construct the variable expressing an average supply-side influence has been described in Appendix A.2.

6 It should be noted that the conceptual discussion was referring to individual level of users and producers, whereas our empirical analysis is based on sector-level data. Nevertheless, the inter-sectoral linkages and knowledge-based interactions fully reflect the entire context of the competent demand pull hypothesis described in Section 2. We are thankful for this comment to one of our referees.

7 The core EU is composed by Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Netherlands, Sweden and the UK. South refers to the three Mediterranean economies, i.e. Italy, Portugal and Spain. Finally, due to the data limitations, to the group of East belong only three countries, namely, the Czech Republic, Hungary and Slovakia. Consequently, the largest eastern European economy, Poland, is not included, so that the conclusions over East should be interpreted with caution. It can be argued that within the group of the core

(13)

reasonable based on the observation of differences in the TFP dynamics between these country groups, as discussed below.

Annual input-output tables, used to calculate the inverse Leontief matrices, have been taken from World Input-Output Database (WIOD). The rest of the data necessary to calculate the logarithmic growth rate of TFP as well as the sector-specific unit wage come from OECD STAN database.

Regarding the calculation of TFP growth rates, the time series of capital were missing in some countries. In such a case, we calculated the time series of capital implementing data on sectoral investment and using the perpetual inventory method.

Summarizing the outcomes of the calculation of TFP, by considering the averages for three country groups, a rather clear picture emerges. In Figure 1 we plot the annual growth rates of aggregated TFP for East, South and EU core in the entire analysed period 1995-2007. A clearly and distinguishing positive development could be observed for East, especially after 1998, thus, after the impact from the post-transition recession broadly expired. Despite periods of lower TFP growth rates, an increasing tendency over the whole analysed time span can be observed.

Both the EU core and South were performing worse than East, with periods of positive and negative TFP growth rates. Nevertheless, it seems that at least since 1998, thus, corresponding to the eve of the Eurozone, the developments in those groups of countries were remarkably diverging, with the core EU reaching positive TFP growth rates in some years, whereas South was reporting negative growth rates at least between 1998 and 2006. This short analysis sufficiently justifies our choice of country groups. Indeed, it allows us to account for the within-EU heterogeneity, in order to compare their respective industrial performances in terms of demand pulling influences.

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 -0.03 -0.02 -0.01 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.03

East South EU core

EU might be further distinguished between Northern EU countries and the rest core. We tried also this combination, but the estimation results did not change considerably.

(14)

Figure 1 TFP annual growth rates in the EU country groupings, averaged over the manufacturing and service sectors.

Source: Own calculations based on OECD STAN database.

Finally, Table 1 shows summary statistics of the variables included in the estimations. The statistics for TFP growth rates are comparable between country groups. However, the average growth rate of TFP for South reports a negative sign, broadly in line with the picture shown in Figure 1. A similar observation regards the remaining sectoral variables.

Table 1 Descriptive statistics

EU core East South

Obs. Mean St. dev. Obs. Mean St. dev. Obs. Mean St. dev.

tfp 2887 0.0003 0.035 850 0.0118 0.048 783 -0.005 0.046 food 2900 0.0001 0.004 850 0.0003 0.012 800 -0.0001 0.010 textiles 2900 0.0001 0.004 850 0.00002 0.006 800 0.0001 0.009 wood 2900 -0.0011 0.006 850 0.0015 0.012 800 -0.003 0.011 paper 2900 0.00004 0.006 850 0.0008 0.008 800 -0.0001 0.007 chemicals 2900 0.0003 0.014 850 -0.0004 0.010 800 -0.0011 0.017

rubber & plastic 2900 0.0003 0.008 850 0.0013 0.009 800 -0.0001 0.008

other non met. 2900 0.0001 0.005 850 0.0011 0.008 800 0.0001 0.008

basic met. 2900 0.0002 0.006 850 0.0008 0.008 800 -0.0011 0.019

mach. &equip. 2900 0.0003 0.006 850 0.0008 0.008 800 0.0001 0.009

electr. equip. 2900 0.0003 0.012 850 0.0016 0.011 800 0.0001 0.011

trans. equip. 2900 0.0001 0.014 850 0.0012 0.009 800 0.0002 0.020

manuf nec 2900 -0.0001 0.006 850 0.0009 0.009 800 -0.0001 0.007

electr, gas & wat. 2900 0.0003 0.008 850 -0.0001 0.013 775 -0.0004 0.009

construction 2900 -0.0004 0.005 850 0.0002 0.012 775 -0.0006 0.014

wholesale 2900 0.0003 0.005 850 0.0018 0.009 775 -0.0005 0.004

hotels & restaur. 2900 -0.0007 0.009 850 -0.0013 0.013 775 -0.0006 0.004

transport 2900 0.0004 0.006 850 0.0010 0.008 775 -0.0003 0.006

finance 2900 0.0005 0.010 850 0.0010 0.015 775 -0.0002 0.010

real esate 2900 0.0003 0.005 850 0.0014 0.010 775 0.0006 0.007

5 Estimation strategy and results

Our empirical strategy consists in two steps. In the first step, we consider the model in equation (9) and apply standard econometric techniques on it. In the second step, we use the results obtained in the first step and transform them into ratios expressing the relative importance of each sector in a

(15)

given context. We repeat the same procedure for three distinct groups of countries, the core EU, East and South.

We estimate the model presented in equation (9) according to the system GMM method by Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998). This method appears to be particularly attractive in our context, in which we are focusing on the contemporaneous external effects between sectors, yet some endogeneity concerns exist. Their methodology is based on a system of two equations. The first one is a difference equation, in which variables expressed as first-differences are instrumented with theirs lagged levels. The second one is the equation with variables in levels instrumented with their own lagged first-differences. To be valid, the following assumptions need to hold: E

[

d

(

TFPj , g , 1

)

εj , g ,t

]

= E

[

rni 1εj , g , t

]

= E

[

z1tmεj , g , t

]

=0, ∀ m, n and t= 2, …, T E

[

∆ d

(

TFPj ,g ,2

) (

γg+δj

)

]

=E

[

∆ rj 2 n

(

γg+δj

)

]

=E

[

∆ z2 t m

(

γg+δj

)

]

=0,∀ m , n∧t=2, …, T

where n ∈{1 … N} is the number of variables in vector rj , g ,t rigt and m∈{1… M} is the number of control variables in vector z.

The results from the estimations regarding our three country groups signal the relevant role played in the sector-level productivity growth of the system as a whole by the demand-driven influence coming from the intermediate users. Indeed, highly significant coefficients in all three columns in Table 2 express the positive impact of sectors – seen in their quality of intermediate customers – on the productivity growth of their upstream suppliers. This confirms our considerations concerning the new formulation of the demand-pull hypothesis. Indeed, according to our results, the positive influence on the system’s dynamic efficiency crucially depends on the availability of knowledge interactions - as carriers of pecuniary knowledge externalities - associated with the flows of transactions that relate each upstream supplier to the derived demand of sophisticated downstream users. Such externalities take place when downstream sophisticated customers transmit their creative ideas to upstream suppliers and stimulate in that way suppliers’ innovative activity. The capability of a system to introduce and adopt timely technological innovations is influenced not only by the internal efforts to generate new technological knowledge, but also and most effectively, by the amount of external knowledge that flows between the sectors of the system, taking into account the strength of their links, as measured by the Leontief coefficients.8

Table 2 Estimation results according to system GMM method.

EU core East South

(16)

l.tfp -0.072 -0.147 -0.067 (0.041)* (0.148) (0.044) food 0.703 0.131 0.668 (0.077)*** (0.251) (0.196)** textiles 0.924 0.856 0.711 (0.032)*** (0.119)*** (0.085)*** wood 0.815 0.723 0.669 (0.068)*** (0.082)*** (0.073)*** paper 0.794 0.583 0.687 (0.060)*** (0.119)*** (0.065)*** chemicals 0.804 0.669 0.741 (0.084)*** (0.119)*** (0.136)***

rubber & plastic 0.967 0.746 0.687

(0.053)*** (0.093)*** (0.065)***

other non metallic min 0.802 0.758 0.776

(0.087)*** (0.118)*** (0.059)***

basic metals 0.617 0.485 0.451

(0.082)*** (0.120)*** (0.093)***

machinery & equip 0.928 0.715 0.554

(0.040)*** (0.093)*** (0.115)*** electr equip 0.793 0.722 0.606 (0.081)*** (0.130)*** (0.096)*** transp equip 0.810 0.524 0.628 (0.106)*** (0.233)** (0.180)** manuf nec 0.874 0.734 0.499 (0.041)*** (0.113)*** (0.192)*** electr, gas & water sup 0.693 0.522 0.680

(0.053)*** (0.113)*** (0.119)***

contruction 0.620 0.432 0.294

(0.170)*** (0.188)** (0.437)

wholesale 0.725 0.527 0.477

(0.111)*** (0.193)** (0.337)

hotels & restaur 0.648 0.945 0.481

(0.149)*** (0.097)*** (0.408)

transport & comm 0.558 0.136 0.623

(0.119)*** (0.316) (0.194)*** finance 0.600 0.719 0.738 (0.101)*** (0.083)*** (0.096)*** real estate 0.341 0.259 0.435 (0.278) (0.367) (0.451) N. obs. 1763 774 709 Sargan 0.763 0.999 0.998 Arellano-Bond 0.243 0.361 0.447

Note: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. Standard errors in parenthesis. The number of instruments has been collapsed as otherwise too many instruments (with respect to the number of groups) would create the risk on the validity of the results.

These results are also in line with the version of the life cycle theory elaborated by Malerba et al. (2003) that stresses the role played by the dynamics on the demand-side. According to this hypothesis, the bulk of network and bandwagon effects on the demand side push users to concentrate on a particular design and develop a minimum threshold to motivate the suppliers to stick to it in order to remain on the market.

But the demand-side life cycle theory is even more insightful for our purposes, as it focuses on heterogeneity conditions intrinsic in every industrial structure and resulting in dynamics

(17)

regarding the relative importance of sectors both over time and across industrial structures. Within a certain industrial context, a sector that in a given period of time acquired dominating importance in shaping the design and the speed of sectoral transformation could be able to maintain its position in the next period as well, but it could also fail to do this if the demand intensity and dynamics related to some other sector successfully enters the picture. Similarly, the differences existing across industrial systems in the same period derive from different relative strength that each sector is able to establish, based on customers’ internal characteristics and market mechanisms put on their disposition. From this viewpoint, our results confirm and generalize at the same time the microeconomic evidence from high tech industries such as semiconductors (Fontana and Malerba, 2010).

This is confirmed in the results shown in Table 3 and illustrated in Figure 2. These ratios have been obtained based on the estimation coefficients seen in Table 1, by taking as reference for each country group the highest coefficient and calculating, for the remaining sectors, the ratios between their respective estimation coefficients and the coefficient of the reference sector. In that way, we obtained a relative classification of sectors, where the highest the ratio, the strongest the demand-side influence of the sector on the productivity dynamics of the rest of the system. This procedure permits us to go beyond the sole confirmation of the substantial role played by demand-side influence in spurring productivity dynamics of the system, as seen in Table 2. Indeed, here we are able to observe and comment on the ‘quality’ of the sectoral architectures of the different systems so as to appreciate whether certain industrial structures with sectors connected with more or less remarkable inter-sectoral linkages are able to experience higher levels of technological congruence and exert larger positive effects on the general increase of total factor productivity at the system level.

Regarding the sectoral architecture within each country group, in the EU core the dominating position in the analysed period has been assumed by rubber and plastic products, followed by machinery and equipment; textile and textiles products, as well as all the remaining manufacturing sectors. These manufacturing sectors have been able to activate a sophisticated demand of intermediary inputs that pushed and helped upstream suppliers to introduce technological innovations. All the service sectors, instead, were playing relatively weaker influence in this system of demand-driven productivity growth.

Table 3 Relative importance of sectors in the transmission of demand-driven pecuniary knowledge externalities

(18)

food 0.727 0.139 0.861

textiles 0.956 0.906 0.916

wood 0.843 0.765 0.862

paper 0.821 0.617 0.885

chemicals 0.831 0.708 0.955

rubber & plastic 1.000 0.789 0.885

other non-metallic min 0.829 0.802 1.000

basic metals 0.638 0.513 0.581

machinery & equip 0.960 0.757 0.714

electr equip 0.820 0.764 0.781

transp equip 0.838 0.554 0.809

manuf nec 0.904 0.777 0.643

electr, gas & water sup 0.717 0.552 0.876

contruction 0.641 0.457 0.379

wholesale 0.750 0.558 0.615

hotels & restaur 0.670 1.000 0.620

transport & comm 0.577 0.144 0.803

finance 0.620 0.761 0.951

real estate 0.353 0.274 0.561

Note: The sector with the highest coefficient reported in Table 1 has been taken as the reference sector; its coefficient is equal to 1. For the remaining sectors, the values express the ratio between their own estimation coefficients and the coefficient of the reference sector. Ratios in grey refer to sectors for which the estimation results were statistically insignificant.

Quite a different picture is found for South, where a relevant influence has been exercised by financial intermediation and transport and communication services. The most effective manufacturing sector in this country group is the other nonmetallic mineral products.

Finally, the group of Eastern European EU members was characterized by the most incisive influence coming from hotels and restaurants services, closely followed by textiles and textile products. Distinguishing in this country group is the relatively weaker impact coming from the remaining manufacturing sectors than it was the case both in South and even more in the EU core.

The results of the horizontal comparison suggest that EU core countries are much more able to benefit from the spillovers than the members of the Southern and Eastern European peripheries. This asymmetric evidence confirms that the re-organization of the intra-European value chains privileges the core countries that are able to specialize in the segments of the production process where innovation activities concentrate (OECD, 2014). This has strong negative implications for long-term cohesion of the Eurozone.

The vertical comparison of the results shows that the manufacturing sectors were on average more effective than services in generating a positive demand side influence. The only exception

(19)

from this rule among manufacturing sectors constitutes basic metal sector, as well as electricity, gas and water supply; hotels and restaurants and financial intermediation within services. Regarding the latter, this result is in line with several theoretical contributions on the positive effects of the reduction of agency concerns and information asymmetries that impede the financing of radical technological changes (King and Levine, 1993; Galetovic, 1996; Blackburn and Hung, 1998; Morales, 2003; Acemoglu, Aghion, and Zilibotti, 2003).9 Such theoretical findings were confirmed

in the empirical investigations pointing on the crucial link between the improvements in the financial systems and technological development. This evidence might be found in historically distant events, as for instance in the case of the establishment of specialized investment banks and of improved accounting systems that reduced the short-termism of firms and supported the financing of the construction of railroad infrastructure in 19th and 20th century (Baskin and Miranti,

1997; Allen and Gale, 1994; Tufano, 2003; Frame and White, 2004).

The case of the energy sector has been also extensively discussed in the past literature. There is a well-established, even though almost implicit, convincement that energy-related innovations play a crucial role in economic growth. Indeed, most probably due to its abundance and at the same time low relative share of energy costs over the total production costs, the theoretical analyses around the endogenous growth do not include energy as an input of production. An exception here is the work by Stern and Kander (2012), who construct a simple extension of the Solow model of growth with the energy factor and, additionally, confirm that the expansion of energy services contributed to the explanation of long-run growth in Sweden.

Among manufacturing sectors that contributed a lot to the positive demand-side influence on productivity dynamics upstream, textiles and textile products assume an important role. This effect might be better understood in the light of the recent developments leading to the successful and efficiency-enhancing establishment of industrial districts covering the traditional EU manufacturing sectors, among which textile sector as well. The so called “district effect”, combined with the generation of innovative textile products, permitted to achieve a better diversification of production towards high value-added product lines (Nassimbeni, 2003; Dunford, 2006; Puig et al., 2009).

The evidence regarding chemicals and also rubber and plastic products confirms the role of the sector as being continuously involved in the search for new feedstocks in the economic system 9 Apart from contributions supporting the view of a great role played by financial innovation for economic growth, there are also other theoretical views arguing that this influence might be negative. In particular, Gennaioli et al. (2012) argue that in a context where investors neglect small risks, financial innovation might result in financial and economic instabilities. Moreover, Shleifer and Vishny (2010) find out that financial innovation accompanied with biased expectations of investors or excessive institutional constraints might be detrimental for economic development.

(20)

at large.10 An exemplary case of the change in the feedstock is given by switching from coal to oil

and gas in the production of synthetic fibers and plastic products in the US already before World War II.11

The horizontal comparison of the standardized results at the sector level is quite interesting as well. Food has a strong effect in the EU core and the South while it does not provide strong effects in the East. Textiles exert a strong positive effect in the three blocks. The strong results of wood are homogeneous across the three blocks. Paper has stronger effects in the EU core and in the South than in the East. Chemicals exert very strong effects in the South and in the EU core, but to a lesser extent in the East. Rubber and plastic is the strongest sector in the EU core where it peaks, but is less effective in the South and in the East. Other-non-metallic minerals have a strong role in the South where it peaks, but quite a weaker one in the EU core and in the East. Basic metals effects are stronger in the EU core than in the South and the East. Machinery and equipment exert a very strong role in the EU core, but a weaker one in the South and in the East. Similarly, electrical machinery has a more powerful effect in the EU core than elsewhere. Transportation equipment has a pulling role in the EU core and in the South but much less so in the East. Manufacturing-not-elsewhere-classified has the expected strong role in the EU core, but a weaker one in the rest of Europe. Electricity-gas-water-supply has a strong role in the South, a slightly weaker in EU core and a weak one in the East. Construction is very effective in the EU core and very weak in the South. Wholesale is very effective in the EU core and much weaker in the rest of Europe. Hotels-and-restaurant has a surprising strong role in the East where it ranks first but exerts much lower pulling effects in the rest of Europe. Transportation and communication services have powerful effects in the South, but negligible effects in the East. Finally financial intermediation is very effective in the South and less effective both in the East and in the EU core.

10 According to Davis Landes (1969:269), chemical industry is the most “miscellaneous of industries”, encompassing synthetic fibers, plastics, agricultural pesticides and fertilizers, food additives, health and beauty aids, and many other products and production components.

11 For a detailed description of the case and for an extensive discussion of the role of chemical innovation for economic growth, see Arora and Gambarella, 2010.

(21)

foo d text les wo od pap er chem ical s rub b. & pla stc oth er n n m et. m in. bas ic m et mac hin . & eq uip . elec tr. e qu ip tran sp. e qu ip man uf. n ec elec tr, g as & wat . con tru cto n wh ole sale ho tels & r esta ur. tran sp. & co mm . fnan ce real est ate 0.000 0.200 0.400 0.600 0.800 1.000

EU core East South

Figure 2 Relative importance of sectors in the transmission of demand-driven pecuniary knowledge externalities

Based on the same results, Figure 2 illustrates differences between the relative demand-side influences of the sectors observable across country groups. Generally, a certain pattern can be recognized that divides East from the other two country groups, EU core and South. Indeed, the latter two groups exhibit more homogenous industrial structures with respect to East. This is particularly true for food, beverages and tobacco; pulp, paper and paper products; chemicals and chemical products; transport equipment; hotels and restaurant service and transport and communication. For the remaining sectors the pattern is much less clear. Indeed, in some cases, East and South seem to show more common characteristics (machinery and equipment; construction; wholesale and retail trade). In some other cases, Eastern European structure is much closer to the one in the core EU (other nonmetallic mineral products; real estate). Finally, in the case of textiles and textile products; wood and products of wood; and electrical equipment all three-country groups seem to belong together.

The fact that we classify our country sample in three country groups permits us to investigate regional differences in the economic importance of a certain sectoral architecture. In this sense, the geographic dimension is exogenously determined. An interesting exercise would be to endogenize the space variable with the aim to establish the geographic extension of the demand-driven productivity impact between sectors located in different regions. This could be made by considering the global input-output tables and, thus, the international flows of intermediate inputs between sectors located in different countries. On the contrary, given that we dispose of national and not

(22)

regional input-output tables, we are not able to detect the strength and the spatial distance within which cross-sectoral knowledge spillovers occur.12

Reassuming, with respect to the appreciation of the sectoral architecture, these results seem to confirm, on the one hand, that each country group exhibits specific characteristics of their sectoral architectures, on the other hand, however, that the architectures of the EU core and South (both old EU members groups) are closer together and further from the structure observed in East.

Our results confirm that the sophisticated procurement of downstream users has important effects on the technological capacity of upstream suppliers. The sophisticated procurement is able to pull innovation upstream both via the traditional loop that relates the extent of the market to the levels of specialization and focused learning processes and by means of the provision from the bottom of knowledge externalities.

These results are quite important from a theoretical viewpoint because they provide empirical support to the hypothesis that knowledge externalities originated downstream do affect the technological capacity of upstream suppliers. This ‘second’ bottom-up mechanism is quite distinct from the top-down flow that received more attention in the literature. According to our results its effects are important enough to deserve a wider attention.

6 The role of openness to trade

The previous estimation framework tackled differences in the transmission of competent demand influences deriving from purely domestic inter-sectoral relations. It is, nevertheless, crucial to account for a possible international dimension of such relations, stemming from the fact that competent customers are usually involved in industrial relations with supplying sectors located abroad. Nevertheless, the direction of impact in this case is a priori uncertain. If through international relations domestic customers are able to increase their competences and efficiently transmit them to the benefit of the domestic producers, the positive impact of competent demand should be reinforced. At the same time, however, the increase in competences due to activity with abroad does not necessarily need to translate into more efficient domestic outcome of suppliers, who, under circumstances of tough international competition could be negatively hit.

To account for such effects due to international exposure, the previously used sector-level explanatory variables are now augmented by a factor expressing the degree of openness to international trade of each of the downstream sector i. As a measure of openness to trade, we take

12 A prominent attempt in this direction has been offered by Bottazzi and Peri (2003) who base their estimates of knowledge spillovers in Europe on European patent data. They find that the spillovers are very localized and exist only within a distance of 300 km.

(23)

the share of the sum of imports and exports of each sector i over the sector’s output. Thus the new covariates measure the influence of the competent demand in an open economy context.

The results of the estimations are summarized in Table 4. The picture that emerges is quite complex, but some general conclusions can be drawn. First, across the three country groups trade openness is an important factor strengthening the impact of the competent demand only in some sectors. Especially in case of manufacturing sectors the impact of international trade flows seems to be positive, as the evidence for textiles and textile products, wood and products of wood, paper and paper products, rubber and plastic products, machinery and equipment, and among services for financial intermediation confirms.

Table 4 Estimation results with covariates accounting for international trade.

EU core East South

l.tfp -0.007 -0.145 -0.004 (0.051) (0.106) (0.044) food 0.050 0.053 0.009 (0.037) (0.304) (0.029) textiles 1.761 3.535 0.254 (0.653)*** (1.464)*** (0.863) wood 0.154 0.185 0.425 (0.046)*** (0.280) (0.147)*** paper 0.350 0.783 0.456 (0.075)*** (0.488) (0.169)*** chemicals 0.007 0.217 0.006 (0.004)** (0.131)* (0.014)

rubber & plastic 1.098 0.812 1.242

(0.505)** (0.558) (0.226)***

other non metallic min 0.642 0.669 1.387

(0.337)* (0.265)** (0.926)

basic metals 0.004 -0.085 0.030

(0.015) (0.044)* (0.007)***

machinery & equip 0.068 0.159 0.100

(0.029)** (0.172) (0.013)*** electr equip 0.015 -0.107 0.062 (0.017) (0.061)* (0.024)** transp equip 0.033 -0.361 0.003 (0.047) (0.079)*** (0.014) manuf nec 0.191 0.348 0.078 (0.077)** (0.238) (0.060)

electr, gas & water sup 0.172 0.144 0.474

(0.095)* (0.149) (0.128)***

contruction -0.003 -0.189 -0.045

(0.015) (0.129) (0.010)***

wholesale -0.009 -0.763 -0.106

(0.035) (0.339)** (0.066)

hotels & restaur 0.137 0.951 -0.100

(0.121) (0.724) (0.035)***

transport & comm 0.006 -0.083 -0.002

(0.008) (0.064) (0.009) finance 0.003 0.168 0.022 (0.005) (0.085)** (0.010)** real estate -0.013 -0.269 -0.058 (0.015) (0.124)** (0.018)** N. obs. 1763 774 709 Sargan 0.508 0.305 0.630

(24)

Arellano-Bond 0.067 0.954 0.982

Note: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. Standard errors in parenthesis. The number of instruments has been collapsed as otherwise too many instruments (with respect to the number of groups) would create the risk on the validity of the results.

Also important is the comparison between the three sectoral architectures. It emerges with clearness that the productivity-increasing effects of competent and internationally involved downstream customers are stronger in EU core – a group with the most dynamic performance in terms of productivity growth. In the two other groups, which experienced much weaker productivity growth over the observed period, the positive demand impact from competent and internationally involved customers on upstream productivity growth was less incisive and in some cases even negative, as the result for real estate clearly confirms.

All in all, these results suggest that the impact of openness to trade is far from certain. It is positive and strong for manufacturing and in more advanced and mature sectoral architectures, but less so for services and in sectoral contexts characterized by a lower degree of technological advance. These results suggest that in EU core countries demand impulses do benefit more upstream producers the stronger is the openness. Here openness to trade exerts a positive impact as it enhances the competence of users. In the two other groups, instead, domestic demand impulses coming from downstream users exposed to international trade may risk to favor productivity growth in exporting countries. These results do confirm how important is the sectoral architecture of the system in shaping the ultimate effects of demand pull.

7 Conclusions and Policy Implications

This paper has empirically appreciated the systemic character of innovative performances, highlighting the crucial role of knowledge externalities that contribute the demand-driven innovation process. The generation of technological knowledge and the consequent introduction and adoption of technological innovations do not take place in isolation. Innovators rely on each other in accessing the collective pools of technological knowledge that become available because of its limited appropriability. The mechanisms by means of which external knowledge actually spills and can be accessed, however, are quite sophisticated: knowledge does not spill freely and everywhere. Dedicated interactions are necessary for knowledge to actually spill from its originator so as to be used by third parties. User-producer interactions play a central role in this context. Economic transactions are the most effective carriers of knowledge interactions and enable customers and suppliers to share and access the knowledge base of the products being traded. Although some

(25)

knowledge interactions may take place without actual exchanges of goods or services, the bulk of knowledge interactions are likely to take place jointly with transactions.

The identification of the flows of goods among industrial and service sectors – made possible by input-output tables that track the derived demand of both capital goods and intermediary inputs-weighted by the levels of technological advance of each demanding sector, provides a unique – if not exclusive - map of the actual flows of knowledge spillovers based upon knowledge interactions taking place in an economic system. This procedure has two important merits. First it has made possible the inclusion in the analysis of the role of the derived demand of intermediary inputs next to that of capital goods, introducing a significant shift in the object of analysis of the demand pull approach that differs both from the Kaldorian emphasis on the final and aggregate demand and on the analysis of the role of the demand for capital goods implemented by Schmookler. Second it enabled to distinguish two separate mechanisms of dissemination of knowledge externalities generated by means of knowledge interactions: A) the top-down flows of knowledge spillovers that take place from the suppliers of goods that embody technological advances to their customers, B) the bottom-up flows of knowledge spillovers that take place from sophisticated and competent customers to their suppliers. This paper concentrates the analysis on the latter. The empirical analysis of this mechanism has enabled to appreciate the effects of a competent demand-pull hypothesis, where the rate of technological advance of a sector is positively influenced by the extent to which it is the recipient of the derived demand of advanced customers. The results confirm that the rate of total factor productivity of upstream sectors is strongly and positively influenced by the relative strength of the competent demand originated from the downstream sectors, according to their own levels of technological advance.

These results reinforce the strong systemic character of the innovation process identified by Schumpeter (1947). Innovation is the result of the creative reaction to the mismatches between expected and actual conditions of product and factor markets that can take place only when strong knowledge externalities are available. Innovation can’t take place in isolation because no agent commands all the existing knowledge. Innovation is intrinsically a collective process, where innovative performance of each agent depends upon the amount of external knowledge that can be accessed and used in the recombination knowledge generation process.

This approach contributes the derived demand pull approach providing solid microfoundations that specify the framework elaborated in the line of analysis Verdoorn-Kaldor-Schmookler with the appreciation of the recombinant character of the generation of technological knowledge and of the essential role of external knowledge as a necessary input. This approach enables to better appreciate the specific quality of knowledge interactions that accompany and

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

As clearly illustrated in Fig. 8 , the COD for the reinforced steel plates is significantly lower than the unreinforced one. It is then expected that the crack closure effects are

La cute dei soggetti con assenza e/o presenza di stress psicologico e/o abitudine al fumo e con fotoesposizione media gruppi V, VI, VII, VIII evidenzia una notevole riduzione

Il diabete ad eredità matrilineare che si associa a sordità neurosensoriale (Maternally Inherited Diabetes and Deafness (MIDD)) è una rara forma di diabete dovuta alla mutazione

Andrea D’Onofrio (Università di Napoli Federico II) I profughi tedeschi tra fughe e migrazioni forzate, nel

In addition, a selection of νμ CC interactions at ND280 is used to constrain the neutrino flux and cross section uncertainties in order to substantially reduce the uncertainties on

The Italian hare populations living in the Central Apennine (i.e. PNM and PNALM areas) share 4 plant families with those from Southern Apennine mountains (i.e. Cilento, Vallo di Diano

According to current ESC guidelines[1], diagnosis of recurrent pericarditis is made in case of: a previous documented episode of acute pericarditis; a symptom-free interval of 4-

In order to remove blood clots from the contralateral ventricle, although contralateral approach through a different burr hole has been described, a standard septostomy can