• Non ci sono risultati.

Cartel Stability, Mark-Up Cyclicality and Government Spending Multipliers

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "Cartel Stability, Mark-Up Cyclicality and Government Spending Multipliers"

Copied!
31
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

Cartel Stability, Mark-Up

Cyclicality and Government

Spending Multipliers

Luca Lambertini

Luigi Marattin

(2)

Cartel Stability, Mark-Up Cyclicality and

Government Spending Multipliers

Luca Lambertini and Luigi Marattin

Department of Economics, University of Bologna

Strada Maggiore 45, 40125 Bologna, Italy

luca.lambertini@unibo.it; luigi.marattin@unibo.it

March 23, 2012

Abstract

Mark-up cyclical behaviour is relevant in determining the size of government spending multiplier on output. While theoretical liter-ature priviliged the counteryclical hypothesis, empirical evidence is far from being conclusive. Based on seminal Rotemberg and Sa-loner (1986) contribution, we build a theoretical framework based on Bertrand duopoly, stochastic demand and product di¤erentiation, where the analysis of cartel stability under partial collusion points towards procyclical pricing. According to the intensity of marginal cost cyclicality, this can produce a procyclical mark up or - at least - render it less countercyclical than expected, with relevant e¤ects on the transmission mechanism of government spending stimuli.

JEL Codes: C73, L13

Keywords: partial collusion, cyclical pricing

We would like to thank Giacomo Calzolari, Paolo Manasse and Antonio Minniti per precious comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.

(3)

1

Introduction

Recent theoretical contributions (Hall, 2009; Woodford, 2011) highlight the importance of price mark-up’s cyclical behaviour for the transmission

mech-anism of …scal policy. Previous literature (Galì et al., 2005; Galì, 2005)

had already stressed that an exogenous reduction in the aggregate ine¢ -ciency wedge (price or wage mark-up) ampli…es the e¤ects of a government

spending stimulus on aggregate demand, and vice versa. However, by

re-lating mark-up movements to the business cycle, it is possible to investigate analytically the relationship between government spending multipliers and the degree of pro/countercyclicality of mark-up. In a stylized sticky prices

macroeconomic model, Hall shows that if we de…ne (y) = y ! as the price

mark-up, and parameter ! indicates the sensitivity to the income level y, then: sign 2 4@ dy dg @! 3 5 = sign (!)

Considering that the government spending multiplier is positive, equation (1) means that if the mark-up is countercyclical (! > 0) then the higher the sensitivity to aggregate demand (! "), the higher the government spending

multiplier dydg " . On the other hand, if mark-up is procyclical (! < 0),

a more pronounced cycle elasticity (! ")lowers the expansionary e¤ects of

government purchases on output dydg # :

What does economic literature have to say about the direction of mark-up cyclicality?

Theoretical literature has mainly focused on countercyclicality,1 by taking

two alternative roads that we could label "the macroeconomic view" and "the industrial organization view".

As to the former, the traditional explanation has centered on nominal rigidities: if prices are sticky, an increase in aggregate demand - assuming

1Lindbeck and Snower (1987) and Bils (1987) achieve mark-up countercyclicality by

es-tablishing a positive relationship between aggregate demand and elasticity of demand. Ed-mond and Veldkamp (2009) assign the central role to income distribution: during booms, income shifts towards the lower tail of the distribution, featured by higher-elasticity

(4)

con-‡exibility of some elements of marginal costs - results in a mark-up reduction (Rotemberg and Woodford 1999, Woodford 2003).

The industrial organization view focuses instead on …rms’ strategic in-teraction in a non-competitive environment. Rotemberg and Saloner (1986) argue that oligopolies are likely to behave more competitively when demand rises, especially when price is the strategic variable. Under these circum-stances, in fact, the bene…t from deviation is larger, and the punishment is diminished because it will be implemented when the expansionary demand shock will have already been absorbed. As a results, price/marginal cost ratio declines as aggregate demand increases. Haltiwanger and Harrington (1991) extend the analysis to allow for time-varying …rms’expectations on future de-mand, by relaxing the assumption of i.i.d. demand shocks so to induce serial correlation in the cycle. They highlight potential asymmetries in collusive pricing behavior across di¤erent state of the business cycle, as their …ndings show that collusion is more di¢ cult during recessions than during booms. In fact, establishing a relation between future and current demand induces asymmetries between the opportunity costs of engaing in price wars accord-ing to the direction of demand. Under fallaccord-ing demand, the forgone collusive pro…ts are on a intertemporally decreasing path, so the incentive to collude is lower and likely to remain so. On the other hand, in a period of increasing demand, the traditional Rotemberg and Saloner result is mitigated by the fact that joint-maximizing pro…ts are going to be higher in the future. Along this path, Bagwell and Staiger (1997) develop a theory of collusive pricing in a framework where aggregate demand alternates stochastically between slow and fast growth states, and where the transition is governed by a Markov process. They …nd that the cyclical behaviour of collusive prices depends cru-cially on correlation of demand growth rates through time and the expected duration of boom and recessions. Particularly, collusive prices are procyclical in presence of positive demand correlation through time, and countercyclical otherwise. Furthermore, the amplitude of the collusive pricing is larger when the recession has a longer expected duration or - conversely- when the boom has a lower lenght. Those two contributions stress that the qualitative and quantitative dimensions of collusive pricing can di¤er according to the state of the business cycle. Such an asymmetry in the intensity of the collusion is directly related to the mark-up cyclical behaviour and thus - as we will argue - to the size of government spending multipliers. Therefore, those results might provide an explanation for multipliers’asymmetries over the business

(5)

cycle (Canzoneri et al., 2011)2.

More recently, a new strand of literature combines traditional general equilibrium macro models with an industrial organization approach, empha-sizing the procyclicality of entry in determining mark-up countercyclicality, through the competition e¤ect (Ghironi and Melitz 2005, Jaimovich and Floetotto 2008, Etro and Colciago 2010)

However, how empirically robust is the evidence about mark-up counter-cyclicality?

Although a considerable number of contributions points towards

coun-tercyclicality,3 empirical literature on mark-up cyclical behaviour is not

un-ambiguous. Donowitz et al. (1986,1988) …nd evidence on procyclicality in the US; Chirinko and Fazzari (1994) use a dynamic factor model to esti-mate markups, …nding that they are procyclical in nine of the eleven 4-digit industries they analyze. Updating Bils (1987) analysis - in favor of counter-cyclicality - with more recent and richer data, Nekarda and Ramey (2010) …nd that all measures of markups are either procylical or acyclical.

Hall (2009) provides a simple …rst-cut test for cyclicality by noting that the mark-up can be expressed as the ratio between the elasticity of output

with respect to labor input @Y@LLY and the share of labor compensation over

nominal income W LP Y = s . In fact, since by the envelope theorem property, a

cost-minimizing …rm equalizes the marginal cost of increasing output across all possible margins for varying production, we can express marginal cost as:

M C = W@Y

@L

(1) As gross mark-up (= ) is de…ned as the ratio between price index and

marginal costs,and multiplying and dividing by Y

L; then: = @Y @L L Y s (2)

2Rotemberg and Woodford (1992) develop the idea of mark-up countercyclicality in

a dynamic general equilibrium setting, …nding that the model’s empirical performances are closer to actual postwar US data than the corresponding predictions of the perfectly competitive model.

(6)

If the production process is approximated by a Cobb-Douglas Y = L K1 ;

then the numerator of (2) is and can be considered relatively stable over

time. Thus, the countercyclicality of the mark-up requires the

procyclical-ity of labor share s:

Figure 1 shows the dynamics of labor share and output in …ve major OECD economies from 1990 to 2009.

(7)
(8)

We can notice that labour share is far from showing an unambigous pro-cyclical behaviour ; table 1 reports a simple correlation analysis showing that - with the exception of US - there seems to be a negative rather than positive correlation between labor share and the business cycle.

Table 1: Correlation between detrendend GDP and labour share

COUNTRY CORRELATION US 0.61 UK 0 FRANCE -0.12 GERMANY -0.52 ITALY -0.49

In this paper, we present a theoretical framework based on strategic in-teraction able to rationalize the existence of pro-cyclical pricing. Our bench-mark model is the one put forward by Rotemberg and Saloner (1986). We indeed set out by o¤ering a brief summary of their analysis, reconstructing the countercyclical behavour of prices in a simple repeated duopoly game with homogeneous goods, in which demand is subject to random shocks a¤ecting the reservation price. In addition to their result, we show that increasing the probability of a positive shock brings about an increase in cartel stability, which could be large enough to more than counterbalance the e¤ect identi-…ed by Rotemberg and Saloner. Then, we review the established IO debate on the behaviour of …rms involved in an implicitly collusive price supergame under product di¤erentiation and perfect certainty, producing well de…ned procyclical conclusions. Our e¤ective contribution consists in bridging the two approaches, pursuing two distinct but related goals: (i) to characterise the maximum degree of collusion (i.e., the highest collusive price) that can be sustained in a stochastic environment, given time preferences and product di¤erentiation; and (ii) to check whether the counterciclity emerging under stochastic demand and perfect product substitutability can indeed be com-patible with the seemingly opposite result produced by the traditional cartel theory belonging to IO, in which much emphasis is posed on product di¤er-entiation but this is accompanied by perfect certainty. Our analysis indeed shows that, provided unilateral deviations grant monopoly power, Rotemberg

(9)

and Saloner’s countercyclical pricing can be seen as the limit of a general model in which, for su¢ ciently high (low) degrees of product di¤erentiation, procyclical (countercyclical) pricing obtains.

The rest of paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 recalls the Rotember and Saloner’s framework, generalized in stochastic demand framework. Sec-tion 3 inserts product di¤erentiaSec-tion and proves that this feature reverts the traditional countercyclical pricing of the benchmank model. In section 4 we provide a framework able to bridge the two positions. Finally, section 5 concludes.

2

Preliminaries: the status-quo.

We set out by brie‡y summarising …rst Rotemberg and Saloner’s (1986) model of countercyclical pricing, and then the features of implicitly collusive pricing in supergame-theoretic models deeply investigated in the industrial organization literature.

2.1

Countercyclical pricing

The following is a simpli…ed version of their setup, in which we will focus on the behaviour of a cartel formed by two (instead of n) …rms, without further

loss of generality.4 As in their paper, we consider a market for a homogenous

good, over an in…nite horizon. Time t is discrete, with t = 0; 1; 2; :::1; and

the demand function at any time t is pt = t q1t q2t;with qit 0being …rm

i’s output. Firms have identical technologies represented by the cost function

Ci = cqi; with t> c 0: To ease the exposition throughout the paper, and

again w.l.o.g., we set c = 0. The pro…t function of the individual …rm thus

coincides with revenues, i = pqi. The reservation price t is stochastic, and

in each period can take one of two values, a > b; with probabilitiesp (a) = m

and p (b) = 1 m; respectively, with m 2 [0; 1] :

The supergame unravels following the rules of Friedman’s (1971) per-fect folk theorem, whereby any unilateral deviation from the collusive path

4This exposition relies on (and slightly generalises) the simpli…ed version of the

(10)

is punished by a permanent reversal to the Nash equilibrium of the con-stituent stage game forever (the so-called grim trigger strategy). In the present setting, product homogeneity entails that the per-period pro…ts at the Bertrand-Nash equilibrium are nil. As in Rotemberg and Saloner (1986), suppose …rms (i) set prices after having observed the state of demand (either

a or b), and (ii) collude at the monopoly price in each period. Later, we will

come to the case of partial collusion.

At any t; monopoly price pMt = t=2 delivers the individual expected

cartel pro…t: E C = m M(a) + (1 m) M(b) 2 = ma2+ (1 m) b2 8 : (3)

If a …rm contemplates the possibility of deviation, the best option is to do so in a period of high demand, so that slightly undercutting the monopoly

price grants the cheating …rms full monopoly pro…ts in that period, D =

a2=4: As already explained above, such deviation at any t is punished by

driving pro…ts to zero from t + 1 to doomsday through the adoption of the marginal cost pricing rule at the Bertrand-Nash equilibrium. Assuming …rms share identical time preferences measured by a symmetric and time-invariant

discount factor 2 (0; 1) ; the stability of price collusion requires to meet

the following necessary and su¢ cient condition:

E C 1 X t=0 t D , a 2[1 (1 + m)] + b2(1 m) 8 (1 ) (4)

which is satis…ed by all

a2 a2(1 + m) + b2(1 m) ; (5) with @ @a = 2ab2(1 m) [a2(1 + m) + b2(1 m)]2 > 08m 2 [0; 1) : (6)

Property (6) indicates that the critical threshold of the discount factor stabil-ising full collusion increases with the good state. This is one of the elements leading to the (by now classical) interpretation of this model, according to which …rms should collude less if demand gets higher, as the size of the mar-ket ensures high pro…ts anyway, and this this suggests the idea of counter-ciclical pricing. This argument is reinforced if one examines the perspective

(11)

of activating some degree of partial collution at the highest pP

2 0; pM

sustainable for < :

All of the above is based on comparative statics taken w.r.t. a. Another possibility (not examined in Rotemberg and Saloner, 1986) is to assess the e¤ect of a change in m on cartel stability:

@

@m =

a2(a b) (a + b)

[a2(1 + m) + b2(1 m)]2 < 08m 2 [0; 1) (7)

revealing that an increase in the probability attached to the good state makes full collusion easier to sustain. This, on the contrary, has a de…nite procycli-cal ‡avour. Moreover, using (6-7), we can construct the marginal rate of substitution between a and m as follows:

da dm = @ @m @a @ = a (a b) (a + b) 2b2(1 m) > 0; (8)

illustrating the complementarity between a and m. Correspondingly,

yields the map appearing in Figure 1, with 1 > 2 > 3: The curves are

upward sloping and convex in m; for all m 2 [0; 1] and a > b: Hence, given any admissible value of m; an increase in a makes it more di¢ cult for …rms to sustain collusion along the frontier of monopoly pro…ts. Conversely, however, given any a > b, an increase in m generates the opposite e¤ect. Overall, the balance between the two may indeed leave the critical threshold unmodi…ed. This suggests that, if probabilities can be generated of at least a¤ected by a policy maker’s announcements, a governement might indeed exploit its own credibility to in‡uence …rms’pricing behaviour in the desired direction.

(12)

Figure 1: The critical discount factor for full collusion in the space (m; a). 6 -1 (b; 0) a m 2 3 1

We may summarise the above exposition into the following:

Lemma 1 Under demand uncertainty and product homogeneity, any positive

shock on demand increasing the level of the reservation price in the best state makes price collusion more di¢ cult to sustain, all else equal.

2.2

Implicit price collusion in oligopoly supergames

The standard approach in industrial organization theory rules out uncer-tainty to focus instead on the bearings of product di¤erentiation on the

in-tensity and stability of implicit collusion.5 Accordingly, we consider a market

where two single-product …rms o¤er di¤erentiated products over discrete time

5The material appearing in this section is a compact exposition of a large debate. See

Deneckere (1983), Majerus (1988), Chang (1991, 1992), Rothschild (1992), Ross (1992), Lambertini (1997) and Albæk and Lambertini (1998), inter alia.

(13)

t = 0; 1; 2; 3; :::1. At any t; the inverse demand function for variety i is (see Spence, 1976; and Singh and Vives, 1984, inter alia):

pi = a qi sqj (9)

where s 2 [0; 1] is the symmetric degree of substitutability between any pair of varieties. If s = 1; products are completely homogeneous; if instead s = 0; strategic interaction disappears and …rms are independent monopolists over

n separated markets. The direct demand function to be used under Bertrand

behaviour obtains by inverting the system (9):

qi = a 1 + s pi 1 s2 + spj 1 s2: (10)

As in the previous model, …rms share the same technology, summarised by

the cost function Ci = cqi; wit marginal cost c being normalised to zero for

the sake of simplicity. Therefore, per-period individual pro…ts are i = piqi:

Throughout the game, …rms also share the same intertemporal preferences

measured by the constant discount factor 2 (0; 1) :

The perfect folk theorem yields the following condition, that must be satis…ed in order for the collusive path to be stable:

C 1 X t=0 t D + N 1 X t=1 t ; (11)

where, unlike the previous model, N 0 is the pro…t generated by the

Bertrand-Nash equilibrium of the constituent game; it is positive whenever some degree of product di¤erentiation exists. Likewise, product

di¤erentia-tion entails that D

2 C; 2 C ; i.e., the cheating …rm may not necessarily

stand alone in the market in the deviation period. Four relevant cases are to be examined:

…rms’ time preferences allow for full collusion at the pure monopoly price, and product di¤erentiation is high enough to allow the cheated …rm to operate on the market with positive market share and pro…ts in the deviation period;

…rms’ time preferences allow for full collusion at the pure monopoly price, but product di¤erentiation is low enough to cause the cheated

(14)

…rms’time preferences only allow for some degree of partial collusion, and product di¤erentiation is high enough to allow the cheated …rm to operate on the market with positive market share and pro…ts in the deviation period;

…rms’time preferences only allow for some degree of partial collusion, but product di¤erentiation is low enough to cause the cheated …rm’s market share and pro…ts to fall to zero in the deviation period.

What is common to all of the above four cases is the per-period

Bertrand-Nash pro…t N appearing on the r.h.s. of (11), that can be quickly worked

out once and for all.

The …rst order condition for the maximization of i w.r.t. pi is

@ i

@pi

= a (1 s) 2pi+ spj

1 s2 = 0 (12)

whereby the symmetric Bertrand-Nash equilibrium price is

pN = a (1 s)

2 s (13)

with pro…ts

N = a2(1 s)

(1 + s) (2 s)2; (14)

both falling to zero in the homogeneous good case.

2.2.1 Full collusion

Under full collusion, both …rms set the monopoly price

pM = a

2 (15)

which yields the symmetric share of monopoly pro…ts

C = a 2 4 (1 + s) = M 2 (16) to each …rm.

(15)

Now look at the deviation period, and suppose the cheated …rms remains on the market selling a positive output. The optimal deviation is the best

reply to pM; i.e.:

pD pM = a (2 s)

4 (17)

which is viable as long as the resulting sales volume of the …rm remaining loyal to the cartel is positive, which requires

s2h0;p3 1 : (18)

The deviation pro…ts are

D = a2(2 s)

2

16 (1 s2): (19)

If instead s 2 p3 1; 1 ; then the cheated …rm is out of business and

the deviator stands alone on the market place. In this range, the deviation price solves qch = a 1 + s pM 1 s2 + spD 1 s2 = 0; (20) yielding pD0 pM = a (2s 1) 2s (21)

delivering deviation pro…ts equal to

D0

pM = a

2(2s 1)

4s2 : (22)

Then one can easily verify that

pD pM = pD0 pM and D pM = D0 pM (23)

in correspondence of s =p3 1:

We can now turn to the derivation of the critical thresholds of the discount

factor , above which full collusion is sustainable in the two cases. For

all s 2 0;p3 1 , (19) is the relevant deviation pro…t, and the critical

threshold of the discount factor above which full collusion in prices is stable is = D pM M = (2 s) 2 (24)

(16)

while for all s 2 p3 1; 1 ; i.e., in the region where (22) applies, it is 0 B = D0 pM M D0(pM) BN = (2 s)2[s (1 + s) 1] (2 s)2[s (1 + s) 1] + s4 (25) with B0 = 1=2 if s = 1: 2.2.2 Partial collusion

Here we deal with the performance of a cartel whose members’time prefer-ences are below the thresholds identi…ed above. The issue, in such a case, is

to …nd the highest collusive price p 2 pN; pM sustainable over time, given

. If all …rms set the collusive output p ; the per-period pro…ts of each cartel member are

C = (a p ) p

1 + s : (26)

Again, the optimal deviation against the cartel price will take two dif-ferent forms, depending on the degree of substitutability s. If the latter is su¢ ciently low (i.e., product di¤erentiation between the two varieties is high enough), the deviator will adopt its best reply to cartel pricing solving (12)

in which one has to plug pj = p ; to get the optimal deviation price

pD(p ) = a (1 s) + sp

2 : (27)

This generates the following one-o¤ deviation pro…ts

D(p ) = [a (1 s) + sp ]

2

4 (1 s2) ; (28)

provided that the cheated …rm is still active, i.e., it must be selling a positive

quantity qch. This happens if

qch= 1 2 a p p 2 (1 s) + 2 (a p ) + p 2 (1 + s) > 0 (29) which requires p 2 pN;a (1 s) [2 + s (6 s)] 2 s2 : (30)

(17)

In this price range, condition (11) yields the following highest collusive price

p = a (1 s) [4 s (1 ) (1 s)]

(2 s) [4 (1 s) + s2(1 )] (31)

which is monotonically increasing in a and lower than pM for all admissible

values of s and .

Now we turn our attention to the collusive price range wherein any unilat-eral deviation makes the cheating …rm a monopolist, driving all loyal cartel members out of business. This happens if expression (29) is non positive, i.e., for all

p 2 a (1 s) [2 + s (6 s)] 2 s2 ; a + c 2 (32) with a + c 2 a (1 s) [2 + s (6 s)] 2 s2 for all s 2hp3 1; 1i: (33)

Imposing qCh = 0 yields the deviation price

pD0(p ) = p a (1 s)

s (34)

which in turn delivers the deviation pro…ts

D0 pM = (a p ) [p a (1 s)]

4s2 : (35)

It can be easily checked that pD0

(p ) = pD(p )in correspondence of

p = a (1 s) [2 + s (6 s)]

2 s2 : (36)

Plugging the above expression in the stability condition (11) and solving w.r.t. p ; one obtains p 0 = a h 4 (5 2s) s2 (2 s)2(1 + s) sp i 2 (2 s) [(1 ) (1 + s) s2] (37)

(18)

in which

= 2 (4 + s) s (2 s) s3 + (2s 1) s2 4 (1 s) (4 + s) s +(2 s)2:

(38)

One can verify that > 0; by solving = 0 w.r.t. and checking that

the resulting solutions 6= R for all s 2 p3 1; 1 . Therefore, has the

same sign as the coe¢ cient of 2 in (38), which is positive, as can be easily

ascertained. Moreover, the denominator of p 0 is positive for all s and in

the unit interval.

The next step consists in observing that

a (1 s) [2 + s (6 s)] 2 s2 < p 0 < a 2 < p 0 + (39)

for all < B0: Accordingly, we select p 0 as the optimal collusive price in the

admissible parameter range identi…ed by

2 ; and s 2hp3 1; 1i: (40)

The partial derivative of p+0 w.r.t. a is:

@p 0

@a =

(2 s) [(1 ) (2 + s) s2(2 )] sp

2 (2 s) [(1 ) (1 + s) s2] (41)

Therefore, relying on the fact that > 0, we may evaluate the sign of the

numerator of @p 0=@a by evaluating the sign of

(2 s)2 (1 ) (2 + s) s2(2 ) 2 s4 (42)

which turns out to be positive for all 2 h0; e : The latter result, together

with Lemma 3, implies that @p 0=@a > 0in the entire admissible range (40).

Hence, the foregoing discussion allows us to formulate:

Lemma 2 In the Bertrand supergame under perfect certainty, any increase

(resp., decreases) in consumers’reservation price increases (resp., decreases) the intensity of partial collusion, for any degree of product di¤erentiation and irrespective of whether unilaterial deviation from the collusive path grants the cheating …rm monopoly power or not.

(19)

3

Bridging two visions

What we have reviewed so far boils down to the following two synthetic and seemingly antithetic messages:

i] if goods are undi¤erentiated and the market is subject to stochastic shoks

a¤ecting consumers’ reservation price, then …rms’ pricing behaviour exhibits a de…nite countercyclical pattern;

ii] if goods are di¤erentiated and the demand level is deterministic, then

optimal cartel prices are always monotonically related to the reservation price, heedless of …rms’time preferences.

Our aim in this section is to develop anew a model in which product di¤erentiation and uncertainty operate together, so as to see whether the above conclusions may indeed be compatible with each other. As a …rst step, we will examine the case in which duopolistic competition survives unilateral deviations from cartel pricing. The second step will be to look at the opposite case where the defecting …rm attains a monopolistic position.

On the supply side, the setup is the same as above. On the demand side, the demand function for …rm i will be:

qit = t 1 + s pit 1 s2 + spjt 1 s2; (43)

with t 2 fa; bg ; a > b > 0 and probabilities p (a) = m and p (b) = 1 m;

respectively, with m 2 [0; 1] :

3.1

Best reply deviation and the persistence of duopoly

Here, the deviation price maximises D and qch> 0: We set out by taking a

quick look at the stability condition for full collusion.

Monopoly price in state t is pMt = t=2; delivering expected per-…rm

cartel pro…ts

E C = ma

2+ (1 m) b2

4 (1 + s) : (44)

The deviation price and pro…ts in correspondence of the best demand state

(20)

The individual expected Bertrand-Nash pro…ts in each period of the punish-ment phase are given by

E N = [ma

2+ (1 m) b2] (1 s)

(1 + s) (2 s)2 : (45)

As a result, collusive stability now requires

a2(2 s)2 a2 4m (1 s) (2 s)2 + b2(1 m)2(1 s)2 ; (46) with @ @a / (1 m) (1 s) > 08m 2 [0; 1) ; s 2 h 0;p3 1 (47) and @ @m / (1 s) < 08s 2 h 0;p3 1 : (48)

As for partial collusion, de…ne

E C = m (a p (a)) p (a) + (1 m) (b p (b)) p (b)

1 + s (49)

with p (b) = b=2, in such a way that the only unknown is the partially collusive price in the best state, p (a). That is, we assume …rms will charge the best collusive price in the worst state, and appropriately tune p (a) so as to satisfy the stability condition (11), which we are about to construct step by step.

Accordingly, the best deviation against p (a) along the reaction function is

pD(p (a)) = a (1 s) + sp (a)

2 : (50)

Then the expected payo¤ in each period of the punishment phase is (45). From the usual stability condition, we get the pair of solutions:

p (a) = a (2 s) (1 s) 2 (1 s) s p (2 s) [s2(1 ) + 4 (1 s)] (2 s)2 4m (1 s) (2 s)2 (51) where = [2 m + (2 s) (1 )] s2(1 ) + 4 (1 s) > 0 (52)

(21)

and

= a2m2 s2(1 ) + 4 (1 s) 2+ (53)

4b2(2 s)2(1 ) (1 m) (2 s)2 4m (1 s) (2 s)2 > 0:

It is then easily checked that lim

m!1p (a) =

a (1 s) [4 s (1 ) (1 s)]

(2 s) [4 (1 s) + s2(1 )] = p (54)

i.e., the same price as in (31). Finally, taking the partial derivative of p (a) w.r.t. a; one can verify that

@p @a / a 2 m2 s2(1 ) + 4 (1 s) (2 s)2(1 ) + 4m + 4b2(2 s)4(1 ) (1 m) [2 m + (2 s) (1 )]2 > 0 (55) everywhere.

Therefore, we can state

Proposition 3 If deviation from the collusive path does not grant monopoly

power, then the maximum collusive price sustainable under stochastic demand conditions is monotonically increasing in the level of the best demand state.

3.2

Defecting to monopoly

The last step consists in investigating the case in which a unilateral devia-tion from the cartel price turns the deviator into a monopolist. Under full collusion, the only detail that has to be modi…ed is the deviation price in correspondence of the best state, which causes the cheated …rm’s output to drop to zero. This is (21), ensuring the deviation pro…ts (22) for all

s 2 p3 1; 1 . The resulting stability condition is

a2(2 s)2[(1 + s) s 1]

a2[s4(m + 1) + 4 (4s 1) s2(1 + 3s)] + b2(1 m) s4

0

; (56)

with @ 0=@a > 0and @ 0=@m < 0for all s 2 p3 1; 1 , so that the picture

remains much the same as we already know it, along the frontier of industry pro…ts.

(22)

Now suppose …rms’time preferences fall short of (56). If so, they may ac-tivate the highest sustainable degree of partial collusion. In such a case, they set p (b) = b=2 whenever demand is low, and solve the stability condition w.r.t. p (a) ; obtaining: p 0(a) = a (2 s) [(1 ) (2 s (2s 1)) ms 2] sp 2 (2 s) [(1 ) (1 + s (1 s)) ms2] (57) in which = a2 s2(1 (1 ms))2+ (58) 4 (1 ) ((1 ) (1 s) m (2s 1))] b2 s2(1 m) (1 ) (1 + s (1 s)) ms2 with (1 ) (2 s (2s 1)) ms2 > 0; (59) s2(1 (1 ms))2+ 4 (1 ) ((1 ) (1 s) m (2s 1)) > 0 (60) and s2(1 m) (1 ) (1 + s (1 s)) ms2 < 0 (61)

for all and m in the unit interval and all s 2 p3 1; 1 : In the same

parameter region, one also has that (i) >for all

a2

b2 >

s2(1 m) [(1 ) (1 + s (1 s)) ms2]

s2(1 (1 ms))2+ 4 (1 ) ((1 ) (1 s) m (2s 1)) (62)

with the threshold on the r.h.s. of (62) being always lower than one (hence,

both p 0(a)and p+0(a) are real), and (ii) p

0

(a) :

To identify the correct solution, it su¢ ces to verify that

lim m!1p 0 (a) = ah4 (5 2s) s2 (2 s)2 (1 + s) sp i 2 (2 s) [(1 ) (1 + s) s2] = p 0 : (63)

The last step consist in di¤erentiating p 0(a) w.r.t. a; de…ning a = rb

with r > 1 and then solving @p 0(a) =@a = 0 w.r.t. r; getting6

r = s (2 s) [(1 ) (2 s (2s 1)) ms

2]p (1 m) [(1 ) (1 + s (1 s)) ms2]

2p(1 s) = r

(64)

(23)

with

= (1 ) (1 + s (1 s)) ms2 ms2 (1 ) (2 s)2(1 + s)

s2(1 (1 ms))2+ 4 (1 ) ((1 ) (1 s) + m (2s 1)) : (65)

Now, it can be shown analytically that r 2 R+; moreover,

lim m!1r = 0 and (66) lim m!0r = s [2 (1 s2) + s]p (2 s)p(1 ) (1 s2) > 1 (67) for all > (2 s) 2 (1 s2) s2+ 4 [1 s (1 + s (1 s)) (1 s) (1 s2)] = (68)

which is decreasing and concave in s, with = 3 39 + 38p3 =937 ' 0:336

in s = p3 1 and = 0 in s = 1: Consequently, we have that

@p 0(a)

@a > 0 for all r > max f1; rg (69)

and conversely between one and r, if indeed r > 1: In general, r is decreasing and concave in m (this can ve ascertained numerically), and will give rise to a picture like the one reported in Figure 2, in which "+" and "-" signs

(24)

Figure 2: Collusive pricing in the space (m; r). 6 -r m 1 + (0; 0) 1

To sum up, above the upper envelope @p 0(a) =@a > 0;if r > 1 for at least

some acceptable parameter values, then in such a region @p 0(a) =@a < 0:7

An analogous exercise can be carried out in the space (s; a) as well as in

( ; a) : This is done in Figures 3 and 4, respectively. In particular, Figure 3

shows that countercyclical pricing emerges in the region in which r 2 (1; r) and the two product varieties are su¢ ciently close substitutes. It is also worth observing that r asymptotically increases to in…nity as s approaches 1 in the limit, in which case pricing is countercyclical irrespective of r; as in Rotemberg and Saloner’s (1986) original formulation.

(25)

Figure 3: Collusive pricing in the space (s; r). 6 -r s 1 + (0; 0) 1

(26)

Figure 4: Collusive pricing in the space ( ; r). 6 -r 1 + (0; 0) 1=2

Our …nal result can be therefore stated as follows:

Proposition 4 If deviation from the collusive path grants monopoly power,

then the maximum collusive price sustainable under stochastic demand condi-tions is monotonically decreasing (increasing) in the level of the best demand state if product di¤erentiation is low (high) enough.

4

Concluding remarks

The e¤ective size of government spending multipliers is a crucial macroeco-nomic issue, especially after the massive …scal stimuli of 2009-2010 and the need for spending cuts which is becoming more and more pressing. In im-perfectly competitive frameworks, multipliers’size is increasing function of mark-up countercyclicality but decreasing function of its procyclicality. As a

(27)

consequence, determining the e¤ective direction of pricing cyclicality becomes crucial for the analysis of a government spending stimulus on agggregate ac-tivity.

We have used a repeated duopoly game to revisit the issue of cyclical pricing so as to reconcile Rotemberg and Saloner’s (1986) results about the emergence of countercyclical pricing under uncertainty with the procyclical ‡avour traditionally associated with implicit collusion in the perfect certainty approach typical of the large debate on this topic in the theory of industrial organization.

The bottom line of our analysis is that the cyclical properties of …rms’ pricing behaviour are sensitive to the degree of product di¤erentiation across product varieties, in such a way that pricing is procyclical whenever the cheated …rm retains a positive market share during deviations (because prod-ucts are weak substitutes), while instead counterciclicity indeed obtains pro-vided that (i) the deviator becomes a monopolist and (ii) product di¤erenti-ation is su¢ ciently low.

Mark-up cyclical behaviour might therefore be a far more complicated issue than previously thought, with relevent consequences on the actual ef-fects of expansionary expenditure-based …scal policies. Future research will be concerned with an empirical analysis attempting to link di¤erent sectors (featured by di¤erent degrees of product di¤erentiation) with di¤erent cycli-cal properties of their average mark-ups.

(28)

References

[1] Albæk, S. and L. Lambertini (1998), “Collusion in Di¤erentiated Duopolies Revisited”, Economics Letters, 59, 305-8.

[2] Bagwell, K. and R. Staiger (1997), “Collusion Over the Business Cycle”, RAND Journal of Economics, 28, 82-106.

[3] Bils, M., (1987), “The Cyclical Behavior of Marginal Costs and Price”, American Economic Review, 77, 838-55.

[4] Canzoneri, M., F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba (2011), “Fiscal Mul-tipliers in Recessions”, mimeo.

[5] Chang, M.H. (1991), “The E¤ects of Product Di¤erentiation on Collu-sive Pricing”, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 9, 453-69.

[6] Chang, M.H. (1992), “Intertemporal Product Choice and Its E¤ects on Collusive Firm Behavior”, International Economic Review, 33, 773-93. [7] Chevalier, J.A., A.K. Kashyap and P.E. Rossi (2003), “Why Don’t Prices

Rise During Periods of Peak Demand? Evidence from Scanner Data”, American Economic Review, 93, 15-37.

[8] Chirinko, R.S. and M. Fazzari (1994), “Economic Fluctuations,Market Power and Returns to Scale: Evidence from Firm-Level Data”, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 9, 509-13.

[9] Donowitz, I.R., G. Hubbard and B.C. Petersen (1986), “Business Cycles and the Relationship Between Concentration and Price-Cost Margins”, Rand Journal of Economics, 17, 1-17.

[10] Donowitz, I.R., G. Hubbard and B.C. Petersen (1988), “Market Struc-ture and Cyclical Fluctuations in US Manufacturing”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 70, 55-66.

[11] Deneckere, R. (1983), “Duopoly Supergames with Product Di¤erentia-tion”, Economics Letters, 11, 37-42.

[12] Etro, F. and A. Colciago (2010), “Endogenous Market Structure and the Business Cycle”, Economic Journal, 120, 1201-33.

(29)

[13] Friedman, J.W. (1971), “A Non-Cooperative Equilibrium for Su-pergames”, Review of Economic Studies, 28, 1-12.

[14] Galì, J., (2005), “Modern Perspective on Fiscal Stabilization Policies”, CESifo Economic Studies, 51, 587-99.

[15] Galì, J., M. Gertler and J.D. Lopez-Salido (2005), “Mark-ups, Gaps and the Welfare Costs of Business Cycle Fluctuations”, mimeo, CREI. [16] Ghironi, F. and M. Melitz (2005), “International Trade and

Macroeco-nomic Dynamics with Heterogenous Firms”, Quarterly Journal of Eco-nomics, 120, 865-915.

[17] Hall, R. (2009), “By How Much does GDP Rises if the Government Buys More Output?”, NBER Working paper 15496.

[18] Haltiwanger, J. and J. Harrington (1991), “The Impact of Cyclical Demand Movements on Collusive Behaviour”, RAND Journal of Eco-nomics, 22, 89-106.

[19] Jaimovich, N. and M. Floetotto (2008), “Firm Dynamics, Mark-Up Vari-ations and the Business Cycle”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 55, 1238-52.

[20] Lambertini, L. (1997), “Prisoners’Dilemma in Duopoly (Super)Games”, Journal of Economic Theory, 77, 181-91.

[21] Majerus, D. (1988), “Price vs Quantity Competition in Oligopoly Su-pergames”, Economics Letters, 27, 293-7.

[22] Martins, J., S. Scapetta and D. Pilat (1996), “Markup Pricing, Market Structure and the Business Cycle”, OECD Economic Studies, 27, 71-105.

[23] Nekarda, C. and V. Ramey (2010), “The Cyclical Behavior of the Price-Cost Markup”, mimeo, University of California, San Diego.

[24] Portier, F. (1995), “Business Formation and Cyclical Markups in the French Business Cycle”, Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, 37, 411-40.

(30)

[25] Ross, T.W. (1992), “Cartel Stability and Product Di¤erentiation”, In-ternational Journal of Industrial Organization, 10, 1-13.

[26] Rotemberg, J. and G. Saloner (1986), “A Supergame-Theoretic Model of Price Wars during Booms”, American Economic Review, 76, 390-407. [27] Rotemberg, J. and M. Woodford (1999), “The Cyclical Behaviour of Prices and Costs”, in J.B. Taylor and M. Woodford (eds), Handbook of Macroeconomics, 1 (B), 1051-1135.

[28] Rotemberg, J. and M.Woodford (1992), “Oligopolistic Pricing and the E¤ects of Aggregate Demand on Economic Activity”, Journal of Politi-cal Economy, 100, 1153-1207.

[29] Rothschild, R. (1992), “On the Sustainability of Collusion in Di¤erenti-ated Duopolies”, Economics Letters, 40, 33-7.

[30] Singh, N. and X.Vives (1984), “Price and Quantity Competition in a Di¤erentiated Duopoly”, RAND Journal of Economics, 15, 546-54. [31] Spence, M. (1976), “Product Di¤erentiation and Welfare”, American

Economic Review, 66, 407-14.

[32] Tirole, J. (1988), The Theory of Industrial Organization, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.

[33] Woodford, M., (2003), Interest and Prices. Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy, Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press.

[34] Woodford, M., (2011), “Simple Analytics of the Government Expen-diture Multiplier”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 3, 1-35.

(31)

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

È nostra intenzione, pertanto, utilizzare il linguaggio cartografico per rappresentare uno spazio e un mondo educativo particolare, quello dell’educazione della prima infanzia al

The starting point in order to ascertain the “state of the art” in international law on the application of the principle of permanent sovereignty over natural resources in NSGTs –

There are no studies of strategies to decrease blood sampling rates or volumes to reduce the prevalence or severity of anaemia in critically ill patients or red cell

Li mette a confronto con lavoratori dell’industria pesante, che vengono al secondo posto, quindi in ordine, impiegati di banca ( per le posture scorrette), agricoltori,

corretti da adottare nei servizi sanitari.. INDICATORI TIPO DI INDICATORE STRUMENTO DI VALUTAZIONE CRITERIO DI VALUTAZIONE n. stanze isolamento struttura Archivio del progetto

After the disputed 2014 presidential election, Ashraf Ghani and Abdullah Abdullah signed an agreement for the formation of a government of national unity.. On this basis, Ghani

É questa appunto la specificità della filosofia dell’infanzia: valorizzare e siste- matizzare il “domandare” filosofico già presente nell’infanzia, accom- pagnando così il

Nel caso della truffa il danno arrecato non è solo economico ma, soprattutto, psicologico in quanto le vittime, essendo, solitamente, persone sufficientemente