• Non ci sono risultati.

Mathematical and statistical modelling of cointegration

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "Mathematical and statistical modelling of cointegration"

Copied!
32
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

Economics Department

Mathematical and Statistical

Modelling of Cointegration

S 0ren Jo h a n sen

ECO No. 97/14

EUI WORKING PAPERS

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(2)

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(3)

EUROPEAN UNIVERSITY INSTITUTE, FLORENCE ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT

EUI Working Paper ECO No. 97/14

Mathematical and Statistical Modelling of Cointegration

S0R E N JOHANSEN

BADIA FIESOLANA, SAN DOMENICO (FI)

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(4)

All rights reserved.

No part of this paper may be reproduced in any form without permission of the author.

©Spren Johansen Printed in Italy in April 1997 European University Institute

Badia Fiesolana I - 50016 San Domenico (FI)

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(5)

Mathematical and Statistical Modelling of

Cointegration

S0ren Johansen

European University Institute

March 12, 1997

A bstract

A brief overview is given of some of the problems in econometric model building. We discuss, by example, the concept of a time series, a random walk, and integrated variable and the notion of cointegration and common trends.

This lecture was presented at the University of Copenhagen for the occasion of Copenhagen as the Cultural City of Europe, September 1996, and at EUI for the workshop on Inflation and Unemployment in Economies in Transition, October 1996. © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(6)

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(7)

1

In tr o d u c tio n

The concept of cointegration was defined by Granger (1981) and after the paper by Engle and Granger (1987) it has become one of the cornerstones in modern time series econometrics, although it was implicitly applied by Sargan (1964) and Davidson, Hendry, Srba and Yeo (1978). It is the purpose of this paper to give some simple examples of cointegrated time series and discuss in relation to a very simple economic problem, how cointegration can be useful. Examples of mathematical statistical models which allow such phenomenon are given.

Section 2 gives a brief description of an economic problem and the data and in section 3 we discuss the notion of a mathematical model in particular a mathematical statistical model of economic data. Section 4 gives some examples of equations th at can generate stationary and non-stationary univariate series and in section 5 the same is done for systems of variables th a t interact.

The notion of equilibrium (or error) correction model is introduced and the basic definition of integration, cointegration and common trends are given.

Throughout there are a few references to the existing literature.

2

A sim p le e c o n o m ic s to r y a n d a d a ta s e t

We give in this section an example of an economic problem and illustrate by a set of data which consists of quarterly measurements of prices and exchange rates from 1973 first quarter to 1987 third quarter. The d ata is shown in Figure 1. We shall use the d ata to illustrate the following simple economic problem.

The law of one price states th at the price of a commodity in Denmark (Pdk) and the price of the same commodity (Pge) in Germany are equal if expressed in the same currency. If (E dk^ e) is the exchange rate between German Mark and Danish Krone then the law of one price is expressed as

p d k _ p g e p d k / g c ^ ^

If the prices measured are not prices of simple commodities but rather price indices computed in a roughly similar manner in different countries, one would expect that this law does not hold as an identity, but rather that if it does not hold over a longer period, then some adjustment must take place either in the exchange rate or in the prices, so that a disequilibrium between price levels will be diminished. If (1) holds we say that Purchasing Power Parity holds.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(8)

Figure 1: The data shown in the left hand panel are log price level in Denmark and Germany as well as the exchange rate. In the right hand panel we have shown the data in differences.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(9)

Figure 2: The series shown is pppt = pdk — p?e — et.

The data in Figure 1 show the consumer price series in Denmark and Germany and the exchange rate. As is usually done in this type of work we have expressed the variables in logarithms. The data is also presented in differences, such that the change of a price series in logs corresponds to a relative change in the price or in other words the inflation rate. Expressed in logarithms we get for pdk = \og(Pdk), pge — log (P9e) , and e = \og(E9e^dk) th at the law one price states that

PPPt = P? - p f - et = 0.

By plotting the variable pppt in Figure 2 it is seen th at the law of one price does not hold with such a simple formulation. We note th a t the log prices increase roughly linearly corresponding to a constant inflation rate. The erratic movements around such a straight line is what we are concerned with in mod­ elling by a statistical model. The exchange rate moves around in a seemingly random fashion and the differences, which form the quarterly increases, look a lot more stable, in the sense that the trend has been taken out of all three series.

The present paper deals with the problem of modelling time series as seen in Figures 1 and 2. It discusses some statistical concepts developed for the analysis of such models.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(10)

3

M o d e llin g E c o n o m ic T im e se r ie s

The purpose of modelling economic variables is to describe the phenomenon we observe, but we hope by this description to get behind the immediate picture and express our understanding of the economic mechanism th at governs the development.

The purpose of this can be prediction or simply understanding. If you understand the mechanism that produced the phenomenon, you can advise on policy implications and design policies for specific purposes.

It is a common feature of such models that they describe in some detail that part of reality which we observe, but not in every detail, since then it would be much too complicated. Hence a model constitutes a cleverly chosen simplification of reality.

Of special concern here are phenomenon that involve randomness, and which require statistical models.

It is an im portant aspect of a model th at it can be incorrect, and it is in the confrontation between a theoretical model and observations of reality that statistics has a role to play.

When modelling the statistical fluctuations of economic variables, we can start with the idea of prediction. If we want to predict the exchange rate tomorrow on the basis of observations of past exchange rates, we define the prediction error as the difference between the observed exchange rate and our prediction of it.

The prediction error measures how much we missed the actual outcome and measures the surprise in the data.

Let et be the exchange rate measured in period t and let the past values observed be e\ , . . . , et_i. These can be daily measurement, weekly measurements or, as on Figure 1, quarterly measurements. A simple, and probably too simple, prediction strategy is expressed in

prediction of exchange rate tomorrow = exchange rate today.

In this case the prediction error or surprise is just

Ct — e(_i. © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(11)

3.0 Gaussian density

Figure 3: The Gaussian density with mean 50 and variance 100.

It has been the tradition since the work of Haavelmo (1944) to model surprises as the outcome of random experiments, or as random variables, and this is where statistical modelling comes in.

The simplest of such models is to define

ft — — et_i, (2)

and then assume that the e are independent random variables which follow the Gaussian distribution.

In Figure 4 the density of such a random variable is given. This density can be considered a continuous analogue of the binomial distribution in Figure 3. The interpretation of this curve is that the probability of finding the random variable between two numbers a and b is the area under the curve from a to b.

Such random numbers are easily generated on a computer and in Figure 5 we have shown a sequence of random Gaussian numbers.

The observations are connected by straight lines to emphasize the variation of the points around the line which gives the central value 0. Model (2) is clearly a very simple description of reality, but is sometimes surprisingly accurate. So much in fact th at when econometricians want to model exchange rates they often compare their method of prediction, or their model, with the above simple benchmark. © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(12)

Figure 4: The left panel shows a sequence of independent Gaussian errors, and the in right hand panel they are cumulated to show a random walk.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(13)

The problem facing the modeler is how to extract information from past values concerning the predictions. We often model the prediction (or the deter­ ministic part of the process) as a linear function of past values and let t, denote the un-modelled part of the process or the surprise.

3.1 R and om shocks and in terven tion shocks

The above description of prediction errors as random is of course too simple. The economy often gives the econometrician surprises. Some of these can be quite easily modelled as random shocks, but others are clearly of more funda­ mental nature as the transition from a macro economic policy influenced by Keynesian economics to monetarist economics, or the shock th at the economy suffered when the capital markets were liberalized around 1983, when capital was allowed to move almost freely across international boundaries. It would not be reasonable to try to neglect such serious disturbances in the economy, but rather analyse their influence on the variables in question. Thus shocks can be grouped into random shocks and intervention shocks. It is an im portant part of econometric model building to sort out which shocks are in which category.

4

U n iv a r ia te tim e se rie s

In order to illustrate the concepts used in modelling economic variables we first consider a single process e(. We want to demonstrate how we can use equations with random disturbances to generate processes with desirable properties.

4.1 N o n -sta tio n a ry p rocesses and th e ran d om w alk

If we add equation (2) for i = 1 , . . . , t we get the equation

Ct = eo + ei + ' ' ' + €<• (3)

Figure 5 shows such a process. We have here defined an example of a so- called stochastic process or time series. This particular one is called a random walk, a terminology which alludes to a person who staggers along a street taking steps (et) of random size and direction, whereby e£ will be his position after t. steps when he starts at e0. The equations (2), when solved, gives a process which behaves very much like the exchange rate.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(14)

It should be emphasized, th at by modelling the exchange rate by a ran­ dom walk, we do not try to produce sample paths, or pictures, th at look like the observed one in every detail, since we have decided th at these details are unexplainable small shocks or surprises, which we want to model as random. But we want to use the model to create sample paths with the same qualitative behaviour, which loosely speaking can be described as a process th at ''floats" in the sense th at once it has reached a level it stays there until it reaches a new level. Such a process is called non-stationary as opposed to a stat ionary process which we shall now discuss.

4.2

A u to regressive and sta tio n a ry p rocesses

Consider the disequilibrium error in the law of one price

PPPt = Pit ~ P2t ~

ent-Figure 2 shows th at we have a process that is somewhat more stable than the prices and exchange rates, and which does not ’’float” as much as for instance the exchange rate. We want a model that mimics the adjusting behaviour of the prices and exchange rates, that is, a model with the property that if pppt gets too far away from zero, then it will be forced back towards zero either by changing prices or exchange rates.

This ’’reversal towards the mean” can be modelled by a so-called station­ ary process and a simple example of an equation that can generate such an adjusting process, which we shall call yt) is

2/t - Vt-i = tt(2/(-i - P) + U- (4) If for instance 7r = - 5 , and we have observed y(_i > p, then the change in the process is minus one half times the overshoot {yt~i — p) plus a random noise, which means th at if the process get too far out then a correction will take place and bring the process back towards the value p. Figure 6 shows the simulations of a stationary process generated by (4) for two different values of the parameter

7r and p = 0. The processes generated by (4) are called autoregressive processes. The name is chosen because in statistical jargon the model suggests a regression analysis of the value yt on the past yt-\.

Note th at the value of tx measures the ’’glue” in the process. It 7r is around — 1, neighbouring values are almost unrelated or independent,a dn the process

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(15)

Figure 5: Autoregressive processes with parameters 7r = —0.5 and n = —0.1. © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(16)

moves up and down completely irregularly. If tt is close to 0 then neighbouring values are more often close together, and we get a wave-like behaviour.

Model (4) is an analogue of a differential equation, which in physics is used to model continuous dynamic phenomena. The simplest differential equation is

= 7T(y(t) - n), (5)

which has solution

y(t)

= (

2

/(

0

) - p )e * ‘ +

n-Thus for 7r < 0 we get an exponential decay towards //..

Model (4) is a simplification of (5) in the sense th at we only have observa­ tions at distinct time points, but more complicated than (5) since we also have random disturbances.

In summary we can say th at model (4) generates a process yt which, if

—2 < 7r < 0, exhibits mean reversion or stationarity, and if n = 0 we get a random walk, which is non-stationary.

Note how the deterministic part of the change of the process is modelled by uyt—i + p, and the random part by the Gaussian random number et.

5

M u ltiv a r ia te s y s te m s

The above discussion of stationarity and non-stationarity focuses on a single variable observed over time. In practice we often have many variables observed together and we here discuss such systems, and use th at as a starting point for defining the important notions of equilibrium correction models, integration and cointegration.

Consider therefore the system consisting of the three variables from section 2. We want to model these by a multivariate version of the autoregressive process considered in (4). We suggest the model

p f - P(_i = KuP'l-i + TrnPlU + + Pi + Hi,

p T - P t -1 = ^ 2 i p f - i + *22PT-1 + 7r23e t —1 + P 2 + «21, ( 6 ) e t ~ «1 -1 = n 3 lP <t - \ + 7 T 3 2 P l-l + n 3 3 Z t- \ + P3 + «31 •

Expresses in words the changes of each of the variables is predicted by a linear combination of past values of all variables. One can make this a lot more

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(17)

complicated by adding more past values or even other variables which can help explain the variability in the prices and exchange rate. For now (6) is enough to illustrate the concepts needed in the empirical analysis of economic data.

The coefficients 7rl} measure the effect that each of the past values have on the changes, and p i is related to the growth rates.

5.1

T h e eq u ilib riu m or error correction m od el

The first question that one can ask one self is: W hat are the properties of the processes pf*, pi' and e( generated by such equations. We want to be able to generate processes th at have qualitatively the same properties as the observed series.

The answer to this problem is of course that it depends on which parameter values we consider.

It turns out that for the equations (6) to generate non-stationary variables we need a condition th at mimics the condition 7r = 0 in the univariate situa­ tion. The algebra behind this is difficult, but suffice it here to say th a t if the coefficients have the special structure given by the equations

.dk _ r dk

Pi Pt-l - rr,,ePt-l — e(_i) + eu, qe. qe

Pi — p?-i = <*2 (p ^ j - nqcPt-l — + £20

fit - et-i = a3( p f , - P t - l - e(- i ) + £qe 31, then the processes have a number of desirable properties.

This is a special case of the general equation (6), with 7tn = o , , n n =

—«1.^13 = —£*i, etc. Note th at the only linear combination of the past values

that enters is the ppp(_i. Thus the past speaks to us through the value of the equilibrium error.

The interpretation of these equations is that the change in the prices, and exchange rates react through the coefficients a, to a deviation between the prices and exchange rates as measured by the pppt-i in the past. Thus if the Danish prices are too large for some period, relative to the German prices as measured by the ppp(_i then the Danish prices will react to this disequilibrium and decrease. In this case it is not so obvious th a t the German prices will react, because their economy is so much larger, so we allow the value 0 for the coefficient «2- Finally the coefficient 03 measures the reaction of the exchange rates to the high prices in Denmark.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(18)

This simple story shows how we can capture a backward looking adjust­ ment behaviour in the framework of a simple tri-variate stochastic difference equation. It should be obvious that we are assuming linearity, whereas a non­ linear reaction function could be more realistic. It is also quite obvious that the formation of exchange rates is related to the financial markets, hence the inter­ est rates would be relevant variables to enter into the model, and the data. Thus there is ample room for making the modelling more realistic. This, however, is not the intention of the present presentation.

5.2

In tegration , coin tegra tio n and com m on tren d s

We discuss in this section three important concepts that have made the mod­ elling of random walk type phenomenon possible.

First of all one can show that the processes generated by (6) are non- stationary, th at is, they do not have any tendency to revert to a mean but ’’float” , like random walks, see Figure 3. We say that such processes are in­

tegrated, a terminology which comes from the usual notation of an integral

through the following associations: An integral /' is the limit of a sum, but a random walk is exactly a sum of the small shocks. Hence we cumulate or sum or integrate the shocks to get a random walk which is an integrated process.

Moreover, we can show th at the linear combination

PPPi = p f ~ PT ~ eo

is mean reverting or stationary. We say th at the processes pf*, />'' and e, are

cointegrated. We have simulated a bivariate system of cointegrated variables in

Figure 5.

Note how the individual processes float, whereas the difference between the processes as measured by ppp( is stationary, such that the processes move together. It is this co-movement phenomenon that we want to use in modelling economic variables in the following way.

Often economic theory makes static statements about relations between economic variables, which in reality move in a dynamic fashion. How can one reconcile a static statem ent as t he law of one price

Pit — P21 — e\21. — 0,

with the dynamically evolving data as shown in Figure 2 ?

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(19)

0.5 0.0 -0.5 ' -1.0 -1.5 -2.0 -2.5 -j -3.0 i -3.5 — An integrated process X1(t) V \ . -^v—' 0.5 T 0.0 • -0.5 -1.0 • -1.5 -i -2.0 -2.5 - -3.0 H 3.5 -20 29 38 47 56 65 74 83 92

Another integrated process X2(t)

\

A

20 29 38 47 56 65 74 83 92 1.00 0.75 4 0.50 0.25 0.00 -0.25 - / »W V -0.50 -0.75 20 30 The difference X1(t)-X2(t)

a

A

t/V ' V A 40 50

V

60 70 80 90 100

Figure 6: The figure shows two processes generated from the equations X u — ■Xit-i = — — X 2t-i) + f it> and X2t — X21-1 = — X 2t -1) + «20

Note that both processes are integrated but their difference is stationary, hence

X u and X21 are cointegrated.

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(20)

Clearly '’we need a stochastical formulation to make simplified relations elastic enough for applications” , Haavelmo (1943). and the interpretation of the long-run relation expressed by P P P is in the present framework that pppt is stationary.

Thus, if an error correction model of the type (6) can describe the variation of the data, then we have achieved a description that allows individual variables to be non-stationary, as they appear to be in reality, and still have the property th at a linear relation between the variables is stationary. Thus a cointegrating relation can be considered the statistical formulation of a long-run relation in the economy. Note that a long-run relation is something th at the processes would satisfy if all errors were switched off and the equations would then bring back the processes to a set of values where the relation is satisfied, a steady state.

Another interpretation is th at a long-run relation is like the equilibrium position of a pendulum. It is usually never seen in practice for a system that works, but can be considered an equilibrium position that is always present and towards which the pendulum is pulled.

5.3

T h e general EC M

We shall meet many examples of equilibrium correction models in the lectures by Juselius and Hendry, so let me just give the full formulation of the general error correction model expressed in mathematical form

A + r A A t _ ! + p + 4 > A + e , . ( 8 )

The process X t — ( X lt, . . . , X pt)' contains the relevant set of variables, often called the information set. The coefficients in the matrix a are the ad­ justment coefficients and the columns of (3 are the cointegrating vectors and

f]'Xt .t = c, the long-run relations. We call T the short-run coefficients, since

they express how the changes react to past changes. Finally we allow for the processes to have a growth rate /x and include the term D, to allow for extra variables like seasonal dummies or intervention dummies, that need to be taken into account when modelling the data.

Thus the general ECM allows us to model processes that are non-stationary but have stationary linear relations. The processes are composed of determin­ istic trends, of common stochastic trends or random walks and are called inte­ grated. Cointegration appears when there are fewer common stochastic trends

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(21)

than variables, such that these are driven by the same trends. This implies that they can be eliminated by suitable linear combinations, and that is how the phenomenon of cointegration appears as a useful way of modeling the long-run economic relations, that exhibit stability in a system of variables that all evolve dynamically.

Equilibrium correction models have been applied to describe economic data series since the work of Sargan (1964) and gained popularity with the pa­ per by Davidson, Hendry, Srba and Yeo (1978), but it was the papers by Granger (1981) and in particular Engle and Granger (1987) th at clarified the relation between ECM and cointegration, in the sense that any ECM will generate coin­ tegrated variables and cointegrated variables can be expresses as solutions of equilibrium correction models.

5.4

T h e p u rp ose o f econ om etric m od ellin g

The purpose of this type of econometric analysis can now briefly be formulated as follows. We have a set of economic variables which have been chosen because they represent measurements of interest to the economist. We have available theory of how these variables interact and are related, often expressed in terms of linear relations. We then analyse the data to find a reasonable statistical description, which in this context is an error correction model, in which we can formulate the economic theory as restrictions on the parameters, in particular we can often formulate the economic relations, that are derived for en economy in equilibrium or steady state, as the long-run or cointegrating relations.

The mathematical statistical analysis of such models amounts to checking whether error correction models provide an adequate description of the observed data. In the process of doing this, one will have to find reasonable estimators of all the unknown parameters and give guidelines for testing hypotheses on the parameters. Thus establishing the tools for checking the economic theory against reality. The book by Hendry (1995) is a general overview of econometric modelling of dynamic phenomena, and the paper by Johansen and Juselius (1990) gives the mathematical statistical analysis of the ECM with respect to inference on cointegration. A systematic theory of cointegration in the ECM is given in Johansen (1995). © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(22)

6

R e fe r e n c e s

Davidson, J. E. H., Hendry, D. F., Srba F. and Yeo S. (1978), Economic Modelling of the Aggregate Time Series Relationships between Consumers' Ex­ penditure and Income in the United Kingdom, Economic Journal, 88, 661-692. Engle, R. F. and Granger C. W. J. (1987), Cointegration and Error Cor­ rection: Representation, Estimation and Testing, Econometrica, 55, 251-276.

Granger C. W. ,). (1981), Some Properties of Time Series and their use in Econometric Model Specification, Journal of Econometrics, 16, 121-130.

Haavelmo, T. (1943), The Statistical Implications of a System of Simul­ taneous equations, Econometrica, 11, 1-12.

Haavelmo, T. (1944), The Probability Approach in Econometrics, Econo­

metrica, 12, 1-118. Supplement.

Hendry, D. F. (1985), Dynamic Econometrics, Oxford University Press. Oxford.

Johansen, S. (1995), Likelihood-based, inference in cointegrated vector au­

toregressive models, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Johansen, S. and Juselius, K. (1990), Maximum Likelihood Estimation and Inference on Cointegration with Applications to the Demand for Money.

Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 52, 169-210.

Sargan. J. D. (1964), Wages and Prices in the United Kingdom: A Study in Econometric Methodology (with discussion). In Hart, P. E. and Mills, G. and Whitaker, J. K. (eds.), Econometric analysis for National Economic Planning,

16, 25-63. © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(23)

EUI

WORKING

PAPERS

EUI Working Papers are published and distributed by the European University Institute, Florence

Copies can be obtained free of charge - depending on the availability of stocks - from:

The Publications Officer European University Institute

Badia Fiesolana

1-50016 San Domenico di Fiesole (FI) Italy

Please use order form overleaf

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(24)

Publications of the European University Institute

To The Publications Officer European University Institute Badia Fiesolana

1-50016 San Domenico di Fiesole (FI) - Italy Telefax No: +39/55/4685 636

E-mail: publish@datacomm.iue.it

From N am e... Address...

□ Please send me a complete list of EUI Working Papers □ Please send me a complete list of EUI book publications □ Please send me the EUI brochure Academic Year 1997/98 Please send me the following EUI Working Paper(s): No, Author ... Title: ... No, Author ... Title: ... No, Author ... Title: ... No, Author ... Title: ... Date ... Signature © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(25)

Working Papers of the Department of Economics Published since 1994

E C O N o. 96/1 Ana Rute CARDOSO

Earnings Inequality in Portugal: High and Rising?

ECO N o. 96/2 Ana Rute CARDOSO

Workers or Employers: Who is Shaping Wage Inequality?

EC O N o. 96/3

David F. HENDRY/Grayham E. MIZON The Influence o f A.W.H. Phillips on Econometrics

EC O N o. 96/4 Andrzej BANIAK

The Multimarket Labour-Managed Firm and the Effects o f Devaluation

EC O N o. 96/5 Luca ANDERLINI/Hamid SABOURIAN

The Evolution o f Algorithmic Learning: A Global Stability Result

E C O No. 96/6 James DOW

Arbitrage, Hedging, and Financial Innovation

E C O No. 96/7 Marion KOHLER

Coalitions in International Monetary Policy Games

EC O N o. 96/8

John MICKLEWRIGHT/ Gyula NAGY A Follow-Up Survey o f Unemployment Insurance Exhausters in Hungary ECO No. 96/9

Alastair McAULEY/John

MICKLEWRIGHT/Aline COUDOUEL Transfers and Exchange Between Households in Central Asia E C O N o. 96/10

Christian BELZIL/Xuelin ZHANG Young Children and the Search Costs of Unemployed Females

ECO N o. 96/11 Christian BELZIL

Contiguous Duration Dependence and Nonstationarity in Job Search: Some Reduced-Form Estimates

ECO No. 9 6 /12 Ramon MARIMON

Learning from Learning in Economics ECO N o. 9 6 /13

Luisa ZANFORLIN

Technological Diffusion, Learning and Economic Performance: An Empirical Investigation on an Extended Set of Countries

ECO No. 9 6 /14

Humberto L6PEZ/Eva ORTEGA/Angel UBIDE

Explaining the Dynamics of Spanish Unemployment

ECO N o. 96/1 5 Spyros VASSILAKIS

Accelerating New Product Development by Overcoming Complexity Constraints ECO N o. 9 6 /16 Andrew LEWIS On Technological Differences in Oligopolistic Industries ECO N o. 96/17 Christian BELZIL

Employment Reallocation, Wages and the Allocation o f Workers Between Expanding and Declining Firms ECO No. 96/18

Christian BELZIL/Xuelin ZHANG Unemployment, Search and the Gender Wage Gap: A Structural Model ECO No. 9 6 /19

Christian BELZIL

The Dynamics o f Female Time Allocation upon a First Birth

ECO No. 96/20 Hans-Theo NORMANN

Endogenous Timing in a Duopoly Model with Incomplete Information

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(26)

EC O No. 96/21

Ramon MARIMON/Fabrizio ZILIBOl'll ‘Actual’ Versus ‘Virtual’ Employment in Europe: Is Spain Different?

EC O No. 9 6 /22 Chiara MONFARDINI

Estimating Stochastic Volatility Models Through Indirect Inference

E C O No. 96/23 Luisa ZANFORLIN

Technological Diffusion, Learning and Growth: An Empirical Investigation o f a Set o f Developing Countries

E C O N o. 96/24 Luisa ZANFORLIN

Technological Assimilation, Trade Patterns and Growth: An Empirical Investigation of a Set o f Developing Countries

E C O N o. 96/25

Giampiero M.GALLO/Massimiliano MARCELLINO

In Plato’s Cave: Sharpening the Shadows o f Monetary Announcements

E C O N o. 96/26 Dimitrios SIDERIS

The Wage-Price Spiral in Greece: An Application o f the LSE Methodology in Systems o f Nonstationary Variables E C O N o. 96/27

Andrei SAVKOV

The Optimal Sequence of Privatization in Transitional Economies

E C O No. 96/28

Jacob LUNDQUIST/Dorte VERNER Optimal Allocation o f Foreign Debt Solved by a Multivariate GARCH Model Applied to Danish Data

EC O N o. 96/29 Dorte VERNER

The Brazilian Growth Experience in the Light o f Old and New Growth Theories EC O No. 96/30

Steffen HORNIG/Andrea LOFARO/ Louis PHLIPS

How Much to Collude Without Being Detected

ECO N o. 96/31 Angel J. UBIDE

The International Transmission o f Shocks in an Imperfectly Competitive

International Business Cycle Model ECO N o. 96/32

Humberto LOPEZ/Angel J. UBIDE Demand, Supply, and Animal Spirits ECO No. 96/33

Andrea LOFARO

On the Efficiency o f Bertrand and Cournot Competition with Incomplete Information

ECO No. 96/34

Anindya BANERJEE/David F. HENDRY/Grayham E. MIZON The Econometric Analysis of Economic Policy

ECO No. 96/35 Christian SCHLUTER

On the Non-Stationarity o f German Income Mobility (and Some Observations on Poverty Dynamics)

ECO No. 96/36 Jian-Ming ZHOU

Proposals for Land Consolidation and Expansion in Japan

ECO No. 96/37

Susana GARCIA CERVERO

Skill Differentials in the Long and in the Short Run. A 4-D igit SIC Level U.S. Manufacturing Study

ECO N o. 97/1 Jonathan SIMON

The Expected Value of Lotto when not all Numbers are Equal

ECO N o. 97/2 Bernhard WINKLER

Of Sticks and Carrots: Incentives and the Maastricht Road to EMU

ECO N o. 97/3 James DOW/Rohit RAHI Informed Trading, Investment, and Welfare © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(27)

EC O No. 97/4 Sandrine LABORY

Signalling Aspects o f Managers’ Incentives

E C O N o. 97/5

Hnmherto Lf)PEZ/Eva ORTEGA/Angel UBIDE

Dating and Forecasting the Spanish Business Cycle

EC O N o. 97/6

Yitdira GONZALEZ de LARA

Changes in Information and Optimal Debt Contracts: The Sea Loan

EC O N o. 97/7 Sandrine LABORY

Organisational Dimensions o f Innovation EC O N o. 97/8

Sandrine LABQRY

Firm Structure and Market Structure: A Case Study o f die Car Industry EC O N o. 97/9

Elena BARDASI/Chiara MONFARDINI The Choice o f (he Working Sector in Italy: A Trivariate Probit Analysis ECO No, 97/10

Bernhard WINKLER

Coordinating Euippean Monetary Union ECO No, 97/U

Alessandra PELLONI/Robert WALDMANN

Stability properties in a Growth Model EC O Np. 9 7 /12

Alessandra PELLONI/Robert

WALDMANN

Can Waslp Improve Welfare? E C O N o, 9 7 /13

Christian DUSTMANN/Arthur van SOEST

PubliG and Private Sector Wages of Male Workers in Germany

E C 0 N o. 9 7 /14 Spren JOHANSEN

Mathematical and Statistical Modelling of Cointegration © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(28)

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(29)

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(30)

C O N IV I © The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(31)

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

(32)

© The Author(s). European University Institute. version produced by the EUI Library in 2020. Available Open Access on Cadmus, European University Institute Research Repository.

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

Eventually, in order to start a study that would take into account the greater complexity of the commuting phenomenon and consider a more realistic geographical dimension,

Commonly used plasmids present in the Registry of Standard Biological Parts enable a 40-fold copy number variation (from 5 copies per cell for low copy vectors to ∼ 200 copies per

On successful completion of this course the student should understand the fundamental concepts of both quantum and classical statistical mechanics and their applications to the

On successful completion of this course the student should understand the fundamental concepts of both quantum and classical statistical mechanics and their applications to the

Chandler &#34;introduction to modern statistical mechanics&#34; solution manuals, &#34;, Oxford University

Doitchinov introduced the notion of supertopological spaces in order to con- struct a unified theory of topological, proximity and uniform spaces, and he proved a certain

This includes the heteronomous portrayal of human creation presented in Prometheus Bound, as well as those parts of Antigone that Castoriadis chooses not to

This theory is based on the observation that in this patients, beyond to well known reduction in norepinephrine and serotonin contents, neurotrophins levels are