• Non ci sono risultati.

Institutions as the ultimate

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "Institutions as the ultimate"

Copied!
44
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

Institutions as the ultimate causes of growth

# 7

11 October 2016

(2)

The institutions hypothesis

The institutions are the “rule of the game”

they are determined by individuals (groups) as members of a society

they place constraints on behaviour

they shape behaviour by determining incentives

Institutions are humanly-devised, man-made

factors, vs geography (out of control) and culture (a very slowly changing variable)

They do not come out of the blue but are a complex product of choices and conditions

(3)

Efficient and inefficient institutions

Societies may chose different economic institutions. The efficient ones:

protection and enforcement of property rights partial or impartial judicial systems

financial arrangements (how much efficient is borrowing money for businesses?)

business and labour regulation (how much open and free is entering into a new line of business or occupations?)

education and training opportunities

(4)

Extractive vs inclusive institutions

Inclusive economic institutions are those

institutions that encourage the participation of the great/vast majority of the population in economic activities by best allocating talents and skills

Extractive economic institutions are those institutions shaped by those who control

political power to extract resources from the rest of the society

typically, a dictatorship, an absolute monarchy

(5)

A natural experiment of history:

North and South Korea

South Korea has a legal system in which private contracts are recognised (property rights) and enforced, a market economy allocating K and H, whilst North Korea has a dictatorship, the opposite of the rule of law

(6)

A second experiment:

Austria and her neighbours

(7)

A more reliable experiment?

“The West” and “the Rest”

A long-term growth process with diverging areas depending on sets of different

institutions is represented by how “the West” expanded after 1500

A larger number of observations

(countries), a longer term process (i.e., a larger sample over a longer time period) This experiment is a good test for the

institutions hypothesis

(8)

The reversal of fortune

When considering

“the Rest” a

reversal of fortune between differently colonised zones emerges

The poorer areas in 1500, proxied by urbanisation rates, are today the

richest areas across the world Why?

(9)

Understanding

the reversal of fortune 1/2

The geography hypothesis could argue that

poorer countries today are so because of less productive semitropical soils in comparison to temperate soils (North America)

But the opposite is true: in 1500 North America was poorer and other areas such India and North Africa were comparatively more

prosperous!

Europeans established more extractive

institutions in places that were more populated to funnel gold and agricultural surplus

(10)

Understanding

the reversal of fortune 2/2

On the contrary, Europeans set up more

inclusive institutions in areas that were less populated and developed

Such a simple strategy was conceived in order to extract wealth and income by controlling former empires (Aztec and Inca in America, Mogul in India): labour, riches, income flows whilst setting up inclusive institutions where

Europeans themselves were settlers, like in North America or in Australia and New

Zealand, i.e. scarcely populated areas

(11)

Urbanisation rate in 1500 and institutions in 1995

(12)

Population density in 1500 and institutions in 1995

(13)

Efficient institutions and settlers’ mortality

(14)

Inclusive institutions

as a key factor for growth

An environment where market participants are not harassed by excessive

regulations, or corruption, or paralysed by uncertainty about the future

will provide a better place in which actors

will work harder and invest more being

more able to innovate with a higher risk

taking and experimentation propensity

(15)

The great divergence

# 8

12 October 2016

(16)

The great divergence

Differences in prosperity (GDP per capita) in 1500 were relatively small

After 1500 some countries became richer while others lagged behind with low per capita

income

But when they became rich and inequality began to take place?

Between 1500 and 1800 the rich countries forged a small lead

Between 1820 and the present the income gap expanded with few exceptions

(17)

The great (and the little) divergence:

GDP per capita levels in 1990 international dollars

According to Broadberry

[2015] Britain and the Netherlands forged ahead of Italy and Spain in the 17th and 18th centuries, while Asian GDP per capita was lower even before the early modern period

England/

GB

Holland/

NL

Italy Spain Japan China India

725 551

900 476

980 1,247

1020 1,518

1050 1,458

1086 754 1,204

1120 1,063

1150 508

1280 679 957 552

1300 755 1,482 957

1348 777 876 1,376 1,030

1400 1,090 1,245 1,601 885 960

1450 1,055 1,432 1,668 889 552 983

1500 1,114 1,483 1,403 889 1,127

1570 1,143 1,783 1,337 990 968

1600 1,123 2,372 1,244 944 605 977 682

1650 1,110 2,171 1,271 820 619 638

1700 1,563 2,403 1,350 880 597 841 622

1750 1,710 2,440 1,403 910 622 685 573

1800 2,080 1,752 1,244 962 703 597 569

1850 2,997 2,397 1,350 1,144 777 594 556

(18)

GDP per capita around the world, 1820-2008 (US1990$)

In 1820 Europe (+

Western offshoots) was the richest

continent but there are

differences in

Europe as well (NL and UK)!

The richest countries in 1820 have grown the most

(19)

The divergence equation

Since 1820 the inequality has increased as the richest have grown constantly richer, whilst the poorest achieved modest income gains

Some exceptions in

Asia (and China may follow this pattern today)

(20)

A periodization of growth

The Mercantilist Era, 1500-1800 ca

from an integrated global economy to the Industrial Revolution

The Westerners Catch-up Era, 1800-1900

catch-up policies in Europe and USA made

industrialisation a priority

The Big-Push Era, 1900-present

closing the gap with the West by using planning and investment coordination

(21)

Models and growth strategies

1500-1800: a global economy

The “Atlantic trade”: Europe, Africa and Asia

European countries sought to increase trade and manufactures by colonies, tariffs and wars – de- industrialising colonies

1800-1900: catch-up strategies (a first variant)

creating a unified national market (tariffs &

transportation infrastructures)

protectionism (“levelling the playing field” vs UK)

modernising financial systems to stabilise currency and finance industrialisation (K)

mass education to upgrade the labour force (H)

(22)

Models and growth strategies

1900-present: the Big Push (a second variant)

The effective policies that had worked in Western Europe and USA proved to be less effective in backward countries

Most technology is created in rich countries to foster the productivity of expensive labour (N) by using more capital (K)

Such technologies are not always cost-effective in low-wage countries albeit that is what they need to catch up with the West

The Big Push: planning and investment coordination to jump ahead

(23)

How can we explain the great divergence?

Industrialisation and de-industrialisation have been major causes of the

divergence in world income

In 1750 most of the world’s manufacturing took place in China (33%) and the Indian subcontinent (25%)

In 1913 the world had been changed: the

UK, the USA and Europe accounted for

three-quarters of the total

(24)

The distribution of world’s manufacturing, 1750-2006

The Western World increased its manufacturing share up to the early 1970s reducing it after the East Asian miracle after WWII and recently because of the China’s industrialisation

If China and East Asia caught up with the West the world would come full circle to the starting point!

(25)

Why did China and India

de-industrialise in the XIX cent.?

The Asian decline as the workshop of the world in the XIX century was a decline in productivity

from exporting manufactures to exporting commodities (raw materials + primary goods) → a vicious circle, a poverty trap

The spread in labour productivity

deepened while Britain was

industrialising (and even more so after

industrialisation spread in the West)

(26)

The productivity differential

The great divergence is related to the differential in productivity, in turn

depending on technological trajectories

how much capital intensive and labour

saving?

Technological dynamics depend on the

incentives to use capital instead of labour

→ the relative prices (K and N) explain the

variance in technological capabilities

(27)

The real wages

To assess the incentive to use machinery (K) instead of labour (N), that is K/N, a

different measure than GDP per capita is adopted (hard to compute and misleading)

the real wages can solve this problem by calculating the living standard that can be bought with one’s earnings

the labourers’ living standard is obtained by comparing their wages to the averaged

prices of consumer goods (consumer price index)

(28)

The subsistance ratio for labourers

The consumer price index (CPI) is calculated as the cost of maintaining a man “at bare bones subsistence”

The graph shows the ratio of full-time earnings to the

family’s cost of subsistence (an exercise in comparing

“the breadwinner”)

A great divergence in real wages occurred within

Europe and between Europe and Asia

(29)

The subsistence ratio in London and Beijing in the very long run

The divergence in the

subsistence ratio between London (4 times) and

Beijing became

astonishingly clear-cut after 1850-70, up to fifty times Today the vast majority of

workers live at bare bones subsistence levels, with a 15% of the world population below the poverty line ($1 per day at 1990 values)

(30)

High wages

and economic growth

The real wages approach allows to assess living standard as the overall wellbeing:

longevity, health, height, education

high wages foster economic progress by sustaining good health and education

High wages are a good incentive to invent and adopt machinery to raise

productivity

Whilst the opposite is a sort of poverty trap

(31)

The industrial revolution

as a response to high wages

According to Allen the industrial revolution in England is not the cause of high

wages, but it was a creative response to high wages

The model is centred on relative prices:

high wages were a good incentive to save expensive labour, whereas low wages encourage the use of this factor as main input with cumulative and incremental effects over time: so the gap deepens…

(32)

The rise of the West

# 9

13 October 2016

(33)

The “Smithian growth”

Institutions, technological change and

economic policies matter, but they are to be put in the right context

The “Smithian growth” [Smith, 1776]:

institutions promoted peace, order and good government

as a result, trade flourished and regional specialisation increased, cities expanded income increased as a consequence of a

rise in productivity

(34)

The Smith’s model in a flow diagram

(35)

The first globalisation

The first globalisation began as soon as technological changes occurred in ship- building techniques

The newly invented full-rigged ship in the late XV cent. allowed to sail the high seas

(Columbus, Magellan, etc.)

The use of such vessels was conducive to the integration of international markets in

Europe first, across the world afterwards The grain market and the “new draperies” (a

shift from Italy to Flanders and England) The Voyages of Discovery by the Portuguese

in search of all-water routes to outcompete the Venetians (Vasco da Gama, 1498)

(36)

The quest for… pepper

The efficiency gains from all-sea routes may be measured by the price of pepper

The Portuguese benefited from the cut in transport costs keeping the price high and pocketing the

savings as profits

The arrival of English and Dutch East Indies Companies broke the Portuguese monopoly

The European consumers reaped most of the efficiency gains

(37)

A sea change in the sea routes

The Voyages of Discovery promoted a string of colonial empires

Spanish and Portuguese empires in the 16th century (the Americas; Brazil, Indian Ocean, Indonesia): but pursuing different strategies English and Dutch empires since the early 17th

century mingling imperialism with private enterprise (East Indies Companies, 1600, and VOC, 1602)

The Mediterranean routes lost weight and

the Oceans became the key trade axis

(38)

The Atlantic trade system

The Atlantic

trade system developed from the mid- 17th century and entailed a regional division and specialisation of labour

(39)

The European consequences

The growth of colonies in America and Asia boosted the European export-led

manufacturing, as well as cities (services) Dutch and English trade with their colonies

drove their economies forward as a higher level of the aggregate demand

provided room for specialisation of labour changed the occupational structure

accordingly

(40)

Changing economies

and the divergence within Europe

The occupational

structure shows the impact of colonial trade and empires on the European economies

The Mediterranean regions stagnated after 1500, thus a divergence took place in Europe

(41)

Globalisation and growth

The first globalisation transformed some countries (UK + NL) by fostering

urbanisation and export-led manufacturing which pushed up real wages

while a higher demand for primary goods stimulated an agricultural revolution (high farming)

and an energy revolution (coal in England) but high wages encouraged education as

well

(42)

The energy revolution

The emerging energy paradigm (coal) had a side effect on

technologies as it promoted related technological

progress in the 18th century, rather

consistent with labour saving incentives

and England has the largest coal mining industry in the world!

(43)

The human capital:

literacy as a very rough measure

The high-wage economy generated a high level literacy, numeracy and skill formation

Adult literacy in Europe rose everywhere, but the most in northwestern Europe The expansion of commerce

and manufacturing made education economically valuable

(44)

Summing up

Institutions are probably the ultimate cause of economic growth

But how can explain the great

(productivity) divergence between Asia and Europe?

Allen provides a basic model centred upon relative prices as incentives

fostering capital stock improvements

even before the industrial revolution

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

senti due brevi lettere, autografe, di Giovita scalvini indirizzate rispettivamente agli amici Giacinto Mompiani e Giovanni arrivabene all’inizio degli anni qua- ranta

From the remaining 4276 employees we selected for the cross-sectional survey a sample of 566 men who were frequency matched for age and country of origin across four levels of

Non sarei invece d'accordo con Parrini se, come certe formulazioni potrebbero indurre a sospettare ("Oggettività e verità non sono...una questione di tutto o nulla", ma

These include: (1) mixtures of hard-deadline periodics with aperiodic tasks having no deadlines (discussed in Section 2.5), (2) hard-deadline aperiodic tasks (discussed in Section

I giuristi, quelli di una certa fama, dispone- vano di uno staff di amanuensi e di personale subalterno, che collaboravano sia alla redazione degli originali che alla raccolta

Precisa- mente alla fine della strada, «appo la pietra del pesce», secondo Matteo Camera, dove è la loro loggia, già presente in età sveva, fatta ampliare nel 1269 da Carlo

Since the Buchberger algorithm implemented with MAPLE turns out to be more efficient when running by usual term orders, the use of global procedures PolyMilnor and PolyTyurina has to