• Non ci sono risultati.

The great divergence

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "The great divergence"

Copied!
41
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

The great divergence

# 10

21 March 2016

(2)

The great divergence

Differences in prosperity (GDP per capita) in 1500 were relatively small

After 1500 some countries became richer while others lagged behind with low per capita

income

But when they became rich and inequality began to take place?

Between 1500 and 1800 the rich countries forged a small lead

Between 1820 and the present the income gap expanded with few exceptions

(3)

The great (and the little) divergence:

GDP per capita levels in 1990 international dollars

According to Broadberry

[2015] Britain and the Netherlands forged ahead of Italy and Spain in the 17th and 18th centuries, while Asian GDP per capita was lower even before the early modern period

England/

GB

Holland/

NL

Italy Spain Japan China India

725 551

900 476

980 1,247

1020 1,518

1050 1,458

1086 754 1,204

1120 1,063

1150 508

1280 679 957 552

1300 755 1,482 957

1348 777 876 1,376 1,030

1400 1,090 1,245 1,601 885 960

1450 1,055 1,432 1,668 889 552 983

1500 1,114 1,483 1,403 889 1,127

1570 1,143 1,783 1,337 990 968

1600 1,123 2,372 1,244 944 605 977 682

1650 1,110 2,171 1,271 820 619 638

1700 1,563 2,403 1,350 880 597 841 622

1750 1,710 2,440 1,403 910 622 685 573

1800 2,080 1,752 1,244 962 703 597 569

1850 2,997 2,397 1,350 1,144 777 594 556

(4)

GDP per capita around the world, 1820-2008 (US1990$)

In 1820 Europe (+

Western offshoots) was the richest

continent but there are

differences in

Europe as well (NL and UK)!

The richest countries in 1820 have grown the most

(5)

The divergence equation

Since 1820 the inequality has increased as the richest have grown constantly richer, whilst the poorest achieved modest income gains Some exceptions in

Asia (and China may follow this pattern today)

(6)

A periodization of growth

The Mercantilist Era, 1500-1800 ca

from an integrated global economy to the Industrial Revolution

The Westerners Catch-up Era, 1800-1900 catch-up policies in Europe and USA made

industrialisation a priority

The Big-Push Era, 1900-present

closing the gap with the West by using planning and investment coordination

(7)

Models and growth strategies

1500-1800: a global economy

The “Atlantic trade”: Europe, Africa and Asia

European countries sought to increase trade and manufactures by colonies, tariffs and wars – de- industrialising colonies

1800-1900: catch-up strategies (a first variant)

creating a unified national market (tariffs &

transportation infrastructures)

protectionism (“levelling the playing field” vs UK)

modernising financial systems to stabilise currency and finance industrialisation (K)

mass education to upgrade the labour force (H)

(8)

Models and growth strategies

1900-present: the Big Push (a second variant)

The effective policies that had worked in Western Europe and USA proved to be less effective in backward countries

Most technology is created in rich countries to foster the productivity of expensive labour (N) by using more capital (K)

Such technologies are not always cost-effective in low-wage countries albeit that is what they need to catch up with the West

The Big Push: planning and investment coordination to jump ahead

(9)

How can we explain the great divergence?

Industrialisation and de-industrialisation have been major causes of the

divergence in world income

In 1750 most of the world’s manufacturing took place in China (33%) and the Indian subcontinent (25%)

In 1913 the world had been changed: the UK, the USA and Europe accounted for three-quarters of the total

(10)

The distribution of world’s manufacturing, 1750-2006

The Western World increased its manufacturing share up to the early 1970s reducing it after the East Asian miracle after WWII and recently because of the China’s industrialisation

If China and East Asia caught up with the West the world would come full circle to the starting point!

(11)

Why did China and India

de-industrialise in the XIX cent.?

The Asian decline as the workshop of the world in the XIX century was a decline in productivity

from exporting manufactures to exporting commodities (raw materials + primary goods) → a vicious circle, a poverty trap The spread in labour productivity

deepened while Britain was

industrialising (and even more so after industrialisation spread in the West)

(12)

The productivity differential

The great divergence is related to the differential in productivity, in turn

depending on technological trajectories how much capital intensive and labour

saving?

Technological dynamics depend on the

incentives to use capital instead of labour

→ the relative prices (K and N) explain the variance in technological capabilities

(13)

The real wages

To assess the incentive to use machinery (K) instead of labour (N), that is K/N, a

different measure than GDP per capita is adopted (hard to compute and misleading)

the real wages can solve this problem by calculating the living standard that can be bought with one’s earnings

the labourers’ living standard is obtained by comparing their wages to the averaged

prices of consumer goods (consumer price index)

(14)

The subsistance ratio for labourers

The consumer price index (CPI) is calculated as the cost of maintaining a man “at bare bones subsistence”

The graph shows the ratio of full-time earnings to the

family’s cost of subsistence (an exercise in comparing

“the breadwinner”)

A great divergence in real wages occurred within

Europe and between Europe and Asia

(15)

The subsistence ratio in London and Beijing in the very long run

The divergence in the

subsistence ratio between London (4 times) and

Beijing became

astonishingly clear-cut after 1850-70, up to fifty times Today the vast majority of

workers live at bare bones subsistence levels, with a 15% of the world population below the poverty line ($1 per day at 1990 values)

(16)

High wages

and economic growth

The real wages approach allows to assess living standard as the overall wellbeing:

longevity, health, height, education

high wages foster economic progress by sustaining good health and education High wages are a good incentive to invent

and adopt machinery to raise productivity

Whilst the opposite is a sort of poverty trap

(17)

The industrial revolution

as a response to high wages

According to Allen the industrial revolution in England is not the cause of high

wages, but it was a creative response to high wages

The model is centred on relative prices:

high wages were a good incentive to save expensive labour, whereas low wages encourage the use of this factor as main input with cumulative and incremental effects over time: so the gap deepens…

(18)

The rise of the West

# 11

22 March 2016

(19)

The “Smithian growth”

Institutions, technological change and

economic policies matter, but they are to be put in the right context

The “Smithian growth” [Smith, 1776]:

institutions promoted peace, order and good government

as a result, trade flourished and regional specialisation increased, cities expanded income increased as a consequence of a

rise in productivity

(20)

The Smith’s model in a flow diagram

(21)

The first globalisation

The first globalisation began as soon as technological changes occurred in ship- building techniques

The newly invented full-rigged ship in the late XV cent. allowed to sail the high seas

(Columbus, Magellan, etc.)

The use of such vessels was conducive to the integration of international markets in

Europe first, across the world afterwards The grain market and the “new draperies” (a

shift from Italy to Flanders and England) The Voyages of Discovery by the Portuguese

in search of all-water routes to outcompete the Venetians (Vasco da Gama, 1498)

(22)

The quest for… pepper

The efficiency gains from all-sea routes may be measured by the price of pepper

The Portuguese benefited from the cut in transport costs keeping the price high and pocketing the

savings as profits

The arrival of English and Dutch East Indies Companies broke the Portuguese monopoly

The European consumers reaped most of the efficiency gains

(23)

A sea change in the sea routes

The Voyages of Discovery promoted a string of colonial empires

Spanish and Portuguese empires in the 16th century (the Americas; Brazil, Indian Ocean, Indonesia): but pursuing different strategies English and Dutch empires since the early 17th

century mingling imperialism with private enterprise (East Indies Companies, 1600, and VOC, 1602)

The Mediterranean routes lost weight and the Oceans became the key trade axis

(24)

The Atlantic trade system

The Atlantic

trade system developed from the mid- 17th century and entailed a regional division and specialisation of labour

(25)

The European consequences

The growth of colonies in America and Asia boosted the European export-led

manufacturing, as well as cities (services) Dutch and English trade with their colonies

drove their economies forward as a higher level of the aggregate demand

provided room for specialisation of labour changed the occupational structure

accordingly

(26)

Changing economies

and the divergence within Europe

The occupational

structure shows the impact of colonial trade and empires on the European economies

The Mediterranean regions stagnated after 1500, thus a divergence took place in Europe

(27)

Globalisation and growth

The first globalisation transformed some countries (UK + NL) by fostering

urbanisation and export-led manufacturing which pushed up real wages

while a higher demand for primary goods stimulated an agricultural revolution (high farming)

and an energy revolution (coal in England) but high wages encouraged education as

well

(28)

The energy revolution

The emerging energy paradigm (coal) had a side effect on

technologies as it promoted related technological

progress in the 18th century, rather

consistent with labour saving incentives

and England has the largest coal mining industry in the world!

(29)

The human capital:

literacy as a very rough measure

The high-wage economy generated a high level literacy, numeracy and skill formation

Adult literacy in Europe rose everywhere, but the most in northwestern Europe The expansion of commerce

and manufacturing made education economically valuable

(30)

The industrial revolution

# 12

23 March 2016

(31)

A (peculiar) turning point

The industrial revolution represents a

turning point as it inaugurated the era of sustained economic growth

thus, income compounded to today’s levels Even though it was not an abrupt

discontinuity it marked a discontinuity at the end of the process of transformation The very point is that it was the first of a

string of industrial revolutions

(32)

The Britain’s GDP growth rate, 1700-1870

The pace of the annual GDP growth rate was relatively modest in the 18th century (circa 1,2% per year) [Broadberry et alii, 2011] compared to recent fast growth experiences (South Korea’s or China’s has grown as much as 8-10% per year)

(33)

Discontinuity from a gradual process: an oxymoron?

At the very end of the process Britain’s

economy appeared radically transformed But the industrial revolution in its making

was a gradual process

as the industrial sector was initially smaller than the others (agriculture + services) as Britain’s was extending the world’s

technology frontier (and that’s slower than importing a technology)

(34)

Why England?

Why did the industrial revolution occur in

England rather than in the Netherlands or in France? Or in China or India?

England had the right context

England had the right political institutions promoted the empire and the commerce as

the basis of the high-wage economy

favoured enclosures, canals and turnpikes by overriding property owners

supported the emerging scientific culture

(35)

Britain’s unique structure of wages and prices

The structure of prices may explain the

macroeconomic dynamics in Europe and Asia

The structure of prices and wages was unique and provided a peculiar set of incentives

high-wages (+ education) cheap energy (coal-mining)

relative low price of capital services

(36)

Less labour, more technology

British wages were high relative to the price of capital from the mid-17th century and even more subsequently (60% by the mid- 18th century)

So British firms had a strong incentive to mechanise production

less (expensive) labour, more (cheap) capital and energy

Technology (K + E) made labour more

productive → compatible with high wages

(37)

Wages relative to price of capital services

Since 1630 circa the ratio measuring the relative affordability of capital compared to labour split in Europe

In the early 1820s the differential between Europe (UK) and India restrained the adoption of capital intensive

technology in India with a negative impact on the Asian growth potential The same was true for

energy

(38)

The industrial revolution at work:

the cotton industry

Cotton was the first industry to be transformed by technology and organisational innovation (factory production)

Britain’s expansion came at the expense of

India, China and the Middle East (Calico Acts, 1710)

Internationalisation was the spur that led to the mechanisation of cotton spinning as

machines where profitable only in England technology adjusted to relative prices through

experimental engineering

(39)

The economics of machines

The economics of machines was quite simple incremental successive innovations made

spinning machines successful (Hargreaves, Arkwright, Crompton)

but they were actually cost saving only where the labour cost was high enough

Arkwright mill’s rate of return was 40% in England, 9% in France, 1% in India

So by the 1820s improved cotton machinery made profitable machines also on the

Continent (saving capital as well)

(40)

The steam engine

The steam engine was the key technology of the industrial revolution allowing mechanical power to be used in a wide range of

industries (factories, railways, ships)

the first general-purpose technology (GPT) As a spin-off of the scientific revolution (from

Galileo to Boyle and Papin) was a pan- European product

But it was economically profitable only in Britain (because of the cheap coal & expensive labour)

(41)

Continuing invention

The greatest feature of the industrial

revolution is that its innovations were not one-offs, but kicked off a stream of

innovations [Mokyr, 2005]

A GPT has a long-run pay-off effect thus explaining why economic growth (and

structural change) was so slow and gradual (up to the mid-19th century)

cumulative and incremental micro-innovations

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

coronación propiamente dicha, que se demorará hasta el siglo xii, pero la presen- cia, real –si la hubo– o simbólica –en imagen– del objeto, contribuye a afirmar el poder

For these reasons, simplification is an important issue of the model analysis process that, starting from the construction of the original detailed description, attempts to

Bruxelles.. Ces deux types d‘emprunt semblent aboutir à la même conclusion qui est celle d‘un „modèle‖ que tout le monde veut impérativement imiter, ce qui

Our results highlight that (a) in the first case analysed both the swept wing and the curved wing reached the flutter condition (at the sea level and cruise altitude) for a

Create an opportunity for teachers to be part of a wider community or network of learning: In many of the case studies, schools were motivated to engage with a programme

David Landes begins his book by suggesting that if it were possible to look around the world in 1000, few people would have guessed that Europe, and

First, we extend the meagre empirical evidence on venture capital and firms’ export engagement by shedding light on the effect that VCBA ownership may exert on the probability,