• Non ci sono risultati.

Venture capital investments and the technological performance of portfolio firms

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "Venture capital investments and the technological performance of portfolio firms"

Copied!
16
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

ContentslistsavailableatScienceDirect

Research

Policy

j ou rn a l h om ep a g e :w w w . e l s e v i e r . c o m / l o c a t e / r e s p o l

Venture

capital

investments

and

the

technological

performance

of

portfolio

firms

Henry

Lahr

a,b,1

,

Andrea

Mina

c,∗

aCentreforBusinessResearch,CambridgeJudgeBusinessSchool,UniversityofCambridge,TrumpingtonStreet,CambridgeCB21AG,UK

bDepartmentofAccountingandFinance,TheOpenUniversity,TheOpenUniversityBusinessSchool,WaltonHall,MiltonKeynesMK76AA,UK

cCambridgeJudgeBusinessSchool,UniversityofCambridge,TrumpingtonStreet,CambridgeCB21AG,UK

a

r

t

i

c

l

e

i

n

f

o

Articlehistory:

Received11July2014

Receivedinrevisedform13May2015

Accepted6October2015

Availableonline16November2015

JELclassification: O31 G24 L26 Keywords: Venturecapital Patenting Selection Signalling Innovation

a

b

s

t

r

a

c

t

Whatistherelationshipbetweenventurecapitalists’selectionofinvestmenttargetsandtheeffectsof

theseinvestmentsonthepatentingperformanceofportfoliocompanies?Inthispaper,wesetouta

modellingandestimationframeworkdesignedtodiscoverwhetherventurecapital(VC)increasesthe

patentingperformanceoffirmsorwhetherthiseffectisaconsequenceofpriorinvestmentselectionbased onfirms’patentoutput.WedevelopsimultaneousmodelspredictingthelikelihoodthatfirmsattractVC financing,thelikelihoodthattheypatent,andthenumberofpatentsappliedforandgranted.Fully accountingfortheendogeneityofinvestment,wefindthattheeffectofVConpatentingisinsignificant ornegative,incontrasttotheresultsgeneratedbysimplermodelswithindependentequations.Our findingsshowthatventurecapitalistsfollowpatentsignalstoinvestincompanieswithcommercially viableknow-howandsuggestthattheyaremorelikelytorationalise,ratherthanincrease,thepatenting outputofportfoliofirms.

©2015TheAuthors.PublishedbyElsevierB.V.ThisisanopenaccessarticleundertheCCBYlicense (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

1. Introduction

Newfirmscanrarelyrelyoninternalcashflowsintheirpursuit ofentrepreneurialopportunities.Amongthesourcesofexternal financeavailabletoentrepreneurs,venturecapital(VC)canprovide notonlythefinancialresourcestheyrequire,butalsoassistance toenhancethedesign,development,andperformanceofportfolio companies(Lerner,1995;BergemannandHege,1998;Gompers and Lerner,2001;De Clercqet al.,2006; Schwienbacher,2008; Cumming,2010).

Amongthedifferentdimensionsofentrepreneurialgrowththat theliteraturehasnoted,astrongassociationhasbeenidentified betweenVCinvestmentsandinnovation,oftenmeasuredbythe firm’spatentingoutput.Aprominentthesisisthatventure cap-italistsimproveinvesteefirms’innovativeperformancethrough theirabilityto‘coach’newbusinessesandtonurturethemto pro-ducegreatertechnologicaloutput(KortumandLerner,2000;Popov

∗ Correspondingauthor.Tel.:+441223765330.

E-mailaddresses:h.lahr@cbr.cam.ac.uk(H.Lahr),a.mina@jbs.cam.ac.uk

(A.Mina).

1 Tel.:+441908332648.

and Roosenboom, 2012).An alternative argument hasreceived relativelylessattentionasyet,althoughitsvaliditymayleadto adifferentconclusion:thatventurecapitalistsareexceptionally goodatidentifyingnewfirmswithsuperiortechnological capabili-ties,whichtheyseeasthebestinvestmentopportunities.Seenfrom thisangle,themostdistinctivetraitofVC,andthereforethemost salientexplanationforthestrongertechnologicalperformanceof VC-backedfirmsrelativetootherfirms,wouldbetheventure capi-talists’superiorselectioncapabilities(BaumandSilverman,2004). Venturecapitalistsfacearesourceallocationproblem charac-terisedbyhighriskandstronginformationasymmetries.Inorder todecreasetheseinformationasymmetries–giventhatpotential investeeshavelittleornotrackrecordsofmarketperformance– investorshavetorelyonothersignalsoffirmquality.Theseinclude theexantepatentingperformanceofpotentialinvestees(Häussler etal.,2012;Contietal.,2013b;HsuandZiedonis,2013),so patent-ingcanbeseenasanantecedentofVCinvestmentdecisions,aswell asalikelyconsequence.Disentanglingtherelationshipbetween VCinvestment and firms’technologicalperformance involvesa significanttheoreticalaswellasempiricalchallengebecauseof endogeneityandreversecausationbetweentheinvestmentand innovationprocesses.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2015.10.001

(2)

Thisisanimportantproblem,notonlyfromascholarly perspec-tivebutalsofromapolicyviewpoint.EventhoughtheVCsector financesonlyaminorityofnewfirms,itplaysaveryprominent roleinpoliciesdesignedtoovercomefinancegapsand togrow entrepreneurial,innovation-driveneconomies(OECD,2014).This rolehasnotgoneunquestioned:criticalissueshavebeenraised aboutscaleandskillsinthedemandandsupplyofventurefinance (Nightingaleet al.,2009), governance (Lerner, 2009), cyclicality andstagedistributionofinvestments(KaplanandSchoar,2005; Cummingetal.,2005;LahrandMina,2014),andtheoverallreturns andlong-termsustainabilityoftheVCinvestmentmodel(Mason, 2009;Lerner,2011;Mulcahyetal.,2012).Thesemakeitevenmore importanttogainaclearandaccurateunderstandingofthe VC-innovationnexus.

InthispaperwemodeltherelationbetweenVCandpatenting usingsimultaneousequationstoconsiderboththedeterminants ofVCinvestments,includingpatentsassignalsoffirmquality,and theeffectofVConfirms’post-investmentpatentingperformance, controllingfortheirpriorperformance.Weusedatafroman orig-inalsurveyof3669USandUKcompanies.Weextractinformation onthe940firmsthatsoughtfinancebetweentheyears2002and 2004andmatchthese recordswithpatent dataextractedfrom theEuropeanPatentOffice’sWorldwidePatentStatisticalDatabase (PatStat)fortheperiodsconcurrenttoandfollowingthesurvey years.Controllingforotherfirmcharacteristics(e.g.size,age,R&D expenditure,andmarketsize),weestimatesimultaneousmodels for(1) thelikelihood that firms’patenting activitiespredictVC investmentsand(2)thelikelihoodthatsuchinvestmentsleadto patentinginthefollowingperiod.Weemployabivariate recur-siveprobitmodelanddevelopasimultaneouszero-inflatedPoisson modelforcountdata,usingbothtocontrolfortheendogenous natureoftheselectionandcoachingprocesses.

Wedemonstrate that,oncewe accountfor endogeneity,the effectofVConthesubsequentpatentingoutputofportfolio compa-niesiseithernegativeorinsignificant.Theseresultsindicatethat, whileventurecapitalistspositivelyreacttopatentsassignalsof companieswithpotentially valuableknowledge,confirmingthe ‘selection’hypothesis,thereisnoevidenceofapositiveeffectofVC investmentonfirms’subsequentpatentingperformance.Itis plau-siblethatVCwillpositivelyinfluenceotheraspectsofnewbusiness growth(i.e.commercialisation,marketing,scalingup,etc.),butthe contributionofVCdoesnotseemtoinvolveincreasinginvestee firms’technologicaloutputs.Importantly,thefactthatthe techno-logicalproductivityofafirmmayslowdownafterVCinvestment doesnotimplythatthefirmwouldbebetteroffwithoutVC:onthe contrary,aninsignificantornegativeeffectofVConfirmpatenting suggeststhatventurecapitalistsrationalisetechnologicalsearches andfocusthefirm’sfiniteresources,includingmanagerial atten-tion,ontheexploitationofexistingintellectualproperty(IP)rather thanfurthertechnologicalexploration.

This paper advances our understanding of the financing of innovativefirms by modelling thedeterminants of investment choicesbyVCandthepatentingoutputoftheirportfolio compa-niesatthetimeofandafterVCinvestment.Insodoing,thepaper alsointroducesanoriginalmethodologythatcandisentanglethe endogenousrelationshipbetweenVCandpatentingefficiently,and hasthepotentialforfurtherusesintreatinganalogoustheoretical structures.

2. VCinvestmentsandpatenting:Theoryandevidence Investmentsinsmallandmedium-sizedbusinesses,andin par-ticularnew technology-basedfirms, posespecificchallenges to capitalmarketsbecausetheyinvolvehighrisksandstrong infor-mationasymmetries(Lerner,1995;Hall,2002).Fromaninvestor’s

viewpoint, theeconomic potentialof these firms is difficultto assess given their short history and the lack of external sig-nalsabouttheirquality(e.g.auditedfinancialstatements,credit ratings),orofmarketfeedbackaboutnewproductsandservices atthetimeofinvestment.Onlyfewinvestorsareableand will-ingtobackthesebusinesses.Theydosowiththeexpectationof satisfactoryreturnsbyapplyingaspecificsetofcapabilities,and oftensector-specificbusinessknowledge,thatenablethemtomake betterchoicesrelativetocompetinginvestors,handle technolog-icaland marketuncertainty,and activelyinfluencetheoutcome oftheirinvestments(Sahlman,1990;Gompers,1995;Hellmann, 1998;Gompersand Lerner,1999,2001;Kaplanand Strömberg, 2003,2004).

IntheextantstudiesthathaveaddressedthelinksbetweenVC andinnovation,onestreamhasfocusedontheabilityofventure capitaliststoassistportfoliocompaniesbygivingthemformaland informaladvice,thusaddingvalueinexcessoftheirfinancial con-tributions(GormanandSahlman,1989;Sapienza,1992;Busenitz etal.,2004;ParkandSteensma,2012).Asecondandmorerecent streamhasinsteademphasisedtheabilityofVCstousepatents assignalsoffirmqualityandtomakesuperiorchoices,relativeto otherinvestors,amongtheinvestmentoptionsthatareavailable tothem.Ifwhatmattersforthesubsequentperformanceof portfo-liocompaniesisthequalityoftheinitialinvestmentdecision,the sourceofventurecapitalists’competitiveadvantagerestsontheir selectioncapabilities,definedastheirabilitytoidentifytheinvestee companieswiththegreatestgrowthpotential(Dimovetal.,2007; Yangetal.,2009;Fitzaetal.,2009;ParkandSteensma,2012).In thefollowingtwosectionswereviewtheargumentsandevidence behindthesetwoperspectives.

2.1. TheeffectsofVConpatenting

Theproposition that venture capitalistsare ableto increase firmvaluebeyondtheprovisionoffinancialresourceshasgained considerable support in the literature (Gorman and Sahlman, 1989;Sahlman,1990;BygraveandTimmons,1992;Lerner,1995; KeuschniggandNielsen,2004;Croceetal.,2013),andisespecially clearwhentheyarecompared,forexample,tobanksinthesupply ofexternalfinancingtosmallandmedium-sizedenterprises(Ueda, 2004).Venturecapitalistscantakeactive rolesin manyaspects ofthestrategic andoperationalconductoftheirportfoliofirms, includingtherecruitmentofkeypersonnel,businessplan devel-opment,andnetworkingwithotherfirms,clientsandinvestors, oftenonthebasisofin-depthknowledgeoftheindustry(Florida and Kenney,1988; Hellmann and Puri,2000, 2002;Hsu, 2004; Sørensen,2007).

SeveralstudiesfindlinksbetweenVCinvestmentsandfirms’ patentingperformance,andgenerallyinterpretapositive associa-tionbetweenthetwoasaresultofthe‘value-adding’or‘coaching’ effectsofVC.Oneofthemostprominentstudiesonthistopicis KortumandLerner’s(2000)paper,inwhichtheauthorsmodeland estimateapatentproductionfunctioninaninvestmentframework. Aggregatingpatentnumbersbyindustry,theyfindapositiveand significanteffectofVCfinancingon(log)patentgrants1.Uedaand Hirukawa(2008)showthatthesefindingsbecomeevenmore sig-nificantduringtheventurecapitalboominthelate1990s.However, estimationsoftotalfactorproductivity(TFP)growthrevealthat thiswasnotaffectedbyVCinvestment,aresultthatcontrastswith

1Bothpatentingandventurefundingcouldberelatedtounobserved

techno-logicalopportunities,therebycausinganupwardbiasinthecoefficientonventure

capital,butregressionsthatuseinformationaboutpolicyshiftsinventurefund

legislationtoconstructaninstrumentalvariablealsoshowpositiveimpactsofVC

(3)

Chemmanuretal.’s(2011)study,whichrevealsapositiveeffect ofVConTFP.PopovandRoosenboom(2012)alsofindsimilar posi-tive,althoughweaker,resultsforsucheffectsinEuropeancountries andindustries.Furtherestimationsofautoregressivemodelsfor TFPgrowthand patentcountsbyindustryseemtosuggestthat TFPgrowthispositivelyrelatedtofutureVCinvestment,butthere isweaker evidencethat VCinvestmentsprecedeanincrease in patentingattheindustrylevel,andthereareindicationsthatlagged VCinvestmentsareoftennegativelyrelatedtobothTFPgrowthand patentcounts(HirukawaandUeda,2008).

Empirical firm-level studies on venture capital investments tendtoconfirmtheexistenceofapositiverelationbetweenVC andpatentingperformance(Arqué-Castells,2012;Bertonietal., 2010;Zhang,2009).Thispattern isnotonlyfoundfor indepen-dentbutalsoforcorporateventurecapital(Alvarez-Garridoand Dushnitsky,2012;ParkandSteensma,2012).Lerneretal.(2011) estimate various models, includingPoisson and negative bino-mial models, for patents granted and patent citations in firms thatexperiencedprivateequity-backedleveragedbuyouts(LBOs). Theyfindanincreasednumberofcitationsforpatentapplications post-LBOandnodecreaseinpatentoriginalityandgeneralityafter suchinvestments. Patentcounts do notseem tovary ina uni-formdirection.AstudybyEngelandKeilbach(2007)foundthat VC-backedfirmsapplyfortentimesasmanypatentsasmatched non-VCbacked firms: theauthorsusepropensityand balanced scorematchingtocompareventure-fundedtonon-VCfunded Ger-man firms in terms of theirtechnologicaloutputs and growth, althoughthisdifferencewasonlyweaklysignificant.Casellietal. (2009)useasimilarmatchingproceduretoassessthedifference inthepatentingandgrowthperformancesintheventure-backed IPOsofItalianfirms.Theirresultsshowahigheraveragenumber ofpatentsintheventure-backedfirmsthanintheircontrolgroup. Importantly,however,noneofthesestudiesprovidessolutionsto thefundamentalproblemoftheendogeneityofinvestmentrelative tofirms’technologicalperformance2.

2.2. Investmentselection

The second hypothesis that might explain the correlation betweenVCinvestmentandfirms’technologicalperformanceis thatventurecapitalistshavedistinctiveselectioncapabilities.This impliesamodellingframeworkinwhichtheinnovativeprofilesof potentialinvesteefirmsaffecttheprobabilitythattheyreceiveVC investment.Fromthisperspective,patentscanfunctionassignals toinvestorsaboutfirmquality(BaumandSilverman,2004;Mann andSager,2007;Häussleretal.,2012;Audretschetal.,2012;Conti etal.,2013a,b;HsuandZiedonis,2013).

Thereareseveraldimensionstotheinvestmentevaluation pro-cessemployedbyventurecapitalists(Shepherd,1999),andthere isgrowinginterestinthetechnologicaldeterminantsofventure financing.BaumandSilverman(2004)exploredthelinksbetween VCfinancing,patentapplications,andpatentsgranted.Their find-ingssuggestthattheamountofVCfinanceobtaineddependson laggedpatentsgranted andappliedfor,R&D expenditures,R&D employees,governmentresearchassistance,theamountof sector-specificventurecapital,horizontalandverticalalliances,andthe investeefirmbeingauniversityspin-off.Ageisnegativelyrelated toventurecapital,asarenetcashflows,diversification,and

indus-2Tothebestofourknowledge,Croceetal.(2013)istheclosestattempttodate

toaddresssampleselectionproblemsinthecontextofthevalue-added

hypoth-esis.However,thisinterestingstudydoesnotconsideranyinnovationindicators

anditsanalysisofportfoliocompanies’productivitygrowthislimitedbytheuse

ofonlyasmallsetofbasicfirmcharacteristics.OurpaperdoesnotfocusonTFP

estimates—insteadweexploreinsomedetailthetechnologicaloutputoffirmsin

relationtoentrepreneurialfinancedecisions.

tryconcentration. Mannand Sager (2007) confirm thepositive impactofpatentingonVC-relatedperformancevariables,including thenumberoffinancingrounds,totalinvestmentandexitstatus. Similarly,astart-upfirm’spriorpatentingattractgreateramounts ofVCfundsinCaoandHsu’s(2011)studyofventure-backedfirms. Häussleretal.(2012)elaborateonSpence’s(2002)signalling theorytoarguethatthefoundersofentrepreneurialfirmsare bet-terinformedaboutthequalityoftheventurethanarepotential investors,andthattheyusepatentsascommunicationdevicesto bridgethisinformationgap.Patentsareeffectivesignalsof qual-ityonthegroundsthat, astheyareproducedat acost (inthis casethefeesassociatedwiththepatentingprocess),low-quality agentswilltendtobeweededout.Theirempiricalanalysis con-firmsthatpatentapplicationshaveapositiveeffectonthehazard rateofVCfundinginasampleofBritishandGermanbiotech com-panies. Thesefindings resonate withprior resultspresentedby EngelandKeilbach(2007),whoseprobitmodellingofVC invest-mentrevealsapositiveassociationwithpatentsandthefounder’s humancapital. Alonga similarlineof enquiry –albeit setin a broaderPenrosian framework thanthat usedby Häussleretal. (2012)–HsuandZiedonis(2013)analyseVC-financedstart-ups intheUSsemiconductorsector.Theyshowthat,bybridging infor-mationasymmetries,patentsincreasethelikelihoodofobtaining initialcapitalfromaprominentVC,andhavepositiveeffectson fundraisingandIPOpricing(conditionalonIPOexit).

Bybringingthesestreamsofcontributionstogether,weaimto answerthequestion:Doesventurecapitalpositivelycontributeto thepatentingperformanceoffirmsorisitaconsequenceof ven-turecapitalists’abilitytoidentifythebestcompaniesatthetimeof investment?Resultsbasedonfirm-levelinformationaremixed, which suggeststhatpositive findingscouldbeatleastpartially drivenbyVC’sselectionofcompaniesonthebasisoftheircurrent patentoutput.Wecanonlyshedlightontheeffectsofcoaching vis-à-vistheselectionfunctionofVCifwetakeintoaccountthe endogeneityoftherelationbetweenVCinvestmentandthe tech-nologicalperformanceoffirms.Ourresearchstrategyisthereforeto model,test,andevaluateinasimultaneoussetting(1)theeffectof VConthepatentingperformanceofportfoliofirmspostinvestment and(2)theeffectoffirms’patentingperformanceontheprobability ofattractingVC.

3. Dataandmethodology 3.1. Data

ThispaperbuildsonauniquecomparativesurveyofU.K.andU.S. businessescarriedoutjointlybytheCentreforBusinessResearch attheUniversityofCambridgeandtheIndustrialPerformance Cen-teratMITin2004–2005.ThebasisforthesamplingwastheDun& Bradsheet(D&B)database,whichcontainscompany-specific infor-mationdrawnfromvarioussources,includingCompaniesHouse, Thomson Financial, and press and trade journals3. The sample coveredallmanufacturingandbusinessservicesectors,andwas stratifiedbysectorandemploymentsize(10–19;20–49;50–99; 100–499;500–999;1000–2999;and3000+),withlarger propor-tionstaken in the smallersize bands,as in both countries the vastmajority(over98%)offirmsemployfewerthan100people. ThedatawerecollectedviatelephonesurveysbetweenMarchand November2004(responserates:18.7%fortheU.S.and17.5%for

3ThechoiceoftheDun&Bradstreetdatabasewasmotivatedbyitsbroadcoverage

ofsmallfirms,whicharekeyforstudyingventurecapitalinvestments.Good

cover-ageofSMEsisalsothereasonwhytheEuropeanCentralBankusesthisdatabasefor

itssurveyontheaccesstofinanceofSMEsintheeuroarea(SAFE);seehttp://www.

(4)

theU.K.),followedbyapostalsurveyoflargefirmsinspring2005 leadingtoatotalsampleof1540U.S.firmsand2129U.K.firms.

Werestrictoursampletofirmsthatactivelysoughtfinance dur-ingthetwo yearspriortobeinginterviewed,whichproduces a workingsampleof940firms(513intheU.S.and427intheU.K.). ThesurveylistsVCfundsandbusinessangelsaspossiblesources ofexternalfinance.Despitesomedifferencesinstagesandsizes ofinvestments,geographicproximity,andmotivationfor invest-ments(Ehrlichetal.,1994), bothventurecapitalistsandangels spendconsiderabletimewithfirms’managementteams,andmake substantialnon-financialcontributionsinadditiontotheir finan-cialcommitments,includingworkinghands-onintheirday-today operations(Kerret al., 2014;Haines et al.,2003; Harrison and Mason,2000).Sincebothformalandinformalventurecapitalists canperformsimilarfunctionsfromourstudy’sviewpoint,wepool observationsfor thesetwo classes of activeinvestors, although when we perform robustness tests with separate samples,the resultsareconsistentwithourmainanalyses(Section5.3). Infor-mationabouttheeventofaVCinvestmententersourmodelsasan endogenousbinaryvariable.

Firms answered the survey questions almost completely, althoughminorgapsinthedatawouldhavepreventedusfrom usingabout10% ofthesurvey responses.In ordertoavoid the lossofobservationsduetomissingvalues,weuserandom regres-sionimputationtoapproximatethem(GelmanandHill,2006).The numberofsuchimputationsisgenerallyverylow—alwayslessthan 2%pervariable.Wheredependentvariablevaluesaremissing,we dropthoseobservations.

PatentdataaretakenfromtheEuropeanPatentOffice’s(EPO) WorldwidePatentStatistical Database(PatStat), which contains informationon68.5millionpatent applicationsby17.3million assigneesandinventorsfrom1790to2010.Sincetherearenofirm identifiersavailableinPatStat,wematchpatentinformationtoour surveydatabyfirmname.Weconsiderfirms’globalpatent port-folios,andcountallapplicationstodifferentpatentauthoritiesfor similaroroverlappingknow-howasmultiplepatentingevents.To alignpatentdatawiththethreeyearperiodaddressedinthe sur-vey,wecountthenumberofpatentsappliedforandgrantedwithin athree-yearperiodpriortotheinterview(calculatedfromexact surveyresponsedates),anddetermineeachfirm’spatentingstatus fromthisnumber.Morespecifically,weuseapplicationfilingand publicationsdatesforthefirstgrantofanapplicationtodetermine thetimingsofpatentingevents.Forourdependentvariables,we countapplicationsandgrantsforthewholepost-surveyperiodin ordertocapturethelong-termeffectsofVCinvestment.Finally, weincludeadummyvariableforthefirmbeingbasedintheUSor theUKtocontrolfordifferentpropensitiestopatent–and likeli-hoodofgrant–indifferentdomesticinstitutionalenvironments. Weabstainfromusingforwardcitation-weightedindicators for patents,acontrolforpatentqualitythatisespeciallyusefulin stud-iesofperformance,becausesuchcitationsmaybeaffectedbythe likelihoodofinvestment,andmaythusintroduceafurthersource ofendogeneityintothisanalyticalcontextthatwouldbeimportant toavoid.

Table1showsdescriptivestatisticsforoursamplefirms’ patent-ingactivitiesandourindependentvariables.146firmsfromour sampleappliedforpatentsduringthethree-yearsurveyperiod(t), and168filedpatentapplicationsinthenextperiod(t+1).We iden-tifiedpatentgrantsin115and141firmsintheserespectiveperiods. 96firmsgainedventurecapitalorbusinessangelfinancinginabout equalproportionsinthetwoyearspriortothesurvey.Asimple cross-tabulationofindicatorsforVCfinancingandforpatenting activityatt(seeTable2)highlightsthestronglinkbetween ven-turecapitalandpatenting.Itshowsthat56.2%ofVC-financedfirms appliedforpatentsinanyoftheperiods,whereasonly18.2%of thosewithoutVCfundingdidso.Butthispicturebeginstolook

differentwhenweconsiderchangesinthepatentingstatusacross periods.Inthenon-VCfinancedgroup,firmsseemtostartpatenting attimet+1moreoftenthantheystopapplyingafterpatentingat timet.Incontrast,thenumbersoffirmsintheVC-financedgroup thatstart patentingat timet+1balancethose thatdiscontinue theirpatentingactivitiesafterperiodt4.Includingadditional con-trolvariablesinourmultivariateanalysesgivesusamuchmore preciseassessmentofthesestatetransitions.

Theinclusionofexplanatoryvariablesbuildsonpriorstudies intotherelationshipbetweenVCandpatenting,whichhaveoften usedaverylimitednumberofco-determinants,sometimesonly R&Dexpenditures.Weextendthescopeoftherelevantpredictors forthepropensitytopatent,ofwhichR&Dintensityisthepreferred choiceaccordingtostandard practiceintheliterature(Scherer, 1965,1983;PakesandGriliches,1980;Pakes,1981;Hausmanetal., 1984).Since prior research hasused various measures for this intensity,includingthelogofR&D expenditures,R&D expendi-turesscaledbysizevariables,orthenumberofR&Demployees, wechooseasuitablecombinationoftheseindicators.Weproxyfor sizebytakingthelogarithmofemploymentandcontrolforR&D intensitybyincludingthepercentageofR&Dstaffandadummy indicating thepresence ofR&D expenditures. Thisallows usto avoidtheuseofmultiplesize-dependentmeasures,sincevariables entertheexpectedmeaninPoissonspecificationsmultiplicatively. Furthervariablescontrolforage,countryandindustry.Following Scherer(1983),weusetheamountofinternationalsalestomeasure marketsizeandcontrolforindustryconcentrationbythenumberof competitors.WemeasureCEOeducationbyadummyvariable indi-catingwhethertheCEOhasauniversitydegreeornot.Thelength oftheaverageproductdevelopmenttimeinthefirms’principal productmarketisalsocontrolledfor,sinceitarguablyplaysarole inattractinginvestment(HellmannandPuri,2000).Finally,given thehighlycumulativenatureoftechnicalchange(Dosi,1988)we includelaggedpatentapplicationsandgrantsasproxiesforthe firm’sknowledgestocksthatitusestoproducenewpatents5. 3.2. Modelsandestimation

The structure of firms’ patenting decisions presents several econometric challenges. Previous research shows that the vast majorityoffirmsdonotpatent,whichcausesobservationsofzero patentsin alargeproportion offirms leadingin turntomodel instabilityanderrordistributions thatdo notmeet themodel’s assumptions if these excess zeroes are not properly addressed (Boundetal.,1984;Hausmanetal.,1984).Atthesametime, unob-servableheterogeneityis highlylikelytobecorrelated between VC investment and patenting performance: for example, firms mightdisclosepatentingactivitiestoprospectiveinvestors,which increasesthelikelihoodthatweobserveVCinvestmentsin com-bination with more patenting in the future. When using VC investment to explain patenting, this endogeneity complicates modelestimationandmaymakeitanalyticallyintractable6.

We suggest that patenting involves a two-step process, in which firmsfirstdecidewhethertousepatenting asa suitable IPprotectionstrategy and then producepatentsaccording toa Poisson orsimilardistribution (seeFig.1).Followingthis logic,

4Lesssurprisingly,forpatentgrantstheproportionoffirmsthatstart

receiv-inggrantscomparedwiththosethatstopafterreceivingatleastonegrantinthe

previousperiodishigherforVC-fundedfirms.

5Inclusionoflaggeddependentvariablesalsohelpstoaccountforunobserved

heterogeneity.

6Asimilarchallenge,also associated with mixedempirical evidence,

char-acterisesstudiesofVCinvestmentsandthefinancialperformanceofportfolio

companies.Confront,forexample,SteierandGreenwood(1995)andBusenitzetal.

(5)

Table1

Descriptivestatistics.

Variable Mean Median Std.Dev. Min Max Description

Anyapplicationsint+1 0.179 0 0.383 0 1

Patentapplicationsint+1 4.118 0 34.241 0 779 Numberofpatentapplicationsbythefirmintheperiodafter

thesurvey

Anygrantsint+1 0.150 0 0.357 0 1

Patentgrantsint+1 2.746 0 30.337 0 889 Numberofpatentgrantstothefirmintheperiodafterthe

survey

Anyapplicationsint 0.155 0 0.362 0 1

Patentapplicationsint 3.266 0 25.347 0 526 Numberofpatentapplicationsbythefirmintheperiodthree

yearspriortothesurvey

Anygrantsint 0.122 0 0.328 0 1

Patentgrantsint 1.176 0 9.972 0 273 Numberofpatentgrantstothefirmintheperiodthreeyears

priortothesurvey

VCinvestment 0.102 0 0.303 0 1 Thefirmobtainedformalorinformalventurecapitalinthe

three-yearperiodpriortothesurvey

Age(log) 2.937 2.996 0.858 0.693 5.720 Thenaturallogarithmofthefirm’sageinyears.

Size(log(employees)) 3.848 3.714 1.059 1.099 6.804 Thenaturallogarithmofthenumberofemployeesinthemost

recentfinancialyear

U.S.firm 0.546 1 0.498 0 1 ThefirmhasitsheadquartersintheUnitedStates.Dummy

variable

Medium-hightechmanuf. 0.310 0 0.463 0 1 Thefirmisamedium-hightechmanufacturingfirmaccording

totheOECD(2005)Science,TechnologyandIndustry Scoreboard

Medium-lowtechmanuf. 0.381 0 0.486 0 1 Thefirmisamedium-lowtechmanufacturingfirm

R&Dservices&software 0.117 0 0.322 0 1 ThefirmisanR&Dserviceorsoftwarefirm.

Otherservices 0.153 0 0.360 0 1 ThefirmisaservicefirmotherthanR&Dorsoftware

Otherindustry 0.039 0 0.195 0 1 ThefirmoperatesunderaSICcodenotcoveredabove

R&Dexpend.(yes/no) 0.732 1 0.443 0 1 ThefirmhasR&Dexpenditures.Dummyvariable

R&Dstaff 0.073 0 0.175 0 1 Full-timeR&Dstaffasaproportionoftotalstaff.

CEOhasadegree 0.637 1 0.481 0 1 Thefirm’sChiefExecutiveorMDhasadegree.Dummyvariable

Marketsize 1.747 2 0.912 0 3 Sizeofthefirm’smarket.Codedasordinal0=local,

1=regional,2=national,3=international,treatedascardinal

Competitors(log) 1.987 1.792 1.012 0 6.909 Numberofcompaniesthatthefirmregardsasserious

competitorsplusone,inlogs

Productdev.time 0.971 1 1.048 0 4 Averagetimeittakestodevelopanewproductfrom

conceptiontothemarket.Codedasordinal0=lessthan6 monthsto4=morethan5years,treatedascardinal

Table2

Venturecapitalandpatentingstatus.

NoVC(n=844):Applicationsint+1 VC(n=96):Applicationsint+1 NoVC(n=844):Grantsint+1 VC(n=96):Grantsint+1

Applicationsint No(%) Yes(%) No(%) Yes(%) No(%) Yes(%) No(%) Yes(%)

No 81.8 6.0 43.8 11.5 85.4 4.7 51.0 15.6

Yes 3.4 8.8 11.5 33.3 2.7 7.1 6.3 27.1

Notes.Thistablepresentsthefractionoffirmsineachpresentandfuturepatentingstatusdependentonventurecapitalinvestment.Rowentriesarethenumberoffirms withanynumberofpatentapplicationsattimet.Columnsshowthenumberoffirmsapplyingfororbeinggrantedanynumberofpatents.

Fig.1.Modelframework.Notes.Dependentvariablesareventurecapitalinvestmentattimetandthenumberofpatentapplicationsorgrantsattimet+1.Inthebinary bivariatecase,“Patents(yes/no):”measureswhetherweobserveanynumberofpatentsforthefirmattimet+1.Inzero-inflatedPoissonmodelsthatalsoincludethenumber ofpatentsatt+1,thisvariableindicatesfirms’latentpatentingstatus.

(6)

wemodelpatentingactivityasabinaryvariablethatdependson

firmandindustrycharacteristicsandaugmentourmodelswithan

endogenousbinaryvariablethatindicateswhetherornotafirm

receivesventurecapitalfinancing.Insteadofrelyingon

propen-sityscorematchingorcomparablealgorithmstoidentifyacontrol

groupofnon-VCbackedfirms,wehavetheadvantagethatwecan

workwith‘treatment’and‘control’datathataregenerated

contem-poraneouslybythesurvey7.Ourdataallowustoidentifyfirmsthat

soughtexternalfinance,andthoseofthemthatobtainedventure finance.Theexplicitconsiderationoffinance-seekingbehaviours, usuallyneglectedintheliterature,strengthensthequalityofour sampleandtheprecisionofourresults.

Weestimatetwo setsofsimultaneousequations:Inthefirst set,whichcontainstwoprobitequationsforpatentingandventure capitalinvestments,weignoreinformationaboutthenumberof patentsandtreatfirms’patentingbehavioursasbinaryoutcomes. Inthesecondsetweintroducethenumberofpatentsina zero-inflatedPoissonmodel.

Thepatentingequationintherecursivebivariatesystemis Pati,t+1=I



Xit0+1Patit+2ln (PatNit)+1VCit+εit>0



, (1) wherePatitisadummyvariableindicatingwhetherfirmiapplied foroneormorepatentsor,dependingoncontext,wasgrantedat leastonepatentperiodt.PatNitdenotesthenumberofpatent appli-cationsorpatentsgranted.TheindicatorfunctionI(·)equalsoneif theconditioninparenthesesholdsandzerootherwise.Sincepatent applicationsandgrantscanbezero–inwhichcasethenatural log-arithmwouldnotexist–wesetln(PatNit)tozeroanduseadummy variable(Patit)toindicatepatentingstatus.Endogenousventure capitalinvestmentiscapturedbyanindicatorvariable(VCit),and Xitrepresentsexogenousvariables.Thesimultaneouslydetermined venturecapitalinvestmentis:

VCit=I



Zitˇ0+ˇ1Patit+ˇ2ln (PatNit)+it>0



, (2)

whereZitisavectorofexogenousexplanatoryvariableswhichcan containsomeoralloftheelementsinXit.Endogeneityofventure capitalfinancingisaccountedforbyallowingarbitrarycorrelation betweentheerrorterms.Sincevarianceoferrortermsisnot iden-tifiedinbinarymodels,theerrortermsεitanditarenormalisedto haveavarianceofunity.

Asimilarsimultaneousmodelstructurecanbeusedtopredict thenumberofpatents.Sincepatentdatashowalargenumberof non-patentingfirms,wemodelthisempiricalregularity usinga zero-inflatedPoissondistribution.Inthismodel,firmsself-select intothepatentingregime,andathirdequationmodelsthenumber ofpatentapplicationsorgrantsproducedaccordingtoaPoisson distribution.AsinLambert’s(1992)zero-inflatedPoissonmodel, thenumberofpatentsisdistributedas:

PatNi,t+1 =



0 withprobability pit+ (1−pit)e−it k withprobability (1−pit)e−ititk/k!, k=1,2,... (3)

7 ThisapproachdiffersfromParkandSteensma’s(2012)andContietal.’s(2013b).

Incontrasttothesestudies,wehavedataonfirmsthatreceivedinvestmentandfirms

thatdidnot,becauseoursamplingwasnotguidedbyVCinvestmentevents.This

enablesustospecifyanappropriatetestforselection(investment)insteadofatest

forthetypeofinvestmentafirmmayhavereceivedwhenallthefirmsintheirsample

havereceivedsomeinvestments(i.e.wherethereisnocounterfactualof‘noVC

investment’).Contietal.(2013a),instead,haveno-VCinvestmentcounterfactuals

attheirdisposal,buttheirfocusisdifferent,astheyareinterestedintherelative

sensitivityofVCandbusinessangelinvestorstoheterogeneousinvestmentsignals.

Moreover,theyoptforamoretraditionaltwo-stageleastsquareslinearprobability

modeltotreatendogeneityofinvestment.

Thelikelihoodthatafirmchoosesnottopatentinthenextperiod is

pit=I



Xit0+1Patit+2ln (PatNit)+1VCit+εit



, (4) whiletheconditionalmeanofthePoissonprocessinthepatenting stateis it=exp



Xitı0+ı1Patit+ı2ln (PatNit)+NVCit+ωit



(5) Anovelfeatureofourmodelisthatafirm’slikelihoodof obtain-ingventurecapitalisdeterminedbyanadditionalequation: VCit=I



Zitˇ0+ˇ1Patit+ˇ2ln (PatNit)+it>0



(6) asinthebivariateProbitcaseabove.

Weallowforarbitrarycontemporaneouscorrelationbetween it and εit,as well asbetween it and ωit, which are assumed tofollowbivariatenormaldistributions.Specifyingthemodelin thiswayallowsforcorrelationbetweenheterogeneityinexpected meansofpatentcounts,thedecisiontopatentandVCfinancing.The varianceofindividual-levelerrors(ωit)introducesafree parame-terthataccountsforover-dispersioninPoissonmodels(Miranda andRabe-Hesketh,2006).Identificationinsemiparametric mod-elsofbinarychoicevariablesoftenreliesonexclusionrestrictions (Heckman,1990;Taber,2000)—inourparametriccase,however, thefunctionalformissufficientforidentification.Infact,imposing additionalrestrictionsonourmodelcouldcausespuriousresults, sincevariablesincludedintheVCequationbutexcludedfromthe patentingequationswouldaffecttheoutcomeequationthrough VCitif thosevariables werenottrulyindependentfrom patent-ing.Wethereforechoosetheexogenousvariablestobeidentical inallequations(Xit=Zit).Section5.4describesadditionalresults obtainedfromrobustnessteststhatuseexclusionrestrictionsin thepatentingequation(s).

Inthefollowingsectionwepresenttheresultsofbivariate recur-siveprobit modelsfor VCfinancing and patenting (i.e., results forthesimultaneousestimationofEqs.(1)and(2)andthenthe resultsweobtainfromthesystemofequationscompletewiththe zero-inflatedPoissonmodel(i.e.,Eqs.(3)to(6)),estimatedby max-imumsimulatedlikelihood(GouriérouxandMonfort,1996;Train, 2009)8. We alsoreport results of zero-inflated Poisson models thatincludeinformationaboutthenumberofpatents,butexclude simultaneousVCinvestmentasourbaselineresultsforthe com-pletesystemofequations(seeTable5).Astermsofcomparisons andtoshowhowkeyresultsdifferwhenendogeneityisnottaken intoaccount,weincluderesultsofindependent(single-equation) probitmodelsasrobustnesschecks(Table6).

4. Results

Wefindthatthecorrelationsbetweenventurecapital invest-ment and subsequent patenting are substantial and highly significant, ranging between 0.21 for (log) patent applications and 0.26 for a dummyvariablemeasuring whethera firm was grantedanypatentsafterreceivingVCinvestment.Thispositive linkcouldbeduetotechnologicalcoachingorselection.Aswe con-structincreasinglycompletemodelsfortherelationbetweenVC investmentandpatenting,thecoachingeffectdisappears.Table3 presentstheresultsfromoursimultaneousmodelthatjointly pre-dictspatentingandventurecapitalinvestment.

8Weusesubscriptstandt+1todistinguishbetweentheperiodsconcurrent

toandfollowingthesurvey.Weuse200randomdrawsinallmodelsestimated

bymaximumsimulatedlikelihood.Furtherestimationdetails,includinglikelihood

(7)

Table3

PatentingandVCinvestment—simultaneousequations.

Dependentvariableinpatentingequation Applicationsint+1 Grantsint+1 Grantsint+1

Model 1 2 3

Dependentvariableinpatentingequation Patenting(yes/no) VCinvestment Patenting(yes/no) VCinvestment Patenting(yes/no) VCinvestment

VCinvestment −0.673(0.34)** −0.175(0.52) −0.444(0.37)

Patentapplications(log) 0.455(0.12)*** −0.095(0.08) 0.568(0.13)*** −0.098(0.08)

Patentapplications>0 1.059(0.21)*** 0.609(0.20)*** 1.635(0.22)*** 0.614(0.20)***

Patentgrants(log) 0.534(0.16)*** −0.170(0.12)

Patentgrants>0 1.206(0.22)*** 0.434(0.23)*

Age(log) 0.083(0.08) −0.344(0.09)*** 0.010(0.11) −0.344(0.09)*** 0.088(0.10) −0.342(0.09)***

Size(log(employees+1)) 0.155(0.06)*** 0.197(0.07)*** 0.058(0.07) 0.213(0.07)*** 0.027(0.07) 0.206(0.07)***

U.S.firm 0.053(0.14) −0.334(0.13)** 0.279(0.17)* −0.327(0.14)** 0.320(0.18)* −0.332(0.14)**

Medium-hightechmanuf. 0.095(0.29) −0.226(0.29) −0.084(0.34) −0.203(0.30) −0.254(0.27) −0.251(0.28)

Medium-lowtechmanuf. −0.223(0.30) −0.375(0.29) −0.463(0.35) −0.389(0.29) −0.566(0.28)** −0.400(0.29)

R&Dservices&software −0.131(0.33) 0.271(0.30) −0.152(0.40) 0.276(0.30) −0.260(0.35) 0.267(0.29)

Otherservices 0.068(0.32) −0.098(0.31) −0.757(0.40)* −0.127(0.31) −0.782(0.36)** −0.132(0.31)

R&Dexpend.(yes/no) 0.468(0.18)*** 0.424(0.21)** 0.318(0.20) 0.439(0.21)** 0.467(0.21)** 0.425(0.22)*

R&Dstaff(in%) 0.356(0.35) 0.701(0.33)** 0.755(0.44)* 0.838(0.32)*** −0.134(0.44) 0.650(0.33)**

CEOhasadegree 0.145(0.14) 0.363(0.17)** −0.201(0.16) 0.347(0.17)** −0.214(0.17) 0.344(0.17)**

Marketsize 0.260(0.09)*** 0.191(0.09)** 0.319(0.10)*** 0.203(0.09)** 0.280(0.11)*** 0.206(0.09)**

Productdev.time 0.160(0.06)*** 0.043(0.07) 0.138(0.06)** 0.055(0.07) 0.120(0.07) 0.045(0.07)

Competitors(log) −0.125(0.06)** −0.084(0.08) −0.119(0.06)* −0.087(0.08) −0.203(0.07)*** −0.075(0.07) Intercept −3.070(0.46)*** −1.845(0.44)*** −2.313(0.54)*** −1.903(0.43)*** −2.408(0.52)*** −1.905(0.44)*** Observations 940 940 940 Log-Likelihood −486.4 −454.7 −393.3 Chi-sq.test 354.1 296.1 374.8 P-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 (vit,εit)

p-Valuefor(Waldtest) 0.010 0.130 0.002

Pseudo-R2 0.334 0.357 0.444

Notes.Thistablepresentsbivariaterecursiveprobitmodelsforpatentapplications,patentgrantsandforthelikelihoodofobservingventurecapitalinvestments.Robust standarderrorsareinparentheses.

Significancelevels:***p<0.01;**p<0.05;*p<0.1.

4.1. Patenting

Venture capital does not increase patenting activity

(Table 3—first column of Models 1–3)—rather, it decreases thelikelihoodofafirmfilingpatentapplicationsafterthe invest-ment, in contrastto prior firm level (e.g.Arqué-Castells, 2012) and industry level studies (e.g.Kortum and Lerner, 2000) that foundpositiveassociations.Theeffectonfuturepatentgrantsis insignificant.Correlationsofunobservedeffects inthepatenting and selection equations are positive, supporting ourmodelling strategy.

Wefindstrongpersistenceinpatenting,forbothapplications andgrants.Iffirmspatentinoneperiod,ittendstodosointhe next.Anindicatorforprior-periodpatentingissignificantinall specifications,whileapplyingfororreceivingalargenumberof patentsinoneperiodincreasesthelikelihoodofobservingatleast onepatentinthenext.Theseeffectscanbeinterpretedintwoways: Ontheonehand,priorpatentingcanbeaproxyforunobserved heterogeneitybetweenfirmsin theirabilitytoproduce innova-tions(othervariablesinourmodelsmightnotcaptureallaspectsof firms’internalprocessesandexternalmarketcharacteristicsthat leadtopatentingbehaviour).Ontheotherhand,knowledge–in theformofexistingpatents–isaninputfornewpatents. Exist-ingpatentscansignalthesizeoffirms’knowledgestocks,which areotherwisedifficulttomeasure.Astheseproductivecapacity stocksdepreciateovertime,itisreasonabletoassumethatrecent additions tothepatent stockare thebestpredictorsof present and future patenting activities, which is essentially what we find.

StrongevidenceoftheproductivityeffectsofR&Dexpenditures isconsistentwithpriorstudies(Cohen,2010).Thepercentageof R&Dstaffweaklypredictspatentingactivity,onlyshowing posi-tivecoefficientsinmodel2.Humancapital–asmeasuredbythe CEO’seducation– doesnotappear toincreasethelikelihoodof

patent applicationsorgrants.Firmage doesnot seem toaffect patenting9,whilefirmsizehasapositiveeffectonfuture appli-cations,butnoeffectongrants,asBoundetal.(1984)found.Other variablesdonotexplainthevariationsinpatentingthatsizewould explainiftheywereexcluded.Collinearity islowinourmodels (varianceinflationfactorsarewellbelow5),anddropping signif-icantvariablesfromthemodelsdoesnotsignificantlychangethe effectofsize.Industryeffectscollectivelyexplainpatenting,but ontheirownareonlyweakpredictors.SignificantWaldtests con-firmtheimportanceofcontrollingforindustryeffects.However, individualeffectsarerarelysignificantinourpatentingmodels, asmightbeexpected,sinceourestimationsincludedetailed firm-level variables suchasR&D and humancapital. Unsurprisingly, firmscategorisedasmedium-hightechnologymanufacturingtend toapplyforpatentsmoreoftenandobtaingrantsmorefrequently thanlow-techmanufacturingandservicefirms.

FirmsbasedintheU.S.exhibitahigherchanceofsuccess(in termsoftheirapplicationsbeinggranted)thanthoselocatedin theU.K.,anindicationofknowninstitutionaldifferencesbetween the two countries’ patenting regimes10. As expected,patenting activityisstronglyassociatedwithproductmarketcharacteristics. Firmsthatoperatenationallyorinternationallyaremorelikelyto engageinformalIPprotectionthanlocalorregionalfirms.Thereis

9Ifpatentingwastodependonfirmage,wewouldexpectastart-upeffectearlyin

thelifeoffirmsthatarefoundedtoexploitsometechnologicalopportunity.Wetried

adummyvariableindicatingwhetherafirmwasonlyfoundedduringthesample

periodbutfoundnoinfluenceonpatentingactivity.

10Thenon-obviousnessstandardinU.S.patentlawattheapplicationstagehas

beenweakened,leadingtothegrantofpatentsonincreasingnumbersoftrivial

inventions(Barton,2003;Gallini,2002).Structuraldifferencesinpatenting

pro-cessesalsoaffectpatentopposition,re-examinationandrevocationrates,which

aresignificantlyhigherforEuropeanandU.K.patentsthanforU.S.patents(Harhoff

(8)

littledifferencebetweenmodelsforfutureapplicationsandgrants. Productsthatneedlongleaddevelopmenttimesaremoreoften protectedbypatentsthanthosewithashorttimetomarket.Again, thisisreasonablefromtheviewpointofafirmthatneedsmore pro-tectionoverlongerR&Dcycles.Finally,protectionfromimitation shouldbemoreprominentinindustriescharacterisedbyintense competition, although it is possible that firms in concentrated marketstrytodeterentrythroughthestrategicuseofpatenting (Scherer,1983).WhileScherer(1983)onlyfindsevidenceforalink betweenindustryconcentrationandthenumberofpatentsin mod-elsthatdonotcontrolforsectors,BaumandSilverman(2004)find fewerpatentsinconcentratedindustries.Incontrast,theeffectof highcompetitiononpatentingisnegativeinourmodels11. 4.2. VCinvestment

Afirm’sknowledgestockisagoodpredictorofventurecapital investment(seeTable3).PatentingattractsVCinvestments—more specifically,itisthefactthatacompanyispatent-active,notthe number of applicationsor grants, that predicts VC investment. Resultsareparticularlystrongfortheapplicationindicator,which signalsstronginnovationpotentialinportfoliocompanies.

R&Dexpenditures and R&D stafflevelsare both strong pre-dictors of VC investments, as is the CEO’s education level. VC involvementismorelikelytobefoundinyoungfirms,echoingthe findingsofpriorresearch.Interestingly,however,venturecapital fundsappeartoinvestinlargerfirmsmoreoftenthaninsmaller ones.Thisfindingcanbeexplainedbyinterpretingsizeasa mea-sureofinvestmentrisk,withverysmallfirmstypicallybeingmore opaquethanlargerones.Butitisalsoimportanttobearinmindthat oursampleincludesfirmswith10to1000employees,andis there-foreasampleofSMEs,asdemandedforastudyofVCinvestment. Industryeffectspointtoapreferenceamongventureinvestorsfor R&Dservicesorsoftware.Firmsoperatinginlarger(international) marketsseemtobeattractiveinvestments,whilecoefficientsfor theintensityofcompetitionareinsignificant.Firmswithlong prod-uctdevelopmenttimesare neithermorenorless likelyto gain venturecapital12.

4.3. Two-stagepatenting—Patentcounts,patenting,andventure capital

The large number of zeroes in patent counts suggests that patentingisatwo-stageprocess,consistingofthebinarydecision whethertousepatentingasanIPprotectionstrategyandadecision abouthowmanypatentstoapplyfor.Twopopularmethodsusedto modelthenumberofpatentsproducedbysuchprocessesarebased onazero-inflatedPoissondistributionandazero-inflatednegative binomialdistribution.Inorder tofurtherrefineourfindingswe integrateazero-inflatedPoissonprocessinoursystemofequations, whichnowincludesanequationforpatentcounts,onefor patent-ing,andoneforventurecapitalinvestment.Table4presentsthe resultsfortheseestimations.Forcompleteness,weincluderesults

11 Wealsotestthehypothesisthatcompetitionismorerelevantifthefirm

opera-tesinternationally,butdonotfindthatthisinteractioneffectissignificant.Prior

studieshavefoundconflictingevidenceontheimpactofprofitabilityonpatenting:

Bertonietal.(2010)showapositiverelationbetweennetcashflowandpatents,

whereasBaumandSilverman(2004)reportanegativeone.Wealsotriedusinga

proxyforprofitabilityconstructedfrompre-taxprofitsscaledbyassets,butdidnot

findsignificantresults.Consequently,wedecidedtodropthisvariablefromour

models,duetothelargeamountofmissingvaluesinsurveyresponsesonprofits.

12 Althoughcollinearityisnotaprobleminthesemodels,thereissomecorrelation

betweenproductdevelopmenttimeandR&Defforts,whichcausesdevelopment

timetobecomeasignificantpredictorofVCinvestmentsifR&Dvariablesare

droppedfromtheregression.

fromamodelwithonlythepatentcountsandpatentingequations asTable5,whichprovidesthebaselineforthefull(three-equation) modeldiscussedinthissection.

Thepositiveeffectonfirms’latentpatentingstates,whichwould beexpectedifventurecapitalistsadded totheirpatenting per-formance,disappearsacrossallmodels,whilethenegativeeffect onthenumberofgrantedpatentsremains.Moreover–andasin thesimultaneousbinarypatentingmodels–thenumberofpatent applicationsdropsafterVCinvestments.

Ifwelookatthenumberofpatentsbeingappliedfororgranted, ourresultssupporttheviewthatVCfinancefollowspatentsignals toinvestincompanieswithexistingcommerciallyviable know-how.WhiletheeffectofVCinvestmentonboththeuseofpatents andontheirnumbersseemsnegligible,VChasanegativeimpacton patentgrantsandapplicationsinsomemodels.Venturecapitalists areattractedtofirmsthatproducepatents,butdonotcontributeto theexpansionoffirms’knowledgestocks—instead,theyarelikely toshiftfirmresourcesfromproducingnewpatentapplicationsto exploitingexistingknowledge.

Controlvariables for future patent counts behave mostly as expected,andgivefurtherinsightsintofirms’patentingdecisions. While manufacturingfirms andservice firms appear– perhaps counterintuitively–equallylikelytopatent(seemodel1inTable3), wefindthatbeingamanufacturingorR&Dfirmincreasesthe num-berofpatentapplicationsrelativetootherservicefirms(seemodel 1 in Table4).The estimation algorithm for three simultaneous equationspickstherelevantequationsforourtwoR&Dvariables: TheexistenceofR&Dprogrammesmainlypredicts patentingin general,whiletheproportionofR&Dstaffexplainsthenumberof applicationsandgrantsawarded.InlinewithBaumandSilverman’s (2004)results,wefindthatcompetitionhasanegativeimpacton thedecision topatent (inbivariatemodelsin Table3)andthe numberofpatentsappliedfororgranted(intrivariatemodelsin Table4).However,firmstendtoprotecttheirpositioninthe mar-ketbychoosingtopatentiftheirmarketsarelargeorhavelong productdevelopmenttimes.

EstimatedmodelparametersprovidesupportformodellingVC investment,patenting,andthenumberofpatentssimultaneously. Inmostofthemodelstestedforpatentapplicationsandgrants, errorcorrelationsbetweenthefirst(VC)equationandthesecond and third are substantial and significant. External shocks lead-ingtoVCinvestmentcorrelatewiththelikelihoodtopatentwith theexpectedpositivesign(andnegativesignfornotpatenting). EstimatederrorcorrelationsbetweenVCinvestmentandpatent numbersareagainlargeandsignificant.Wealsotestmodel stabil-itybycheckinginfluentialobservationsandcross-tabulationsfor firmsthatstartorstoptheirpatentingactivitiesdependingonVC investment,butfindnoabnormalities.

5. Robustnesstests 5.1. Independentequations

Ourfirstrobustnesscheckshowstheadvantagesofour estima-tionstrategyoversimpleralternatives.Wecomparetheresultsof oursimultaneousestimationswiththoseobtainedfrom indepen-dentregressionsforVCinvestmentand patenting(seeTable6). Whilethereis nochangeintheVCequation,thereisastriking differenceinthepatentingequations(Table6,columns1–3): With-outcontrollingforendogeneity,venturecapitalappearstoincrease thelikelihoodofpatentsbeinggranted.Thisarguablybiasedresult notonlydisappearsinthesimultaneousestimationstrategy,but thefindingemergesthatVCinvestmentcanreducethelikelihood thatfirmsapplyfornewpatentsintheperiodimmediatelyafter theinvestment.Wecanruleoutthatreducedeffectsofventure

(9)

Table4

Patenting,patentnumbers,andVCinvestment.

Dependentvariableinpatentingequations Applicationsint+1 Grantsint+1 Grantsint+1

Model 1 2 3

Dependentvariable Notpatenting

(zeroinflation)

VCinvestment Notpatenting (zeroinflation)

VCinvestment Notpatenting (zeroinflation)

VCinvestment

VCinvestment 0.186(0.58) −0.976(0.66) −0.815(0.85)

Patentapplications(Log) −0.313(0.22) −0.083(0.08) −0.371(0.18)** −0.103(0.08)

Patentapplications>0 −1.779(0.51)*** 0.560(0.20)*** −2.460(0.43)*** 0.591(0.20)***

Patentgrants(Log) −0.586(0.21)*** −0.173(0.13)

Patentgrants>0 −1.110(0.27)*** 0.400(0.24)*

Age(Log) −0.161(0.12) −0.346(0.10)*** −0.233(0.12)* −0.343(0.09)*** −0.111(0.14) −0.338(0.09)***

Size(log(employees+1)) −0.167(0.09)* 0.206(0.07)*** −0.006(0.08) 0.203(0.07)*** 0.022(0.10) 0.201(0.07)***

U.S.firm 0.075(0.20) −0.342(0.13)** −0.400(0.18)** −0.318(0.14)** −0.351(0.24) −0.342(0.14)**

Medium-hightechmanuf. −0.151(0.44) −0.216(0.29) −0.061(0.38) −0.125(0.30) 0.162(0.36) −0.228(0.29)

Medium-lowtechmanuf. 0.188(0.45) −0.375(0.29) 0.295(0.39) −0.346(0.30) 0.465(0.34) −0.384(0.29)

R&Dservices&software 0.159(0.49) 0.280(0.30) −0.094(0.48) 0.320(0.30) −0.111(0.42) 0.266(0.30)

Otherservices −0.652(0.57) −0.107(0.31) 0.634(0.46) −0.074(0.32) 0.711(0.49) −0.116(0.31)

R&Dexpend.(yes/no) −0.613(0.25)** 0.425(0.21)** −0.288(0.23) 0.440(0.21)** −0.487(0.28)* 0.432(0.21)**

R&Dstaff(in%) 0.359(0.51) 0.752(0.32)** −0.485(0.56) 0.881(0.32)*** 1.123(0.67)* 0.665(0.33)**

CEOhasadegree −0.282(0.22) 0.345(0.17)** 0.313(0.22) 0.333(0.17)* 0.355(0.23) 0.341(0.17)**

Marketsize −0.366(0.14)*** 0.186(0.09)** −0.299(0.13)** 0.199(0.09)** −0.388(0.15)*** 0.194(0.09)**

Productdev.time −0.176(0.09)* 0.045(0.07) −0.208(0.10)** 0.052(0.07) −0.226(0.11)** 0.050(0.07)

Competitors(Log) 0.109(0.09) −0.081(0.07) 0.148(0.09) −0.087(0.07) 0.164(0.11) −0.082(0.07)

Intercept 3.655(0.70)*** −1.859(0.44)*** 2.780(0.62)*** −1.897(0.44)*** 2.703(0.65)*** −1.867(0.44)***

Dependentvariable Applications(number) Grants(number) Grants(number)

VCinvestment −0.780(0.15)*** −0.136(0.25) −0.886(0.29)***

Patentapplications(Log) 0.815(0.05)*** 0.962(0.05)***

Patentapplications>0 −0.160(0.23) −0.411(0.32)

Patentgrants(log) 0.615(0.06)***

Patentgrants>0 0.820(0.23)***

Age(log) −0.032(0.06) −0.441(0.12)*** −0.042(0.11)

Size(log(employees+1)) 0.017(0.05) 0.186(0.09)** 0.014(0.10)

U.S.firm 0.289(0.10)*** −0.061(0.15) 0.119(0.19)

Medium-hightechmanuf. −0.027(0.34) −0.246(0.27) 0.074(0.40)

Medium-lowtechmanuf. 0.071(0.36) −0.282(0.32) 0.130(0.44)

R&Dservices&software −0.106(0.34) −0.799(0.30)*** −0.199(0.45)

Otherservices −1.136(0.53)** −0.664(0.46) −0.285(0.59)

R&Dexpend.(yes/no) 0.224(0.42) −0.128(0.41) 0.544(0.32)*

R&Dstaff(in%) 1.215(0.12)*** 0.850(0.30)*** 1.059(0.37)***

CEOhasadegree −0.158(0.17) 0.012(0.34) 0.031(0.20)

Marketsize −0.055(0.09) 0.166(0.11) −0.211(0.12)*

Productdev.time 0.096(0.05)** −0.103(0.06) −0.054(0.07)

Competitors(log) −0.210(0.05)*** 0.042(0.14) −0.239(0.09)*** Intercept 0.259(0.62) 0.914(0.53)* 0.531(0.53) Var(ωit) 1.307(0.12)*** 0.656(0.10)*** 0.483(0.07)*** (vit,εit) −0.338(0.24)* 0.076(0.29) −0.092(0.44) (vit,ωit) 0.290(0.03)*** −0.108(0.06)** 0.444(0.11)*** Observations 940 940 940 Waldtest 25697 25356 8424 p-Value 0.000 0.000 0.000 Log-likelihood −968.4 −846.0 −762.8

Notes.Thistablepresentszero-inflatedPoissonmodelsforpatentapplicationsandpatentgrantsduringtheperiodfollowingthesurveyperiod,includinganendogenous equationforventurecapitalinvestment.Robuststandarderrors(estimatedusingthesandwichestimator)areshowninparentheses.

Significancelevels:***p<0.01;**p<0.05;*p<0.1.

capitalarecausedbyestimationuncertaintyduetotheadditional

parameterforerrorcorrelationbetweenequations.Waldtestsof

thejointsignificanceofthiscorrelationandthecoefficientof

ven-turecapitalonpatentingaresignificantatthefivepercentlevelin

allmodelsinTable3.Theimpactofpositiveerrorcorrelationscan

beseeninthecoefficientsforventurecapital,whichchange consid-erablywhenestimatedsimultaneously.Introducingcross-equation correlationalsoharmonisescoefficientsforsomevariablesacross modelsand causesno majorchanges in theresultsfor control variables.

Whetherornotafirm obtainsfinancecouldhaveanimpact onitsabilitytostartorsustainpatentingactivities.Sincewe per-formourregressionsonasample offirmsthat soughtexternal finance,ratherthanonlyonthosethatobtainedit,weaddasetof robustnesstestsforthissubsample.Resultsofseparateregressions

(not reported here) confirm ourfindings in Table 3. However, two smallchangesappear inthepatenting equations.First, the effectsize ofdevelopmenttime decreasesslightly and losesits significance.Second,coefficientsonproductmarketcompetition allincreaseinmagnitude,andtheonepredictingfuture applica-tionsbecomesslightlysignificant.Estimatingourmodelsonthe fulldataset(includingthose96firmsthatdidnotobtainexternal finance)hastwoadvantagesoverthesmallersample.First,adding theseobservationsincreasesthestatisticalprecisionofourresults. Second,ourfindingsareconservative,thatis,theeffectofobtaining venturecapitalonpatentingcanbeupwardbiasedifitincludesa (positive)effectofobtaininganykindoffinance,whichwouldbe ignorediffirmsgainingnofinancewereexcluded.Inthissense,the negativeorinsignificantcoefficientsforventurecapitalrepresent upperboundsforthe‘true’effect.

(10)

Table5

Patentingandpatentnumbers—zero-inflatedPoissonmodel.

Dependentvariablein patentingequations

Applicationsint+1 Grantsint+1 Grantsint+1

Model 1 2 3

Dependentvariable Patents(number) Notpatenting

(zeroinflation)

Patents(number) Notpatenting (zeroinflation)

Patents(number) Notpatenting (zeroinflation)

VCinvestment −0.5030.29)* −0.342(0.22) −0.287(0.22) −0.689(0.22)*** −0.696(0.26)*** −1.130(0.36)***

Patentapplications(log) 0.805(0.10)*** −0.448(0.14)*** 0.990(0.09)*** −0.419(0.18)**

Patentapplications>0 −0.756(0.34)** −1.150(0.27)*** −0.916(0.43)** −2.372(0.37)***

Patentgrants(log) 0.682(0.11)*** −0.545(0.16)***

Patentgrants>0 0.314(0.30) −1.167(0.24)***

Age(log) −0.098(0.17) −0.177(0.08)** −0.318(0.17)* −0.143(0.10) 0.143(0.15) −0.078(0.14)

Size(log(employees+1)) −0.125(0.14) −0.150(0.07)** 0.244(0.14)* 0.019(0.07) −0.138(0.15) −0.015(0.10)

U.S.firm 0.401(0.34) −0.073(0.16) 0.583(0.24)** −0.262(0.16) 0.164(0.17) −0.381(0.22)*

Medium-hightechmanuf. 0.260(0.32) −0.159(0.34) −0.510(0.58) −0.041(0.37) −0.269(0.46) 0.101(0.34)

Medium-lowtechmanuf. 0.126(0.36) 0.133(0.34) −0.162(0.59) 0.390(0.37) −0.223(0.47) 0.372(0.33)

R&Dservices&software 0.392(0.40) 0.255(0.38) −0.443(0.62) 0.163(0.42) −0.459(0.47) −0.128(0.40)

Otherservices −0.498(0.43) −0.232(0.37) −0.415(0.67) 0.726(0.42)* −0.684(0.62) 0.696(0.45)

R&Dexpend.(yes/no) 0.470(0.39) −0.420(0.19)** −0.100(0.57) −0.284(0.23) 0.389(0.45) −0.484(0.26)*

R&Dstaff(in%) 1.324(0.72)* −0.020(0.37) 0.752(0.48) −0.474(0.46) 1.551(0.42)*** 1.292(0.62)**

CEOhasadegree −0.048(0.28) −0.105(0.16) −0.193(0.32) 0.234(0.18) 0.249(0.35) 0.459(0.25)*

Marketsize 0.055(0.32) −0.243(0.09)*** 0.487(0.22)** −0.233(0.11)** −0.157(0.17) −0.336(0.15)**

Productdev.time −0.225(0.10)** −0.189(0.07)*** −0.072(0.10) −0.161(0.08)** −0.248(0.09)*** −0.281(0.11)**

Competitors(log) −0.163(0.15) 0.101(0.07) −0.307(0.18)* 0.046(0.09) −0.568(0.22)** 0.069(0.14) Intercept 1.674(1.21) 3.451(0.50)*** 0.498(1.11) 2.385(0.55)*** 1.974(0.90)** 2.967(0.65)*** Observations 940 940 940 Waldtest 2204.7 469.0 480.9 p-Value 0.000 0.000 0.000 Log-likelihood −1537.8 −982.8 −819.3

Notes.Thistablepresentszero-inflatedPoissonmodelsforpatentapplicationsandpatentgrantsduringtheperiodafterthesurvey.Whencomparingcoefficientsfromthe patentingequationwithpriormodelsforthelikelihoodtopatent,allsignsmustbereversedasthe“patenting”equationinthistablepredictsthelikelihoodofnotpatenting. Asarobustnesstest,wetriedzero-inflatednegativebinomialmodels.Testsforoverdispersionareallinsignificantinthesemodels,whileVuongtestsagainstthealternative hypothesisofastandardPoissonprocessarehighlysignificant.Robuststandarderrorsareinparentheses.

Significancelevels:***p<0.01;**p<0.05;*p<0.1.

Table6

Patentingactivityandventurecapitalinvestment—independentequations.

Patenting(yes/no) VCinvestment

Model 1 2 3 4 5 6

Dependentvariable Applicationsint+1 Grantsint+1 Grantsint+1 VCinvestment VCinvestment VCinvestment

VCinvestment 0.267(0.20) 0.598(0.20)*** 0.445(0.25)*

Patentapplications(Log) 0.513(0.13)*** 0.627(0.14)*** −0.094(0.08)

Patentapplications>0 0.980(0.22)*** 1.594(0.23)*** 0.574(0.20)***

Patentgrants(log) 0.584(0.16)*** −0.166(0.12)

Patentgrants>0 1.182(0.22)*** 0.393(0.23)*

Age(log) 0.164(0.07)** 0.073(0.09) 0.167(0.09)* −0.331(0.09)*** −0.345(0.09)*** −0.339(0.09)***

Size(log(employees+1)) 0.123(0.06)** 0.028(0.06) −0.012(0.07) 0.202(0.07)*** 0.205(0.06)*** 0.193(0.07)***

U.S.firm 0.132(0.14) 0.344(0.15)** 0.409(0.18)** −0.327(0.14)** −0.324(0.14)** −0.323(0.14)**

Medium-hightechmanuf. 0.177(0.32) −0.045(0.34) −0.202(0.27) −0.235(0.29) −0.138(0.29) −0.142(0.29)

Medium-lowtechmanuf. −0.127(0.32) −0.407(0.35) −0.500(0.28)* −0.405(0.29) −0.351(0.30) −0.347(0.29)

R&Dservices&software −0.235(0.36) −0.229(0.39) −0.352(0.36) 0.259(0.29) 0.312(0.30) 0.312(0.30)

Otherservices 0.122(0.34) −0.761(0.40)* −0.786(0.36)** −0.127(0.31) −0.084(0.31) −0.099(0.31)

R&Dexpend.(yes/no) 0.430(0.18)** 0.278(0.20) 0.432(0.22)** 0.419(0.21)** 0.442(0.21)** 0.464(0.21)**

R&Dstaff(in%) 0.170(0.36) 0.563(0.46) −0.352(0.46) 0.696(0.33)** 0.878(0.32)*** 0.874(0.31)***

CEOhasadegree 0.085(0.14) −0.261(0.16)* −0.288(0.18) 0.335(0.17)** 0.339(0.17)** 0.362(0.17)**

Marketsize 0.239(0.09)*** 0.300(0.10)*** 0.260(0.11)** 0.198(0.09)** 0.196(0.09)** 0.214(0.09)**

Productdev.time 0.163(0.06)*** 0.136(0.07)** 0.119(0.08) 0.044(0.07) 0.053(0.07) 0.057(0.07)

Competitors(log) −0.119(0.06)* −0.111(0.07)* −0.202(0.08)*** −0.077(0.07) −0.089(0.07) −0.092(0.07) Intercept −3.311(0.46)*** −2.448(0.52)*** −2.588(0.52)*** −1.883(0.44)*** −1.887(0.44)*** −1.889(0.44)*** Observations 940 940 940 940 940 940 Log-Likelihood −252.3 −218.3 −159.3 −235.2 −237.1 −238.9 Chi-sq.test 235.7 186.4 265.8 111.0 114.6 101.5 p-Value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Pseudo-R2 0.428 0.451 0.599 0.241 0.235 0.229

Notes.Thistablepresentsprobitmodelsforthelikelihoodofobservinganynumberofpatentapplicationsorgrants,respectively,incolumns1–3andprobitmodelsforthe likelihoodofobservingventurecapitalinvestmentsincolumns4–6.Robuststandarderrorsareinparentheses.

(11)

Table7

Likelihoodofbecomingamergeroracquisitiontarget.

Dependentvariable M&ATarget M&ATarget M&ATarget M&ATarget

Model 1 2 3 4

VCinvestment×applications(log) −0.013(0.19)

VCinvestment×grants(log) 0.303(0.26)

VCinvestment×(applications>0) −0.433(0.38) −0.406(0.55)

VCinvestment×(grant>0) −0.215(0.39) −0.700(0.55)

VCinvestment 0.619(0.24)** 0.547(0.23)** 0.619(0.24)** 0.537(0.23)**

Patentapplications(log) 0.020(0.09) 0.024(0.11)

Patentapplications>0 0.509(0.26)** 0.502(0.27)*

Patentgrants(log) 0.183(0.12) 0.108(0.13)

Patentgrants>0 0.184(0.28) 0.302(0.28)

Age(log) −0.181(0.09)** −0.191(0.09)** −0.181(0.09)** −0.190(0.09)**

Size(log(employees+1)) 0.266(0.07)*** 0.257(0.06)*** 0.266(0.07)*** 0.257(0.06)***

U.S.firm −0.124(0.15) −0.143(0.15) −0.125(0.14) −0.145(0.15)

Medium-hightechmanuf. −0.157(0.33) −0.134(0.33) −0.157(0.33) −0.171(0.33)

Medium-lowtechmanuf. −0.257(0.34) −0.234(0.34) −0.258(0.34) −0.258(0.34)

R&Dservices&software −0.289(0.37) −0.294(0.36) −0.292(0.36) −0.278(0.36)

Otherservices −0.525(0.37) −0.514(0.37) −0.525(0.37) −0.527(0.37)

R&Dexpend.(yes/no) −0.507(0.18)*** −0.474(0.18)*** −0.506(0.18)*** −0.475(0.18)***

R&Dstaff(in%) 0.218(0.44) 0.133(0.46) 0.216(0.44) 0.127(0.46)

CEOhasadegree 0.132(0.17) 0.150(0.18) 0.133(0.17) 0.146(0.18)

Marketsize 0.119(0.08) 0.129(0.08) 0.118(0.08) 0.139(0.08)*

Productdev.time 0.072(0.08) 0.067(0.08) 0.072(0.08) 0.066(0.08)

Competitors(log) −0.055(0.08) −0.051(0.08) −0.055(0.08) −0.050(0.07) Intercept −2.004(0.43)*** −1.958(0.42)*** −2.001(0.43)*** −1.952(0.43)*** Observations 940 940 940 940 Log-Likelihood −170.713 −171.065 −170.711 −170.518 Chi-sq.test 65.850 64.510 66.040 65.380 p-Value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Pseudo-R2 0.151 0.149 0.151 0.152 Significancelevels:***p<0.01;**p<0.05;*p<0.1.

5.2. Sampleattritionbias

Sampleattritioncanbeaproblemiffirmsdisappearinginperiod

t+1aresystematicallythoseforwhichventurecapitalinvestment

hadapositiveeffectonpatenting.Tolimittheriskofattritionbias

weinvestigatethemergerandacquisitionhistoryofthefirmsinour

samplebyretrievingtherelevantrecordsfromThomsonReuters’

SDCPlatinumdatabase.Weusethisinformationtoestimatethe

probabilitythat firmsare acquireddepending onwhetherthey

patentandwhethertheyreceiveVCfunding.Table7showsthat

firmsaremorelikelytobeacquirediftheypatentinperiodtandif theyexperienceVCinvestment.Thisresultisnotsurprisingsince acquirersmayfollowthesamepatentsignalsthatcauseventure capitaliststoinvest—ormayevenbeventurecapitaliststhemselves. Note,however,thattheinteractioneffectsforVCinvestmentand patentingarenotsignificant.Sampleattritionduetomergersand acquisitions,ifthesefirmsactuallyleavethesample,isthusunlikely tosystematicallyreducethemeasuredeffectofVConpatenting.

AfterinspectingtheM&ArecordsintheSDCdatabase,ifafirm isthetargetofanykindoftransaction,wecorrectthenumberof patentapplicationsandgrantsinthefollowingway.Ifafirmretains itsidentityandremainsactiveunderitsnameinthesample,we keeptheoriginalnumberofpatents.Anexampleofthistypeof transactionisaleveragedbuyout,inwhichthefirm’smanagement acquiresthefirm,buttheoperatingbusinessremainsunchanged. If,instead,thefirmismergedintotheacquirer,wecheckwhether itisstillpatentingattheoriginallocation,butundertheacquirer’s name,andifthisisthecaseweaddthesepatentstothesample.If thefirmdisappearsasalegalentityafterthemerger,weaddallthe acquirer’spatentstotheoriginalfirm’spatents,whichthen estab-lishesanupperboundaryforthefirms’patentingactivityint+1.Of 128transactionsweidentified,weadjustedthepatentapplication orgrantnumbersfor15firms.Theresultsofthebinarymodels pre-sentedinTable8areunchanged,whilethoseofthezero-inflated PoissonmodelspresentedinTable9showaninsignificanteffectof

VConpatentinginmodels1and3,asonemightconfidentlyexpect afterattributingmergedfirms’technologicaloutputsintothoseof acquiringfirms.

5.3. Formalvs.informalventurecapital

PoolingformalandinformalVCinvestmentsinourmodelmay affectresultsifthetwoclassesofinvestorsbehavedifferentlyin relationtothetechnologicalprofilesoftheirinvesteefirms.Outof 96firmsthatobtainVCfinancinginoursample,66firmsreceive formalVCfunding,while41firmsattractVCinvestors.We there-foredisaggregateformalVCinvestmentsfromthoseofinformal venturecapitalists(suchasbusinessangels)inTable10,butfind theresultsforthetwosub-samplestobeverysimilar.EffectsofVC involvementarenegativeinbothcases,albeitinsignificant,while theeffectofformalVConpatentingseemstobemorenegative thanthatofinformalVC.Whiletheseeffectsdonotseemtodiffer betweentypesofinvestors,theirlackofsignificanceisanexpected consequenceofthereducednumberofobservationsineachbinary modelestimation.

ItshouldalsobepointedoutthattheeffectsobservedinTable10 maybeduetothefactthatthecontrolgroupsforfirmsthatgained formal(orinformal)venturecapitalincludefirmsfinancedby infor-mal(orformal)venturecapital.Hence,wewould(tosomeextent) becomparingfirmsreceivingformaland informalventure capi-talandnot,forexample,firmsgainingformalventurecapitalwith those receivingneithertype of investment.Ifwe excludefirms fundedbyinformalVCfromthecontrolgroupfortheformalVC models,andviceversa,wefindthattheseeffectsremain insignifi-cantandqualitativelyunchangedfromthosepresentedinTable10. Theserobustnesschecks,whichtakeintoaccountthetypeofVC investor,contrastwithContietal.’s(2013a)results,where busi-nessangelsarefoundnottobeassensitiveasVCtopatentsignals, butareconsistentwithresultspresentedbyAudretschetal.(2012), whoseestimationsofprobitmodelsfortheprobabilityofreceiving

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

With the conditions for the spread of crisis phenomena in the enterprise among the mechanisms of corporate governance, the system of anti-crisis communication policy takes the

• Le azioni quotate rappresentano solo il 22,8% del PIL (molto meno che in Germania e in Francia), mentre gli strumenti di debito corrispondono. complessivamente all’8% del PIL

One or more constraints or rules that must be satisfied in order for activity(i) to be performed. • Other parameters can be added if necessary. The process modeling starts

quod Te praeclare norim; qui Tua consuetudine tam diu suavissime sim usus, nuncq(uam) ea iniucundissime caream. Fac me ames; quando ego te, maximo Tuo merito, in oculis fero».

Il terzo e ultimo capitolo verterà su uno studio del venture capital spaziale attraverso un database creato appositamente, il quale avrà al suo interno tutte le imprese europee

Il corso, anche attraverso l’analisi di casi di studio, è finalizzato a fornire strumenti di analisi e valutazione della situazione finanziaria delle imprese nonché capacità

However, since the data accumulations for the most of CVs inside gap are not enough for or- bital period analysis, we only chose five ob- jects including an eclipsing pre-CVs HW Vir

Methods: Forty male Wistar rats were randomly allocated to one of four groups r of ten animals each: Group 1(G1): ad libitum breast feeding in litters of six pups per dam;