• Non ci sono risultati.

Anomalies and monotonicity in net present value calculations

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Condividi "Anomalies and monotonicity in net present value calculations"

Copied!
6
0
0

Testo completo

(1)

Marco Lonzi and Samuele Riccarelli* Dipartimento di Metodi Quantitativi

Università degli Studi di Siena P.zza San Francesco 14

53100 Siena ITALY

Abstract. In recent issues of Economics Letters ( (2001) 127-129 and 72 67 (2000) 349-351), the authors find conditions on internal rates of return so that the net present value function doesn't present more than one change in sign. We show in this note a condition for the strictly monotonicity of net present value function.

Author Keywords: Internal rate of return; Net present value JEL classification codes: D92; G31

(Article Outline)

The internal rate of return and the net present value are two of the most used criterions to accept or reject projects; for the internal rate of return (IRR) criterion, a project is acceptable if its IRR is major than its risk-adjusted discount rate, while for the net present value (NPV) criterion, we

*Corresponding author: Samuele Riccarelli, Dipartimento di Metodi Quantitativi, Università degli Studi di Siena, P.zza San Francesco 14, Tel 0390577232731, Fax 03900577232626, e-mail riccarelli@unisi.it

(2)

have acceptance if NPV is positive. Both procedures have been criticized from many authors; in particular, if the project has a stream of net benefits with more than one change in sign, the internal rate of return may not exist or it is possible to have two or more IRR.

The Oehmke (2000) and Domingo (2001) letters explain that when the stream of net benefits has more than one change in sign, isn't assured that the relation between NPV and the discount rate is monotonic, thus the net present value criterion, as the IRR, can generate ambiguous results. The non monotonicity of NPV can cause situations where an increment in the discount rate yields a NPV that grow from negative to positive quantities.

Before to explain our considerations on the letters above quoted, we remember that for every discount rate < −‘ and for every stream of net benefits ÐF ß F ß á ß F Ñ −! " 88", (F  !! , F Á !8 and F  !> for at least one ) we define NPV at rate as the quantity> <

R < œ F

"  <

>œ!

>œ8

>

>

while a rate is an IRR for the stream 3 ÐF ß F ß á ß F Ñ! " 8 if R Ð3Ñ œ ! 3 ( is a positive root for the function ).R

The Oehmke paper focuses attention on the relation between function's sign of NPV and its roots; in particular is noted that "a necessary condition for anomalous behavior" of NPV criterion "is that R < have at least two real roots. A sufficient condition is that R < have (at least) two distinct real roots", and concludes "the cases in which NPV may exhibit anomalous behavior are exactly those cases in which there are multiple" IRRs. Domingo note instead achieves the following result: "Let ÐF ß F ß á ß F Ñ −! " 88", and , be positive real numbersB C with B  C" such that R ÐBÑ  ! and R ÐCÑ  !. "If the interval ÐBß CÑ contains at most one internal rate of return corresponding to ÐF ß F ß á ß F Ñ −! " 88", then the NPV is positive for all .< − ÒBß CÓ "

If we consider the stream Ð  %ß (ß  %Ñ with

R < œ  %  (  % œ  % "  "  "

"  < "  < # Œ "  < "  <

#

,

we can observ that even if R < have'nt roots, the NPV may exhibit anomalous behavior, infact in this case the function is strictly increasing in R Ð!ß "Î(Ñ while for <  "Î( is strictly decreasing, thus we do not belive correct the condition that if R < have at least two real roots is necessary for anomalous behavior of NPV. But moreover the results displaied by Ohmke and

(3)

Domingo consider only the sign of R < and not its monotonicity; to go at one condition for it, take a5 Ÿ 8 the quantity

R5

>œ!

>œ5

>

< œ F >

"  < (1)

obviously R < œ R <8 . Every R5 < may be explained as the net present value at rate of the<

truncated stream ÐF ß F ß á ß F Ñ! " 5 and following the idea of maximization of the truncated net present value, see Arrow and Levhary (1969), for the monotonicity be worth the following Proposition 1. Let ÐF ß F ß á ß F Ñ −! " 88" (with the conditions before expressed) and , twoB C positive real values with B  C. If for every 5 Ÿ 8 and for every < − ÒBß CÓ is R5 < Ÿ R < , then R < is strictly decreasing in ÒBß CÓ.

Proof. For every < −‘ calculate the derivative of R < :

R < œ  > † F

"  <

w

>œ"

>œ8

>

>"

œ "  F

"  <>œ" "  <

>œ8 2œ8

2œ>

2 2

œ " R <  R <

"  <>œ!

>œ8

> .

Conditions in proposition imply that R <w Ÿ ! for every < − ÒBß CÓ and by F Á !8 follow

R8" <  R < for every < −‘, thus at least one addendum in last summation is negative and

so the strict negativity of R <w in ÒBß CÓ. è

If we consider the sign of R < , by the Proposition 1 turn out immediatly the

Corollary 2. Under the hypotesies of Proposition 1, the condition R ÐCÑ  ! is sufficient to assure positivity of R < in the interval ÒBß CÓ.

Unfortunally Proposition 1 and Corollary 2 provide conditions on strict monotonicity that have to be valid for every that belong in < ÒBß CÓ; surely conditions only on one point are easier to be cheked, for this goal we have

Proposition 3. Let ÐF ß F ß á ß F Ñ −! " 88" (with the conditions before expressed). If bB −‘À a Ÿ 8ß R ÐBÑ Ÿ R ÐBÑ5 5 , then R < is strictly decreasing in Ò!ß BÓ.

(4)

Before to start the proof note that as before if we derive R < we get

R < œ " R <  R <

"  <

w

>œ!

>œ8

> ; (2)

rearranging the above summation follow that for every 5 Ÿ 8 "

Rw

!

< œ " R <  R <  " R <  R <

"  < "  < >œ!

>œ5 >œ5

> 5 5

 " R <  R <

"  <>œ5"

>œ8

>

by (1) the first addendum is the derivative of R <5 , thus

R <  R < œ " R <  R <

"  <

w w

5

>œ!

>œ8

>”5 (3)

where .> ” 5 œsupÖ>ß 5×

To prove the proposition we need of the following

Lemma 4. Under the hypotesies of Proposition 3, R5 < Ÿ R < for every and for every5

< − Ò!ß BÓ.

Proof. By the hypotesies if we calculate in the summation in (3) every addendum is notB positive, besides from condition F Á !8 at least one is negative and this imply R ÐBÑ  R ÐBÑß a5w 5w Ÿ 8 ". From the previous inequality follow that exist a positive A  B such that

R <  R < ß a 55 Ÿ 8 "ß a < − ÒAß BÓ. (4)

Now go ad absurd and suppose that exist 4 Ÿ 8  " and @  B such that R Ð@Ñ  R Ð@Ñ @4 ; is less than and by the continuity of every function A R <5 , we may suppose without lose of generality that exist (? @  ?  A), such that:

R <  R < ß a < − Ò@ß ?Ò4 ;

R Ð?Ñ œ R Ð?Ñ4 ; (5)

R <4 Ÿ R < ß a < − Ó?ß AÓ. (6)

Integrating the difference R <  R <w 5w we obtain

(5)

R Ð?Ñ  R Ð?Ñ œ4 R <  R < .<  R ÐBÑ  R ÐBÑ4 B

? w w

( ˆ 4

  ( ˆR <  R < .< ‰ ( ˆR <  R < .<‰

? A

A B

w w w w

4 4

where the inequality follow from hypotesies in Lemma; by (3) the addition above may be rewritten as

( (

? A

A B

>œ! >œ!

>œ8 >œ8

>”4 >”4

" "

"  < R <  R < .<  "  < R <  R < .<

and by (6) the first integral is not negative while the second is positive from (4). Thus R Ð?Ñ  R Ð?Ñ  !4 in contradiction with (5) and the proof is completed. è Proof of Proposition 3. From Lemma 4 every addendum in (2) is not positive a < − Ò!ß BÓ and by condition F Á !8 at least one is negative a < − Ò!ß BÒ; this imply R <w ! in Ò!ß BÒ and so the

strictly decreasing of in R Ò!ß BÓ. è

(6)

References

1) Arrow K.J. and Levhary D., 1969, Uniqueness of the internal rate of return with variable life of investment, The Economic Journal 79 , pp. 560-566.

2) Domingo C. J., 2001, Anomalies in net present value calculations?, Economics Letters 72 , pp.

127-129.

3) Oehmke J. F., 2000, Anomalies in net present value calculations, Economics Letters 67 , pp.

349-351.

Riferimenti

Documenti correlati

GESAAF - University of Florence, Piazzale delle Cascine, 18 - 50144 Firenze, Italy; RIS-BIO - Laboratory for Research and Sustainable Innovation on Biomaterials, Located at

In its broader meaning of “process for creating sustainable, successful places that promote well-being, by understanding what people need from the places they live and work”, social

Kprowpc j , K prowkh j , K prowkp j – value of the repaid bank commission in the j-th year of operation during the loan repayment period of N sbpc years, taken to cover

Both the first and second-generation cognitive science fail to conceive semantics as a matter of language, considering it rather a matter of thought or even of brain (Lakoff

• The necessity of developing quality indicators specific for children is the basis to highlight and discuss the various issues concerning the measurement of quality

[11]Lance Patrick Williams,” Low Cost Radar and Sonar using Open Source Hardware and Software”, Master Thesis 2008, Department of Electrical Engineering

This part of the report focuses on the relationship between dynamic and productive &#34;territories&#34;, as contexts of reception of the development process, by identifying

Analyses carried out on policies, processes and perspectives in the Latium region reveal three basic lines of thinking concerning the scenarios of sustainable territorial